42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 157 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 157 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1439
SHADOW CREDIT AND THE DEVOLUTION OF CONSUMER
CREDIT REGULATION
by
Nathalie Martin* & Lydia Pizzonia**
Shadow credit is trending. Shadow credit has all the essential attributes of
regular credit except that it is unregulated. It operates in a world in which
products and services that look, act, and feel like credit products are deemed to
be something that is not actually credit. This legal sidestep is accomplished
either by passing industry-friendly legislation or by tweaking the shadow credit
product just enough to not be defined as credit, but “something else.” That
“something else” is often called a “lease,” an “advance,” or in the case of After-
pay, simply a “service.” At its essence, however, it is still credit. More and more
shadow credit products are popping up to take the place of actual credit prod-
ucts.
The purpose of avoiding being “credit” is to avoid consumer credit regulation.
We see this trend among purveyors of rent-to-own household goods, rent-to-
own real estate, employer payday advances, buy-now-pay-later services like Af-
terpay, income sharing agreements in higher education finance, and even bail
bonds, all of which seek to avoid complying with usury laws or interest rate
caps, Article 9 of the Uniform Commercial Code (U.C.C.), the federal Truth
in Lending Act, and all other consumer credit protection laws.
While some of these products are helpful to consumers, or at least not particu-
larly harmful, some are deeply predatory. They can operate outside the law.
*
Frederick M. Hart Chair in Consumer and Clinical Law, University of New Mexico School
of Law. The author thanks Stewart Paley, Adam Levitin, Bob Lawless, and colleagues Ernesto
Longa, Joe Schremmer, George Bach, Reed Benson, Jennifer Moore, Jen Laws, and Fred Hart for
their research and comments on earlier drafts; Clair Gardner and Jarrod Greth for their fine
research assistance; and the University of New Mexico School of Law for its generous financial
assistance. The authors are also grateful to the Lewis & Clark Law Review, particularly Lead
Article Editor John Mayer, Executive Editor Alexandra Giza, Submissions Editor Colin Bradshaw,
and Editor in Chief Connor B. McDermott.

J.D. 2019, University of New Mexico School of Law. The author thanks her husband and
children for their constant encouragement and support, and Professor Kenneth Bobroff for being
a sounding board, providing insight and new ideas, and supporting her desire to initiate change
in this area.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 157 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 157 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1440 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
For example, classic rent-to-own contracts that were historically used for house-
hold goods are now being used in housing contracts in vulnerable Native
American communities.
Emerging shadow credit products are testing the limits of what should be per-
mitted in rent-to-own contracts and similar financing tools. The trend toward
shadow credit has the capacity to derail our entire consumer credit regulation
system.
I. Introduction ....................................................................................... 1441
II. The Essence of Consumer Protection and Credit Transactions ........... 1444
A. What is Shadow Credit? ................................................................ 1444
B. The Protections Consumers Need and Businesses Seek to Avoid ........ 1448
1. The Truth in Lending Act ....................................................... 1452
2. The Fair Debt Collection Practices Act ..................................... 1454
3. Other Federal Laws ................................................................ 1456
4. State Usury Laws .................................................................... 1457
C. Recourse Versus Non-recourse Debt, Article 9, and the Scope and
Legislative History of Article 9 ....................................................... 1458
1. Rent-to-Own Debt is Non-recourse Debt, but Debt Nevertheless 1458
2. The Side-Step Around Article 9 ............................................... 1459
III. The Anatomy of Rent-to-Own ........................................................... 1464
A. Rent-to-Own Fundamentals .......................................................... 1465
B. Unprecedented Self-Regulation ...................................................... 1465
C. Rent-to-Own Regulation ............................................................... 1468
1. The Substance (or Lack Thereof) of Rental Purchase Agreement
Acts ....................................................................................... 1468
2. Case Law on Rent-to-Own ...................................................... 1470
D. The Demographics of the Typical Rent-to-Own Customer ............... 1471
E. What do Customers Really Want in Rent-to-Own Transactions ....... 1472
IV. Rent-to-Own Housing and Shadow Credit ......................................... 1473
V. Rent-to-Own Housing Sheds and Native American Predation ............ 1475
A. Native Americans are a Vulnerable Target for Rent-to-Own Shed
Deals ...........................................................................................
1476
B. Housing Crisis in Indian Country .................................................. 1477
C. Rent-to-Own Shed Dealers: The New Predator of New Mexico’s
Native Americans ......................................................................... 1479
D. An Insider’s View of Rent-to-Own Predation .................................. 1482
E. Comparing the Cost of Credit in Shed Homes to Rent-to-Own Land
Sale Contracts and Mortgages ........................................................ 1484
VI. The Greater Implications of the Credit-No Credit Distinction on the
Future of Credit Regulation ................................................................ 1484
VII. Conclusion ......................................................................................... 1487
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 158 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 158 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1441
I. INTRODUCTION
As we say in the law, if it looks like a duck and it quacks like a duck it is a
duck.
1
Sometimes products in the consumer credit market look very similar to other
products, but by tweaking that product in a tiny way, a provider of credit can avoid
a great deal of regulation, including consumer protection regulation. In this Article,
we identify a dangerous trend in consumer protection law, namely the expansion of
shadow credit. Shadow credit is credit disguised as something else. Sometimes the
disguise is unintended. Other times, it is designed to avoid consumer protection
laws.
When it comes to defining what constitutes credit, what is old is suddenly new
again. If one were to find the perfect designer, Covid-19 facemask on the internet,
like my family just did, the shopper would be told to add one more thing to the
shopping cart in order to qualify for Afterpay. Afterpay is a financing service that
claims not to be financing.
2
Similarly, education finance Income-Sharing Arrange-
ments (ISAs) allow lenders to advance funds to students for tuition/living expenses
in exchange for a percentage of that student’s future income. Again, these financiers
claim not to be financers and thus not to be providing credit.
Over 50 years ago, leading up to the passage of the Truth in Lending Act
(TILA) in 1968, what counted as “credit” and was thus subject to TILA was a big
question. At the time, many states had statutorily enacted the time-price differential
doctrine.
3
Under this doctrine, if a retailer sold goods for future payment, the dif-
ferential between the price of a cash sale and that of credit sale was not interest for
usury law purposes.
4
State retail installment loan acts eventually held these fees to
be finance charges that had to be disclosed in a certain way,
5
but as we discuss in
Part III.B below, some retailers found their way around these regulations. Fifty years
later, the dance continues. Indeed, these shadow credit products are proliferating
and putting our entire consumer credit regulation system at risk.
6
1
Joe Campbell & Richard Campbell, Why Statutory Interpretation Is Done as It Is Done 11–
12 (Sydney Law School, Legal Studies Research Paper No. 14/79, 2014),
http://ssrn.com/abstract=2484315.
2
David Chan, Afterpay: Consumer Advocates Fear ‘Instant Approvals’ Will Cause Serious
Financial Hardship, ABCN
EWS (Sept. 26, 2017), https://www.abc.net.au/news/2017-09-
26/afterpay-consumer-debt/8988394.
3
Adam Levitin, What Is “Credit”? Afterpay, Earnin’, and ISAs, CREDIT SLIPS (July 16, 2019,
1:31 PM),
https://www.creditslips.org/creditslips/2019/07/what-is-credit-afterpay-earnin-and-
isas.html#more.
4
Id.
5
Mourning v. Family Publ’ns Serv., Inc., 411 U.S. 356, 361(1973).
6
In his blog on the renewed importance of defining what constitutes “credit,” Adam Levitin
notes that products like payday advances, income sharing agreements for higher education finance,
and buy-now-pay-later products like Afterpay all claim not to be credit and not subject to the
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 158 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 158 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1442 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
While we discuss several modern examples as evidence of the rise of shadow
credit, we focus on rent-to-own transactions to demonstrate how an entire industry
can legislate itself out of consumer credit laws and restrictions. If one industry can
accomplish this, so can others. Before we know it, our entire system of protecting
consumers could disappear. Moreover, we have identified a small segment of the
rent-to-own industry that is taking advantage of consumers, raising the question of
whether it is time to revisit the entire framework for regulating consumer credit.
We start our inquiry by asking about the nature of credit, and then whether
rent-to-own transactions are essentially credit, or just leases as the rent-to-own in-
dustry claims. The implications of this question are far-reaching. If the transaction
is essentially a sale or purchase, the transaction is a credit transaction regardless of
what you call it. In that case, the transaction is subjected to many state and federal
laws regarding disclosures, default requirements, remedies, and so on.
7
If the main
point is to rent, but never to own, that is a lease that need not be regulated as credit.
8
Long ago, the rent-to-own industry passed enabling legislation to state explic-
itly that its transactions were outside the realm of credit.
9
This legislation removes
rent-to-own transactions from all state consumer credit regulation, TILA, all other
federal regulations, and state commercial law such as Article 9 of the U.C.C.
10
This
Article explores this industry-sponsored legislation in the context of a complex set
of consumer needs. It asks whether rent-to-own contracts are indeed outside of Ar-
ticle 9 and outside all of the protections that loan products have under both state
and federal law.
11
It further asks whether we need to revisit the nature of all rent-to-
Truth in Lending Act, as well as a slew of other federal and state regulations. Levitin, supra note
3.
7
See infra Part II.A.
8
Id.
9
See infra notes 168–81 and accompanying text; see also James M. Lacko, Signe-Mary
McKernan & Manoj Hastak, Survey of Rent-to-Own Customers, F
ED. TRADE COMMN ES-4 (April,
2000), https://www.ftc.gov/reports/survey-rent-own-customers/.
10
Id. at ES-4, 12–13.
11
Michael G. Bridge et al., Formalism, Functionalism, and Understanding the Law of Secured
Transactions, 44 M
CGILL L.J. 567, 599 (1999). As these scholars explain, from a functionalist
perspective:
a lease operates as a form of purchase money financing to the extent that it allows a lessee
who lacks the wherewithal to buy the leased goods to nonetheless obtain their possession and
use. The economic function of the transaction from the point of view of the lessor and the
purchase money secured party is similar: both obtain the right to a stream of payments dur-
ing the currency of the transaction and both can claim an in rem right to priority as against
other creditors in the event of insolvency.
Id. at 599; see also, e.g., Margaret Howard, Equipment Lessors and Secured Parties in Bankruptcy:
An Argument For Coherence, 48 W
ASH. & LEE L. REV. 253, 253–54, 279–83 (1991); John D.
Ayer, On the Vacuity of the Sale/Lease Distinction, 68 I
OWA L. REV. 667, 668, 681 (1983)
(discussing functionalist arguments in favor of the identity of leases and security).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 159 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 159 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1443
own contracts or simply find protections in situations in which the abuses seem
most egregious.
12
While our focus is rent-to-own, and ultimately a small niche market within
rent-to-own, the question of what constitutes credit has far-reaching implications
for the future of consumer credit regulation. We are watching a trend in which more
and more industries carve themselves out of the credit definition, further eroding
what consumer protection remains.
In Part II of this Article, we explore the essence of credit transactions, discuss
the goals of the consumer credit protection scheme, and examine the specific laws
through which these goals are met.
13
We then discuss the difference between re-
course and non-recourse credit and describe relevant portions of Article 9 of the
U.C.C., one of the main laws rent-to-own companies and other shadow credit pro-
viders seek to avoid.
14
In Part III, we describe the taxonomy of rent-to-own trans-
actions, how they work, how the industry regulated itself, and what these industry
regulations provide.
15
We then describe the demographics of a typical rent-to-own
customer and the goals of most rent-to-own customers in rent-to-own relation-
ships.
16
In Part IV we describe another form of the rent-to-own contract, those relating
to rent-to-own real estate.
17
We explore various predatory practices in these shadow
12
While many scholars have dabbled in rent-to-own scholarship, two have studied this
industry extensively: Professor Michael Anderson and Professor Jim Hawkins. Professor Anderson
has dedicated his career to studying rent-to-own. See, e.g., Michael H. Anderson & Raymond
Jackson, A Reconsideration of Rent-to-Own, 35
J. CONSUMER AFF. 295, 298 (2001),
http://www.thefreelibrary.com/A+Reconsideration+of+Rent-to-Own.-a080805982. Anderson
has deep ties to industry, but nevertheless is an honest scholar. In one article, he critiques a scholar
who shortens rental periods and inflates the value of rented goods in order to reduce the annual
percentage rate on typical rent-to-own transactions. Id. Professor Hawkins is a leading consumer
law scholar, who has written on many consumer products, including fertility treatment financing,
title lending, payday lending, rent-to-own, and most recently, employer payday advances. See, e.g.,
Jim Hawkins, Financing Fertility, 47 H
ARV. J. LEGIS. 115, 116 (2010) (fertility treatment
financing); Kathryn Fritzdixon, Jim Hawkins, & Paige Marta Skiba, Dude, Where’s My Car Title?:
The Law, Behavior, and Economics of Title Lending Markets, 2014 U
NIV. ILL. L. REV. 1013, 1016
(2014) (title lending); Ronald J. Mann & Jim Hawkins, Just Until Payday, 54 UCLA L. Rev. 855,
857 (2007)
(payday lending); Jim Hawkins, Renting the Good Life, 49 WM. & MARY L. REV. 2041,
2046 (2008) (rent-to-own).
Hawkins views rent-to-own from an extremely practical point of view,
expressing the desire to see the transactions as hybrids between typical credit transactions and basic
rental agreements. Id. at 2052–53. His goal is to avoid overly-paternalistic regulation in order to
maintain the rent-to-own option for consumers, and regulate with fee caps, lifetime reinstatement
polices, and other regulatory “light touches.” Id. at 2047, 2117. These are valuable contributions.
13
See infra notes 24–123 and accompanying text.
14
See infra notes 124–49 and accompanying text.
15
See infra notes 150–205 and accompanying text.
16
See infra notes 206–22 and accompanying text.
17
See infra notes 223–44 and accompanying text.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 159 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 159 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1444 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
credit transactions, sometimes called land sale contracts or contracts for deed.
18
In
Part V, we describe a recent trend that combines the classic rent-to-own contract
with the shadow housing market. More specifically, we explore predatory practices
in Native communities involving rent-to-own sheds used for housing.
19
These prac-
tices are largely unknown and thus have not been explored by previous scholars.
These rent-to-own shed transactions provide an opportunity to describe these un-
known practices and to examine the real dangers of shadow credit at its worst.
20
In Part VI, we discuss the greater implications of the credit/no credit dichot-
omy, focusing on the societal implications of sheltering shadow credit products from
regulation.
21
We provide a number of examples from other areas of the law in which
society elevates substance over form to protect various regulatory frameworks in our
complex legal system.
22
In Part VII, we conclude that the rent-to-own industry,
particularly as it morphs into areas beyond household goods, demonstrates the harm
that all shadow credit products can impart on the consumer credit regulatory sys-
tem, and perhaps even the entire credit regulatory system.
23
II. THE ESSENCE OF CONSUMER PROTECTION AND CREDIT
TRANSACTIONS
The purpose of this Part is to determine what our consumer credit regulation
system is designed to do for consumers, to which transactions it should apply, and
why. We discuss what makes a product or service “credit” as opposed to something
else. We explore why and how our legal system regulates consumer credit products
and briefly review some of the most important federal and state consumer credit
laws. We then describe the distinction between recourse and non-recourse credit,
which relates to the rent-to-own industry’s argument that rent-to-own contracts are
not credit because customers can terminate the contracts at any time without owing
more debt. We end with a Section describing Article 9 of the U.C.C. and the ways
it has been amended regarding what actually constitutes credit.
A. What is Shadow Credit?
As lawyers, we are comfortable with unsettled or grey areas in the law.
24
Indeed,
18
Id.
19
See infra notes 245–95 and accompanying text.
20
Id.
21
See infra notes 296–315 and accompanying text.
22
Id.
23
See infra notes 315–18 and accompanying text.
24
Raúl Jáuregui, Rembrandt Portraits: Economic Negligence In Art Attribution, 44 UCLA L.
REV. 1947, 1959–61, 2011–12 (1997); W. Bradley Wendel, Autonomy Isn’t Everything: Some
Cautionary Notes On Mccoy v. Louisiana, 9 S
T. MARYS J. LEGAL MAL. & ETHICS 92, 111–13
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 160 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 160 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1445
interpreting gray areas of the law is one of the skills lawyers bring to society.
25
This
interpretive process is also what makes our work interesting, more art than science.
26
Gray areas can either arise from the world at large or be created by law and lawyers
themselves, but however they arise, the law aspires to elevate substance over form
and to recognize reality rather than contort it.
27
Shadow credit operates much like regular credit but differs in small ways.
28
Shadow credit operates in the grey areas or shadows of the finance industry. When
we charge an item on a credit card, or take out a mortgage or a payday loan, we
know we are entering into a credit relationship.
29
Since creditors tend to have more
power in credit relationships than borrowers, a host of laws protect borrowers, par-
ticularly consumer borrowers.
30
What makes something credit? Starting with a basic dictionary definition,
credit is “the provision of money, goods, or services with the expectation of future
payment.”
31
Under this definition, credit is borrowing money and promising to pay
it back at a later time. Credit is a service, not a good,
32
and as Ayn Rand once pro-
claimed, credit transactions include the vast majority of economic transactions in a
complex industrial society.
33
Most of us have instincts about what constitutes credit
(2018). Our own experiences with rent-to-own come from a lifetime of interacting with low-
income consumers and first-hand knowledge of their experiences with consumer credit products.
Our experiences with actual consumers allow us to see not just the law, though that is critically
important, but also the effect of the law on human beings. Some of our reactions come from a gut
reaction, developed over three decades of teaching, writing, and law practice, about what does and
does not constitute credit.
25
Jáuregui, supra note 24, at 1963, 1986–87, 1990.
26
Id. at 1958–59, 1963, 1990, 2012.
27
See, e.g., Frank Lyon Co. v. United States, 435 U.S. 561, 581–82 (1978) (the Supreme
Court held that the title owner that acquired depreciable real estate, rather than a mere conduit
or agent, had the legal right to take tax deductions associated with depreciation on the building).
28
By shadow credit, we do not meanshadow banking, a phrase used during the Great
Recession of 2008 to mean activities that involved high-risk financing outside that provided by
traditional banks. See Stijn Claessens & Lev Ratnovski, What Is Shadow Banking? 3 (International
Monetary Fund, Working Paper No. 14/25, 2015), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2559504.
29
Elizabeth Renuart & Diane E. Thompson, The Truth, The Whole Truth, and Nothing but
the Truth: Fulfilling the Promise of Truth in Lending, 25 Y
ALE J. REG. 181, 184–85 (2008).
30
Id. at 185, 196–97; see also Anderson & Jackson, supra note 12, at 305 (describing rent-
to-own transactions and stating that “[d]ue to asymmetry in experience and depth of information,
the salesperson is at an advantage to the ordinary consumer regarding not only the product but
also, even more importantly, the legal and financial provisions of the contract.”).
31
Credit, MERRIAM-WEBSTER, https://www.merriam-webster.com/dictionary/credit (last
visited Dec. 20, 2020).
32
Alexei Alexandrov, Daniel Grodzicki & Özlem Bedre-Defolie, Consumer Demand for
Credit Card Services 2 (Consumer Financial Protection Bureau Office of Research, Working Paper
No. 2018-03, 2018), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3135421.
33
AYN RAND, THE VIRTUE OF SELFISHNESS: A NEW CONCEPT OF EGOISM 111 (1961).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 160 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 160 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1446 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
as opposed to something else. Some of the less tangible attributes of credit include
transactions that get reported on a credit report,
34
transactions in which the con-
sumer puts down a deposit, transactions in which the item being paid for can be
repossessed, and so on. None of these attributes are determinative, however.
Federal consumer credit regulations contain numerous technical definitions of
credit. We discuss the substance of these laws later, but under Regulation Z,
35
which
regulates most consumer credit transactions including home mortgages, home eq-
uity lines of credit, reverse mortgages, credit cards, installment loans, and certain
kinds of student loans,
36
credit means “the right to defer payment of debt or to incur
debt and defer its payment.”
37
The Consumer Financial Protection Act of 2010
(CFPA), that created the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau, defines credit as
“the right granted by a person to a consumer to defer payment of a debt, incur debt
and defer its payment, or purchase property or services and defer payment for such
purchase.”
38
The Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA) and the Fair Credit Re-
porting Act (FCRA) track this CFPA definition,
39
except that ECOA and the FCRA
limit a “creditor under these Acts to those who regularly extend credit, not those do
so only occasionally.”
40
The Fair Debt Collection Practices Act (FDCPA) lacks a
definition of credit but broadly defines a creditor as “any person who offers or ex-
tends credit creating a debt or to whom debt is owed.”
41
Debt is defined by the Fair
Debt Collection Practices Act as:
any obligation or alleged obligation of a consumer to pay money arising out
of a transaction in which the money, property, insurance, or services which
are the subject of the transaction are primarily for personal, family, or house-
34
Alexandra P. Everhart Sickler, The (Un)Fair Credit Reporting Act, 28 LOY. CONSUMER L.
R
EV. 238, 243 n.21 (2016).
35
Regulation Z, 12 C.F.R. § 1026.1 (2019).
36
Id.
37
Id. at § 1026.2(a)(14); see also Levitin, supra note 3. Regulation Z, section 1026.2(b)(3)
also states that “[u]nless defined in this part, opportunity words used have the meanings given to
them by state law or contract.” This means more transactions might fall within TILA/Reg Z than
it appears at first glance. Levitin, supra note 3.
38
Consumer Financial Protection Act (CFPA) of 2010 § 1002, 12 U.S.C. § 5481(7) (2018)
(definitions). Oddly, there is no definition of debt. Id.
39
Under ECOA, credit is defined as, “the right granted by a creditor to a debtor to defer
payment of debt or to incur debts and defer its payment or to purchase property or services and
defer payment therefor.” Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA), 15 U.S.C. § 1691a(d) (2018);
Fair Credit Reporting Act (FCRA), 15 U.S.C. § 1681a (r)(5) (2018) (defining “credit” and
“creditor” as having the same meaning as in the ECOA).
40
Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA) §§ 1692(a)–(e); see also Fair Credit Reporting Act
(FCRA) § 1681a(r)(5).
41
Fair Debt Collection Practices Act (FDCPA), 15 U.S.C. § 1692a(4) (2018).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 161 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 161 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1447
hold purposes, whether or not such obligation has been reduced to judg-
ment.
42
While TILA’s definition of “credit” is similar to that of the CFPA and
ECOA/FCRA, providing that “the right granted by a creditor to a debtor to defer pay-
ment of debt or to incur debt and defer its payment,”
43
its definition of “creditor” is
entirely different:
The term ‘creditor’ refers only to a person who both (1) regularly extends,
whether in connection with loans, sales of property or services, or otherwise,
consumer credit which is payable by agreement in more than four installments
or for which the payment of a finance charge is or may be required, and (2) is
the person to whom the debt arising from the consumer credit transaction is
initially payable on the face of the evidence of indebtedness or, if there is no
such evidence of indebtedness, by agreement.
44
In describing all of these various definitions of debt and credit, Professor Adam
Levitin explains:
Credit is generally defined as the right to defer payment of an obligation. But
sometimes it has to be granted by a “creditor,” and “creditor” is defined sub-
stantially differently by statute. In particular, TILA requires either a possible
finance charge or payment in more than four installments.
45
Needless to say, much of this language is in conflict, even though many of these
federal laws apply to the same transaction.
When it comes to rent-to-own, many consumer law scholars and legislators
instinctively believe that rent-to-own transactions are credit transactions.
46
In his
discussion of whether rent-to-own is regulated by the Consumer Financial Protec-
tion Bureau, Jim Hawkins catalogues a list of congresspersons who assumed rent-
to-own was credit.
47
Many consumers also assume they are using credit to buy some-
thing when they enter into rent-to-own transactions, because they are not paying
42
Id. at § 1692b(5).
43
Truth in Lending Act (TILA), 15 U.S.C. § 1602(f) (2018).
44
Id. at § 1602(g).
45
Levitin, supra note 3.
46
Jim Hawkins, The Federal Government in the Fringe Economy, 15 CHAPMAN L. REV. 23,
31–32 (2011).
47
“For instance, consider this exchange between Senators Dodd and Schumer when
discussing the differences between the bill the House and Senate passed:
DODD: Could we try, I’m not going to—as I said I’m not going to offer the amendment
now but could we try to deal with the non-bank payday lenders and the non-bank rent to
own type people who escape regulation here?
DODD: Well, we’ve raised that with the other side . . .
SCHUMER: The House put it in. No, the House is OK with it. The House has it in their
bill.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 161 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 161 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1448 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
the full price at the moment of the purchase.
48
Even atypical rent-to-own customers
often assume that rent-to-own is credit.
49
So why aren’t rent-to-own transactions
credit? Primarily because the industry passed laws proclaiming that rent-to-own was
not “credit,”
50
as described in Part III.B below.
B. The Protections Consumers Need and Businesses Seek to Avoid
The point of being “not credit” is to avoid consumer credit regulation, but why
do we regulate consumer credit in the first place? Concerns include high fees, dis-
guised fees, repossession without notice, unfair default provisions, and unequal bar-
gaining power.
51
Consumer protection laws come in two types: disclosures and substantive reg-
ulations.
52
Various federal and state laws protect consumers from harm, including
inaccurate, misleading, or deceptive practices engaged in to gain an advantage over
consumers.
53
The policy behind disclosure is that consumers are less sophisticated
than businesspeople, but that if sufficient information is provided to consumers,
Testimony from people supporting the Military Lending Act (MLA) also assumes rent-to-own is
credit. In support of an amendment to the MLA, Senator Jack Reed stated:
Rent-to-own loans. This is where you go to a shop and you say I would like to rent a TV for
30 days because you am [sic] deploying in 45 days . . . then you don’t deploy so you keep it,
and in some cases, you end up paying two to three times the retail price of the appliance. At
least individual soldiers have to be informed of those practices and know about it. We have
to be sure they are getting that information . . . . That is what we want to do – coordinate
these activities through a military liaison at a consumer financial protection agency. We want
to do that because it is the right thing to do and because if we cannot protect the men and
women who are protecting us, then we have to ask seriously whether we are doing our job. I
know they are doing their job.
Id. at 30–31.
48
Lacko, supra note 9, at ES-4.
49
One friend, a law professor, was renting a piano and it ultimately was taken back by its
owner. She sought Professor Martin’s advice as a consumer. She assumed that once she had paid
the fair market value of the sued piano, she would own it. This was without any additional interest
or fees.
50
See infra notes 168–81 and accompanying text.
51
Lacko, supra note 9, at 3.
52
According to scholar Scott Burnham, consumer law serves three primary functions: “(1)
the disclosure function to provide consumers with essential information, (2) the representation
function to act as the bargaining agent for the consumer by mandating substantive provisions
consumers would otherwise be unable to obtain, and (3) the bargaining function to offer
consumers a choice.” Scott J. Burnham, The Regulation of Rent-to-Own Transactions, 3 L
OY.
CONSUMER L. REV. 40, 41 (1991).
53
Federal Trade Commission Act (FTCA), 15 U.S.C. §§ 41–77 (2019) (prohibiting “unfair
methods of competition and unfair or deceptive acts or practices”); Truth-in-Lending Act (TILA),
15 U.S.C. § 1602(a) (2018) (having among its goals to protect consumers against inaccurate and
unfair billing).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 162 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 162 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1449
this can help level the playing field.
54
We also want to ensure that consumers have
a way to compare the cost of credit being offered by various credit service provid-
ers.
55
Disclosure can be appealing because, theoretically, it encourages consumers to
be free agents and limits paternalism.
56
If it works, and consumers can read and
understand the disclosures, the disclosures can help market forces operate more ef-
ficiently.
57
In contrast, substantive protective regulation limits free choice, including the
choice to make bad decisions. Even if substantive regulation does limit free will,
where bargaining power is imbalanced, substantive regulation may be necessary to
achieve fairness.
58
In reality, substantive versus disclosure regulation is a false di-
chotomy because disclosures are critical to enforcing substantive regulations and be-
cause most consumer protection laws contain both.
The rent-to-own industry has been clear in its desire to avoid most consumer
credit regulation schemes. In describing the development of the industry, James
Nehf explains:
Eventually, entrepreneurs noticed an apparent void in consumer credit laws.
When read literally, many statutes applied only to transactions in which a
“debt” was created and the consumer was obligated to pay for the full value
of the goods. They did not cover a transaction in which the consumer was
obligated for only a week or two and then had the option of renewing the
agreement for a number of successive weeks or months in order to complete
the contract. By 1960, businesses had opened in low-income neighborhoods
offering short-term renewable leases, with no credit check, that promised im-
mediate possession of furniture and home appliances. Moreover, a consumer
renewing the lease long enough would obtain ownership of those goods. The
contract was thus styled not as a sale of goods on credit but as a weekly or
monthly lease that ultimately would lead to a transfer of ownership if the cus-
tomer continued leasing for a stated period, usually twelve or eighteen
months. A market for the [rent-to-own] service was quickly established.
59
If a product is not debt or credit, it escapes compliance with TILA,
60
the
54
Susan Lorde Martin & Nancy White Huckins, Consumer Advocates vs. the Rent-To-Own
Industry: Reaching a Reasonable Accommodation, 34 A
M. BUS. L.J. 385, 388 (1997).
55
Renuart & Thompson, supra note 29, at 184, 187.
56
Hawkins, supra note 12, at 2115.
57
Id. at 2116.
58
Id. at 2092–93; see also New Mexico ex rel. King v. B & B Inv. Grp., Inc., 329 P.3d 658,
669–70 (N.M. 2014) (decision of the New Mexico Supreme Court discussing substantive and
procedural unconscionability).
59
James P. Nehf, Effective Regulation of Rent-to-Own Contracts, 52 OHIO ST. L.J. 751, 755
(1991).
60
Truth-in-Lending Act (TILA), 15 U.S.C. §§ 1601–1667f (2018).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 162 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 162 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1450 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
FDCPA,
61
and numerous other federal and state laws applicable to the extension of
credit.
Some of the products in the marketplace that currently claim to not be credit
include rent-to-own contracts,
62
bail bonds,
63
employer loans,
64
buy-now-pay-later
services like Afterpay and education finance ISAs. These last two are modern cut-
ting-edge examples of the expansion of shadow credit.
Afterpay works with retailers to provide financing for relatively small purchases,
by breaking up the purchase price into four equal installments.
65
In the same breath,
Afterpay claims that “[u]nlike some typical finance businesses, Afterpay relies on
and only benefits from customers not going into default, paying off their orders in
full and on time,” but also that “[a]fterpay charges a flat $10 late fee per payment
and a further late fee of $7 if the payment is not made within 7 days.”
66
On a small
purchase, these fees represent thousands of percentage points per annum if stated as
interest rates. The first YouTube video to pop up to help consumers understand
Afterpay calls this service interest-free, which is scary.
67
The capacity to use essen-
tially unregulated services like this to overspend is breathtaking, especially for
younger consumers.
68
Likewise, with education finance ISAs, lenders advance funds to the consumer
61
Id. § 1692a.
62
Hawkins, supra note 12, at 2051.
63
California felt the need to clarify that bail bonds are indeed credit after the industry
claimed they were not and thus claimed they did not need to state an APR in their contracts. S.
318, 2019-20 Leg., Reg. Sess. (Cal. 2019).
64
Jim Hawkins, Earned Wage Access and the End of Payday Lending, B.U. L. REV.
(forthcoming 2020) (manuscript at 36–41), https://ssrn.com/abstract=3514856.
65
Afterpay Fact Sheet, AFTERPAY, https://www.afterpay.com/attachment/44/show (last
visited Dec. 21, 2020).
66
Id.
67
Destinyc06, What is afterpay??? Afterpay pros and cons!! How to use afterpay., YOUTUBE
(Mar. 23, 2019), https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=GFw1-klb7-s.
68
As Levitin explains in his blog:
This finance charge or four-installments provision is key for buy-now-pay-later products like
Afterpay. Afterpay allows the consumer to purchase goods now and pay over 4 equal install-
ment payments. So it’s within the 4-installment part of the “creditor” definition. And After-
pay does not have a charge if you pay on time. It only has a late fee. Late fees are excluded
from the finance charge if it is for “actual, unanticipated late payment.” So if borrowers are
anticipated to pay off the Afterpay advance within the four installments, no problem—no
finance charge, and not a “creditor” for TILA, and therefore not subject to TILA disclosure
rules, TILA error resolution rules, or TILA unauthorized transaction liability limitation
rules. Of course, if most consumers are paying late, then Afterpay’s late fee would be a finance
charge, so it would be a creditor, extending credit and subject to TILA. (I have no reason to
believe that this is the case).
Levitin, supra note 3. Note, however, that even though Afterpay is not subject to TILA, it is still
subject to ECOA, FCRA, FDCPA, and CFPA.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 163 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 163 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1451
for tuition/living expenses in exchange for the consumer’s promise to pay a percent-
age of his or her future income, over and above a minimum amount, to the lender.
69
While the total number of payments, payment time, and/or amount of payment
may be capped, generally speaking, “the more you earn, the more you pay.”
70
While these ISAs are clearly used to finance an education, they claim to be “not
credit.”
71
Similar to buy-now-pay-later arrangements like Afterpay, and like
Paycheck advances, the financiers claim that they do not issue credit.
72
Like the
rent-to-own industry, ISA providers claim that only unconditional promises to re-
pay constitute credit,
73
belying the existence of non-recourse credit. Indeed, in one
law firm’s analysis of ISAs, the firm explains in detail, law by law, why all of the
usual consumer protection laws do not apply to ISAs.
74
We can see that many cred-
itors would indeed want “more of that please.” Below we describe some of the laws
these entities seek to avoid.
69
Levitin, supra note 3.
70
Id.; see also Robert Farrington, Be Careful with Income Sharing Agreement (ISAs) to Pay for
College, F
ORBES (Apr. 12, 2019), https://www.forbes.com/sites/robertfarrington/2019/04/
12/income-sharing-agreements-to-pay-for-college/#70fc4d1052e0.
71
Levitin describes them as more like “participating preferred shares, in that if there’s
enough to pay the common equity (the consumer) a dividend, then the preferred shares must be
paid a dividend. While we often call preferred shares equity, they’re really a hybrid of equity and
debt features.” Levitin, supra note 3.
72
Regulatory Treatment of Educational ISAs Under Federal and Select State Consumer Credit
Statutes, M
ORRISON & FOERSTER LLP (Mar. 2019), https://media2.mofo.com/documents/
190408-regulatory-educational-consumer-credit-statutes.pdf.
73
Id. at 1–2. As Levitin explains in his blog:
Whether ISAs are credit is critical to their viability. ISAs are priced differently depending on
school and/or major. A computer science major is likely to have to pay a lower percentage
than an anthropology major. One might imagine a pricing differential between students at
an HBCU or minority-serving institution and at other schools. If ISAs are credit for ECOA
purposes, there’s likely, therefore, to be major disparate impact issues.
. . .
For CFPA purposes, there are two possible ways [ISAs could be credit]. First, for ISAs pro-
vided by the school itself (such as Perdue University), the answer is clearly yes. “Credit” is
“the right granted by a person to a consumer to . . . purchase . . . services [education] and
defer payment for such purchase.” If a school is the ISA provider, it’s definitely credit for the
CFPA, which means UDAAP prohibitions apply. I think the answer is also the same if the
provider is affiliated with the school, as the CFPA has an anti-evasion provision in its defi-
nition of “financial product or service”.
Second, for ISAs provided by third-parties, the question is whether the ISA is a “right granted
by a person to a consumer to defer payment of a debt” or to “incur debt and defer its pay-
ment.” (To be sure, the language about “purchase property or services and defer payment for
such purchase” does not necessarily refer to a purchase from the person . . .).
Levitin, supra note 3.
74
MORRISON & FOERSTER LLP, supra note 72, at 2, 6–21.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 163 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 163 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1452 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
1. The Truth in Lending Act
The granddaddy of all consumer protection laws is TILA,
passed by Congress
in 1968.
75
TILA requires all credit providers to disclose all fees and charges in one
number, an annual percentage rate (APR) comprised of the sum of the amount fi-
nanced and the finance charge, as well as the number, amount, and due dates of all
scheduled payments and the amount of any late payment charge.
76
Congress’ pur-
pose in enacting TILA was to allow consumers to more readily compare the various
credit terms available, to avoid the uninformed use of credit, and to protect the
consumer against “inaccurate and unfair credit . . . practices.”
77
As explained by
Elizabeth Renuart and Diane Thompson:
The drafters of TILA understood that without uniform disclosure, interest
calculations are forbiddingly complex. The APR is meant to be a simplifying
heuristic that allows borrowers to decide between options that are otherwise
overwhelmingly complex. Many consumers stumble when confronted with
even basic computational problems. Lenders can compound those missteps
through marketing that distracts consumers from the salient points.
78
Congress designed the APR to be the single number for consumers to focus on
when shopping for credit, and thus the APR has become the touchpoint for con-
sumers comparing the cost of credit.
79
The purpose of TILA is to allow consumers
to compare fees, or the total cost of goods or housing, by comparing the annual
percentage rate on credit costs.
80
Moreover, TILA has been remarkably effective at
getting consumers to pay attention to interest rates and the cost of credit.
81
TILA’s
familiar and tidy TILA text box makes easy an otherwise daunting math task.
82
TILA applies to credit sales, which include “any contract in the form of a bail-
ment or lease in which the bailee or lessee contracts to pay a sum substantially equiv-
alent to or in excess of the aggregate value of the property and services involved and
the bailee or lessee will become, or for no other or a nominal consideration has the
option to become, the owner of the property upon full compliance with his obliga-
tions under the contract.”
83
Barring industry legislation to the contrary, this lan-
guage certainly covers rent-to-own transactions.
75
Truth in Lending Act (TILA), Pub. L. No. 90-321, 82 Stat. 146 (1968) (current version
at 15 U.S.C. § 1601 (2018)).
76
Id. at § 1638(a)(6).
77
Id. at § 1601(a); see also Martin & Huckins, supra note 54, at 388–89.
78
Renuart & Thompson, supra note 29, at 190.
79
Id. at 217.
80
Id. at 190.
81
Id. at 189–90.
82
Id.
83
Martin & Huckins, supra note 54, at 389; Truth in Lending Act (TILA), 15 U.S.C. §
1602(g) (2018).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 164 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 164 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1453
Retail sales stores like Conn’s or Best Buy, who sell items on credit, must com-
ply with TILA, but rent-to-own stores in states with industry-sponsored legislation
do not. Yet there is no doubt that the market substitute for rent-to-own contracts
are installment sales contracts offered through retailers like Conn’s. Conn’s is a na-
tional appliance, furniture, and electronic store which makes most of its sales from
the credit it offers to consumers who have difficulty getting credit elsewhere.
84
It is
required to include an APR in all its contracts which puts it at a disadvantage com-
pared to rent-to-own companies.
To help consumers compare the cost of their goods and credit services to those
offered by typical rent-to-own companies, Conn’s offers a side-by-side comparison
on their web site.
85
For an LG 43” television, their cash price is $699.99 and their
financed price over 24 months is $1,173.52. They compare this to a typical rent-to-
own transaction for the same television in which the cash price is $1,046.05 and the
financed price is $2,092.09.
86
The point of all this is not the exorbitant cost, but the fact that Conn’s and
rent-to-own are not on a level playing field because Conn’s is required to be honest
and transparent in its disclosure of the total costs of its products and services and
rent-to-own is not, despite that these transactions are market substitutes.
87
84
Lawrence Meyers, A Case Study in Capital Preservation: Conn’s (Part 1), WYATT INV.
RESEARCH (Sept. 22, 2014), https://www.wyattresearch.com/article/capital-preservation/.
85
YES MONEY vs. Rent To Own, CONNS HOMEPLUS, https://www.conns.com/yes-money-
financing-vs-rent-to-own-texas, (last visited on Aug. 27, 2020).
86
Id. This is a saving of $918 over roughly two years. Id. They do the same math for an LG
French door refrigerator, which they sell for $1,699.97 cash or $2,515.12 financed. With rent-to-
own, one would pay $2,500.53 for the same refrigerator in cash or $3,846.96 financed, a $1331
savings. Finally, they offer a sofa set for $1,979.99 in cash or $2,890.96 financed, whereas these
same items would cost roughly $2,080 in cash or $4,160 over time from a rent-to-own
establishment.
87
A few courts have considered whether rent-to-own companies must disclose an APR and
comply with TILA. Some have found that rent-to-own contracts fall within TILA, given that in
substance they are the same as a credit transaction and that in most cases the customer intends to
buy the item, not merely rent it. See Clark v. Rent-It Corp., 685 F.2d 245, 248 (8th Cir. 1982);
Davis v. Colonial Sec. Corp., 541 F. Supp. 302, 305 (E.D. Pa. 1982); Waldron v. Best T.V. &
Stereo Rentals, Inc., 485 F. Supp. 718, 719 (D. Md. 1979); Murphy v. McNamara, 416 A.2d
170, 177 (Conn. Super. Ct. 1979). Most courts, however, have found that TILA does not apply
to rent-to-own contracts, on the reasoning that in a rent-to-own transaction, the customer does
not promise to pay the full value of the goods he or she is acquiring. See, e.g., Ortiz v. Rental
Mgmt., Inc., 65 F.3d 335, 342 (3d Cir. 1995); In re Hanley, 135 B.R. 311, 314 (C.D. Ill. 1990);
Clark v. Rent-It Corp., 511 F. Supp. 796, 799 (S.D. Iowa 1981); LeMay v. Stroman’s, Inc., 510
F. Supp. 921, 923 (E.D. Ark. 1981); Dodson v. Remco Enters., Inc., 504 F. Supp. 540, 543
(E.D. Va. 1980); Smith v. ABC Rental Sys. of New Orleans, Inc., 491 F. Supp. 127, 397 (E.D.
La. 1978), aff’d, 618 F.2d 397 (5th Cir. 1980); Stewart v. Remco Enters., Inc., 487 F. Supp. 361,
363 (D. Neb. 1980); Remco Enters., Inc. v. Houston, 677 P.2d 567, 573 (Kan. App. 1984).
Moreover, in 1981, the Federal Reserve Board, empowered by Congress to issue implementing
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 164 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 164 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1454 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
Some scholars insist that providing an APR in rent-to-own transactions will
only confuse customers. For example, Michael Anderson claims that APRs do not
help consumers understand rent-to-own transactions and that they “neither convey
sufficient information to enable a consumer to rationally choose the most efficient
alternative nor can they be cited as evidence of exploitation of either [rent-to-own]
or laundromat customers.”
88
Similarly, Professor Jim Hawkins has argued that
APRs should not be required in rent-to-own transactions, in part because consumers
do not understand APRs and cannot calculate them,
89
and in part because the in-
dustry has indicated in the strongest possible way that if it has to disclose an APR,
it will leave the marketplace.
90
On the other hand, consumers need not be able to calculate an APR as long as
they can compare two TILA boxes, which many apparently can do.
91
APR disclo-
sures are still relevant in contracts shorter than one year in duration. After all, one
need not travel a mile to go a certain number of miles per hour. If rent-to-own
dealers were required to disclose the APR, this interest rate might shock consumers
into reconsidering signing on the dotted line. Then, on the other hand, it may not,
but at least consumers could compare the cost of a rent-to-own transaction to an
installment purchase agreement if they wanted to.
2. The Fair Debt Collection Practices Act
The FDCPA sets limits on the ways in which debt collectors can contact con-
sumers to collect a debt. For example, debt collectors may not call before 8 am or
after 9 pm,
92
call a consumer at work,
93
employ any unfair practices in an attempt
to collect a debt,
94
or conceal his or her identity on the phone.
95
Moreover, if the
consumer asks to never be contacted again, the debt collector must cease all contact
regulations for the TILA, clarified the scope of the act by amending its Regulation Z to define a
credit sale as including “a bailment or lease (unless terminable without penalty any time by the
consumer).” Martin & Huckins, supra note 54, at 389–90. Rather, he or she has an option to keep
paying and own the item at the end of a certain term. But see Perez v. Rent-a-Ctr., Inc., 892 A.2d
1255, 1257–58 (N.J. 2006).
88
As Anderson explains:
Requirements that rent-to-own agreements disclose implicit APRs merely cloud the issue for
consumers because they are not simply disguised installment contracts any more than are
layaway plans or the long-term use of coin-operated washing machines and photocopiers.
Anderson & Jackson, supra note 12 , at 304–05.
89
Hawkins, supra note 12, at 2107.
90
Id. at 2103–04.
91
See Renuart & Thomas, supra note 29, at 217–18.
92
Fair Debt Collection Practices Act (FDCPA), 15 U.S.C. § 1692c (a)(1) (2018).
93
Id. § 1692c (a)(3).
94
Id. § 1692f.
95
Id. § 1692d (6).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 165 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 165 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1455
with that consumer.
96
The FDCPA also dictates how a debt collector must act when
communicating with a third party about the consumer being collected upon, and
dictates that debt collectors cannot even share information pertaining to a debt to
anyone but the consumer, a spouse, or a parent if the consumer is underage.
97
Debt
collectors cannot communicate with consumers by postcard or in any other way that
invades privacy about the debt, nor can they publish any kind of listing of consumers
that have not paid a debt, except to a consumer bureau.
98
If a consumer hires an attorney and tells the debt collector he or she is repre-
sented, the debt collector can no longer communicate with the consumer directly.
99
Debt collectors are prohibited from using any form of harassment or abuse while
attempting to collect.
100
They cannot lie or falsely imply that the consumer has
committed a crime.
101
While these rules do not generally apply to companies col-
lecting on their own debts, if the creditor collects under a slightly different name
than the one they otherwise operate under, the FDCPA rules do apply.
102
If the
FDCPA is violated, the consumer can recover statutory and actual damages plus
attorney’s fees, an important remedy when seeking a lawyer.
103
The FDCPA does not apparently apply to rent-to-own transactions, yet fair
debt collection in rent-to-own transactions is a problem. According to the National
Consumer Law Center (NCLC), the rent-to-own industry has used the threat of
arrest and criminal sanctions to obtain payments from customers.
104
In many states,
if a customer misses a single payment and does not promptly return the merchan-
dise, the rent-to-own dealers pursue criminal charges against the customer.
105
The
industry, enabled by state criminal statutes and prosecutors’ offices, has pursed crim-
inal theft charges against renters of property, which the NCLC likens to the resur-
gence of debtor’s prison and the criminalization of poverty.
106
In other consumer
transactions, failure to make a payment would be considered a breach of contract, a
civil matter, but, because in rent-to-own contracts, the dealers retain title to the
property, dealers base their criminal claims on “theft of services” or “theft of rental
96
Id. § 1692c (c).
97
Id. §§ 1692c (b), (d).
98
Id. §§ 1692b (4)–(5), 1692d (d), 1692f (7).
99
Id. §§ 1692b (6), 1692c (a)(2).
100
Id. § 1692d.
101
Id. §§ 1692e (7)–(8), (10).
102
Id. § 1692a (6).
103
Id. § 1692k (a).
104
Brian Highsmith & Margot Saunders, The Rent-To-Own Racket: Using Criminal Courts
to Coerce Payments from Vulnerable Families, N
ATL CONSUMER L. CTR. 2 (Feb. 2019),
https://www.nclc.org/images/pdf/criminal-justice/report-rent-to-own-racket.pdf.
105
Id. at 3.
106
Id. at 4. In these situations, dealers use intimidation tactics on customers struggling to
make payments on their rent-to-own contracts. Id. at 3, 9.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 165 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 165 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1456 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
property.”
107
NCLC attorneys also describe how state agencies such as prosecutors’ offices
and the police are being used by the rent-to-own dealers.
108
State theft laws vary
widely. Some explicitly apply to rent-to-own contracts, while others are silent on
whether they apply to rent-to-own transactions.
109
Some state statutes base the se-
verity of the offense on the value of the property (i.e., misdemeanor versus felony)
and are particularly concerning because of the high mark-up on the property being
rented in these contracts.
110
For example, someone arrested for theft of a TV worth
$200 at retail might be charged with stealing property worth $1200 if that’s what
the inflated “cash price” of the TV is in the rent-to-own agreement.
111
Thus a simple
failure to pay a consumer debt, a civil collection suit, becomes first a criminal mis-
demeanor charge that can then be inflated to a felony conviction which carries all
of the consequences of serious criminal behavior, including inability to vote, obtain
employment, etc.
3. Other Federal Laws
The Consumer Leasing Act, enacted by Congress in 1976, applies to consumer
leases that obligate the consumer for more than four months.
112
The Act requires
lessors to disclose the initial payment, any official fees or other incidental charges,
and the number, amount, total amount, and due dates of the periodic payments,
but does not require the disclosure of a finance charge or an annual percentage rate
107
Id. at 3. Only three states specifically exclude RTO transactions from their theft statutes:
Connecticut, South Carolina, and Virginia. Id. at 12.
108
Id. at 11.
109
Id. at 12.
110
Id. at 13.
111
Advocates suggest that state laws be passed to protect consumers from being targeted by
rent-to-own dealers. Some suggested provisions explicitly excluding rent-to-own contracts from
theft statutes, requiring specific proof that the defendant intended to steal the property,
establishing a civil legal process through which rent-to-own deals and consumers can resolves
disputes, and regulating coercive collection strategies by imposing legal liability for threatening
arrest with no reasonable basis. Id. at 3; see also Shannon Najmabadi & Jay Root, New Texas Law
Protects Rent-to-own Customers Against Criminal Prosecution, T
EXAS TRIBUNE (June 21, 2019, 9:00
AM), https://www.texastribune.org/2019/06/21/new-texas-law-protects-rent-own-customers-
against-criminal-prosecution/ (describing the passage of this kind of state law). There is also the
FCRA, but this act is used by creditors and non-creditors alike. KaydenPhoenix2011, Credit
Advice, CREDIT KARMA (May 19, 2011), https://www.creditkarma.com/question/does-leasing-
furniture-and-other-items-help-boost-a-credit-score/. Rent-to-own establishments send mixed
signals on whether they do or do not report credit, but one thing is clear: if they do not, that does
not help one’s credit, and taking out a regular loan does. Ciaran John, Does Rent to Own Help
Your Credit?, T
HE NEST, https://budgeting.thenest.com/rent-own-credit-23222.html (last visited
Oct. 21, 2020).
112
Truth in Lending Act (TILA), 15 U.S.C. § 1667 (1) (2018).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 166 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 166 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1457
because the lessor is not extending credit.
113
These requirements are extremely min-
imal,
114
yet the rent-to-own industry need not even comply with these laws because
rent-to-own contracts do not obligate the consumer beyond the one week or one
month rental.
The ECOA prohibits a creditor from discriminating against an applicant on
the basis of race, color, religion, national origin, sex, marital status, age, or receipt
of public assistance.
115
Since rent-to-own deals are allegedly not credit, rent-to-own
dealers are allowed to discriminate. The FCPA requires those who collect payments
on debts to report on such activity in a fair and accurate manner,
116
but these re-
quirements do not apply of course if rent-to-own transactions do not involve the
extension of credit.
117
4. State Usury Laws
Another set of laws that rent-to-own dealers seek to avoid is usury laws, or laws
that cap the interest rates that a lender can charge on loans.
118
To establish a usury
claim at common law, a plaintiff must ordinarily prove the following: (i) a loan of
money or forbearance of debt, (ii) an agreement that the principal shall be repayable
absolutely, (iii) the exaction of a greater amount of interest than is allowed by law,
and (iv) an intention to evade the law at the inception of the transaction.
119
Sixteen states plus the District of Columbia have usury caps ranging from 12%
113
Id. at § 1667a (9).
114
See Martin & Huckins, supra note 54, at 391 n.42, stating that:
The industry has recognized that because the provisions of the Consumer Leasing Act are so
“benign,” some RTO dealers might attempt to conform their agreements to its requirements.
Ed Winn III, Looking at Leasing, PROGRESSIVE RENTALS, Dec. 1994/Jan. 1995, at 10.
Legal counsel to the Association of Progressive Rental Organizations, a RTO trade group,
advises caution to dealers considering such action for the following reasons: 1) advertising
“no obligation,” a particular attraction of RTO, might subject them to charges of false ad-
vertising; 2) RTO customers are quite likely to return the merchandise during the initial
four-month rental period; if dealers, to avoid expenses, do not take default judgments, they
may be viewed as not really being in the leasing business, but they would no longer be in
compliance with state RTO statutes; 3) the availability of a purchase option becomes an issue
because, if one is offered, it has to be for a price greater then [sic] “nominal” or the transaction
may be characterized as a sale, subjecting the transaction to the TILA and state installment
sales statutes.
Id. at 12–13; FED. DEPOSIT INS. CORP., CONSUMER COMPLIANCE EXAMINATION MANUAL V-7.1
(Sep. 2015), https://www.fdic.gov/regulations/compliance/manual/5/v-7.1.pdf.
115
Equal Credit Opportunity Act (ECOA), 15 U.S.C. § 1691 (2018).
116
Fair Credit Reporting Act (FCRA), 15 U.S.C. § 1681(a) (2018).
117
Rent-to-own agencies surely use the credit reporting system to check on customer’s
creditworthiness, so they are using the system and they should also report to it.
118
Miller v. Colortyme, Inc., 518 N.W.2d 544, 549–50 (Minn. 1994).
119
Id. at 549.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 166 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 166 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1458 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
to 36% per annum. Minnesota is one of those states.
120
As a result, in Miller v.
Colortyme, the Minnesota Supreme Court had to decide if a rent-to-own transaction
was a credit transaction because if so, the transaction involved an interest rate well
above the Minnesota interest rate cap.
121
The court ultimately held that rent-to-
own transactions were credit sales and thus subject to general usury laws.
122
Naturally, being able to get out from under usury caps is a tremendous benefit
for a creditor. For example, payday lenders, which charge 300% per annum or more,
cannot operate in states with usury caps.
123
If rent-to-own transactions are not
credit, they need not comply with usury laws and can charge whatever they want.
C. Recourse Versus Non-recourse Debt, Article 9, and the Scope and Legislative
History of Article 9
Secured debt comes in two types: recourse debt, in which the creditor can pur-
sue the debtor for the full amount even if the collateral doesn’t cover it, and non-
recourse debt, where the creditor can only realize on the collateral for the debt, once
the debtor stops paying.
124
Article 9 covers all security interests, whether the debt is
recourse or non-recourse.
125
Several industries that look like they are providing se-
cured credit are claiming that their products are not credit at all but something else.
This Section describes these different types of secured credit and why we care if a
vendor is providing secured credit.
1. Rent-to-Own Debt is Non-recourse Debt, but Debt Nevertheless
The industry’s most consistent and compelling argument for why rent-to-own
is not credit is that customers can end the relationship at any time, surrender the
rented goods, and not be liable for the remaining lease payments. As the New Jersey
Supreme Court noted in Perez v. Rent-A-Center, however, this one fact is not deter-
minative on the issue of whether something is credit or something else.
126
Function-
ally, rent-to-own transactions involve non-recourse debt, a type of debt for which
the creditor does not seek additional payment after default, but relies solely on its
collateral post-default.
120
Payday Loan Consumer Information, CONSUMER FEDN AMERICA, https://
paydayloaninfo.org/state-information (last visited Dec. 21, 2020).
121
Miller, 518 N.W.2d at 546.
122
Id. at 548.
123
Nathalie Martin, Public Opinion and the Limits of State Law: The Case for Federal Usury
Caps, 34 N.
ILL. U. L. REV. 259, 266, 268–71 (2014).
124
Julia Kagan, Defining Limited Recourse Debt, INVESTOPEDIA, https://investopedia.com/
terms/l/limitedrecoursedebt.asp (last visited Dec. 20, 2020).
125
U.C.C. § 1-901(a) (AM. LAW. INST. & UNIF. LAW COMMN 2019) (“. . . [T]his article
applies to . . . a transaction, regardless of its form, that creates a security interest in personal
property or fixtures by contract . . .”).
126
Perez v. Rent-a-Ctr., Inc., 892 A.2d 1255, 1270 (N.J. 2006).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 167 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 167 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1459
Non-recourse or limited recourse debt is debt for which the creditor agrees not
to pursue the borrower for any additional payments once it repossesses its collat-
eral.
127
With recourse debt, the lender has the legal right to collect not just from the
collateral, but also from the debtor’s other assets upon default.
128
Recourse debt can
either be full recourse or limited recourse.
129
Full recourse debt allows the lender to
seize and sell the debtor’s assets, through the state execution and collections pro-
cess.
130
Limited recourse or non-recourse debt contracts forbid the lender from collect-
ing except from limited assets, typically just its collateral.
131
This type of debt “gives
the lender a limited amount of recourse to the borrower’s other assets in the event
of default.”
132
If the borrower defaults on his or her payments, the lender can exer-
cise its rights to repossess its collateral, but that’s it. If the collateral is insufficient to
cover the entire debt, the borrower is not personally liable for the deficiency or
shortfall between the amount of unpaid debt and the amount realized on the collat-
eral.
133
Non-recourse loans are not limited to home loans.
134
Any time the lender relies
solely on the value of its collateral for collection, the debt is non-recourse debt. Rent-
to-own contracts create just that, non-recourse debt. It is not that the transactions
are leases, as both parties prefer that the customer ultimately own the property and
in most cases that is what happens.
135
Rather, rent-to-own transactions create debt
for which the lender intends to rely solely on its collateral for repayment. Rent-to-
own contracts in which the customer can end the relationship at any time by just
returning the goods have all of the attributes of non-recourse debt. Non-recourse
debt is debt, nevertheless.
2. The Side-Step Around Article 9
As we have seen, creditors extending credit on a secured or unsecured basis
benefit in many ways by calling their products something other than “credit.” One
127
Kagan, supra note 124.
128
Id.
129
Id.
130
Id.
131
Id.
132
Id.
133
Id.
134
For example, “[a]uction houses and art specialists, on the other hand, provide non-
recourse loans and their decisions are based solely on the value of the art and its risk. The
borrower’s guarantee is not required in order to approve a non-recourse loan, and the main
criterion is the art itself, not the creditworthiness of the borrower.” William N. Goetzmann &
Milad Nozari, Art as Collateral 5 (Yale ICF, Working Paper No. 2018-01, 2020),
https://ssrn.com/abstract=3099054.
135
Lacko, supra note 9, at ES-2.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 167 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 167 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1460 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
benefit is escaping the purview of Article 9 of the U.C.C., which governs reposses-
sions, forfeiture, and creditor liability. In the first scholarly article on rent-to-own,
Professor James Nehf noted the industry’s particular interest in avoiding Article 9’s
repossession provisions.
136
The scope of Article 9 has always been broad, to keep lenders from disguising
their transactions as leases for the purpose of escaping the protections of the U.C.C.
As one court explained:
[Article 9 was drafted, in part,] [t]o avoid the dismal history under which
legislatures drafted laws to govern security arrangements and clever lawyers
routinely escaped the grasp of such laws by devising ingenious documents that
suited their clients’ needs . . . . [The Code instructs that, with limited excep-
tions, Article 9 applies regardless of] whether title in collateral is in the secured
party or the debtor . . . . The drafters . . . took this step with the intention
“that its provisions should not be circumvented by manipulation of the locus
of title.”
137
Ensuring that Article 9 applies to disguised security interest is critical to, among
other things, avoiding forfeitures of equity similar to that which occurred in the
infamous Walker Furniture case, in which a low-income woman made most of her
installment payments on various household goods, but defaulted at the end and lost
everything.
138
The drafters of Article 9 also sought to avoid unfair collection and
repossession.
139
136
Nehf, supra note 59, at 752.
137
In re Jeff Benfield Nursery, Inc., 565 B.R. 603, 613 (Bankr. W.D.N.C. 2017).
138
Williams v. Walker-Thomas Furniture Co., 350 F.2d 445, 447 (D.C. Cir. 1965).
139
As Nehf explains:
If the agreement is deemed to have created a security interest, the state’s version of Article 9
will impose several restraints on the repossessing firm that do not apply to lessors. For in-
stance, after a dealer lawfully repossesses, the consumer has a right under section 9-506 to
cure the default by tendering the amount secured by the obligation. If default is not cured
and the dealer decides to retain the collateral (instead of selling it or re-renting it to another
customer), section 9-505 requires the dealer to give written notice of the proposed retention
to the consumer, and if the consumer does not object, the dealer may keep the collateral in
full satisfaction of the debt and the consumer would not owe any additional amount. Reten-
tion is not permitted, however, where the consumer has paid 60% of the original purchase
price; the dealer must then sell or lease the goods within ninety days unless the consumer
signs a waiver of this right. Most importantly, under section 9-504 if the dealer sells or leases
the repossessed property, it must notify the consumer before the disposition and account to
the consumer for any surplus realized from the sale or lease above the amount owed. Because
the percentage of RTO contracts that result in repossessions is relatively high, the notice and
accounting requirements of Article 9 would impose a substantial administrative burden on
RTO operations. Noncompliance would subject the dealer to a statutory damages formula
which, particularly in a class action alleging a pattern of noncompliance, could be substantial.
Nehf, supra note 59, at 789–90.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 168 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 168 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1461
As explained below, the original U.C.C. distinguished between leases and con-
tracts by looking at the economic realities of the transaction. The customer’s option
to get out of the deal before the end of the lease was one factor, but not determina-
tive.
140
Under former section 1-201(37), courts balanced many factors to determine
if a lease was a true lease or a security interest.
141
Under most of these analyses, rent-
to-own transactions were deemed disguised security interests, which were covered
by Article 9 and were thus subject to all of the protections of both the U.C.C. as
well as all other credit-related laws.
142
Courts focused on a variety of objective facts
related to the leasing transaction, such as the terms of the lease and any option, the
140
If a “lease” includes a purchase option for nominal or no consideration, then it is
presumed to be intended as a security agreement and not a lease, unless the option price bears a
resemblance to the fair market value of the property. In re Phoenix Pipe & Tube, L.P., 38 U.C.C.
Rep. Serv. 2d 28, *2 (E.D. Pa. June 8, 1993). A purported lease is actually a secured sales contract
and therefore does not constitute a true lease when the parties apparently intended the lease as
security, as demonstrated by the debtor’s option to purchase the “leased” equipment at the end of
the lease term. Although the lease may not contain explicit language granting a security interest,
the practical effect of the lease is to create a security interest if the lease is intended as security. In
re Village Import Enters., 126 B.R. 307, 308 (Bankr. E.D. Tenn. 1991). The Code recognizes
that a secured sale may be veiled in lease terms. The lease need not contain specific language
granting the security interest. The drafters of the U.C.C. “expected a lease intended as security to
use only lease terms. They did not expect a party to disguise a secured sale as a lease and then give
away the disguise by including words granting the lessor a security interest.” Id. at 308–09; see also
Sutton v. Ryder Truck Rental, Inc., 807 S.W.2d 905, 906–07 (Ark. 1991). An equipment lease
is in reality a secured transaction if the lessee has the right to purchase the equipment for $1.00 at
the end of the lease period. In re McDaniel, 127 B.R. 132, 134 (Bankr. N.D. Tex. 1991).
141
See In re Price, 577 B.R. 643, 653–54 (Bankr. E.D.N.C. 2017) (holding that a purported
lease agreement was a disguised security agreement when the “lessee’s” obligations were not subject
to termination, the “lessee” was obligated for the initial term of the lease, and the option to
purchase the equipment for $1.00 constituted nominal consideration); see also In re Johnson, 571
B.R. 167 (Bankr. E.D.N.C. 2017); In re Ajax Integrated, L.L.C., 554 B.R. 568, 578–79 (Bankr.
N.D.N.Y. 2016); In re Johnson, 86 U.C.C. Rep. Serv. 2d 207, *6–8, *12–13 (S.D. Miss. Mar.
27, 2015); In re Purdy, 763 F.3d 513, 519–21 (6th Cir. 2014); Gib. Fin. Corp. v. Prestige Equip.
Corp., 949 N.E.2d 314, 321 (Ind. 2011); In re Lash, 73 U.C.C. Rep. Serv. 2d 292, *15–16
(Bankr. M.D.N.C. Dec. 9, 2010); In re Bailey, 326 B.R. 156, 161 (Bankr. W.D. Ark. 2005); In
re Super Feeders, Inc., 236 B.R. 267, 269–70 (Bankr. D. Neb. 1999); In re Eagle Enters., 237
B.R. 269, 274–75 (E.D. Pa. 1999).
142
More specifically, former section 1-102(37), which later became section 1-203, provided
that:
Unless a lease or consignment is intended as security, reservation of title thereunder is not a
“security interest.” Whether a lease is intended as security is to be determined by the facts of
each case; however, (a) the inclusion of an option to purchase does not of itself make the
lease one intended for security, and (b) an agreement that upon compliance with the terms
of the lease the lessee shall become or has the option to become the owner of the property
for no additional consideration or for a nominal consideration does make the lease one in-
tended for security.
In re Super Feeders, Inc., 236 B.R. at 269–70.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 168 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 168 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1462 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
amount of equity, if any, that the lessee was acquiring in the leased property, the
amount of rent under the lease compared to the purchase price for the goods if sold
rather than leased, which party insured the property, whether the lessor had dis-
claimed warranties, the value of the property at the end of the lease, and the nature
of the lessor’s business.
143
One very significant factor was whether the lease agree-
ment required that the transferee pay consideration for the use of the goods for a
term that was equal to their economic life, although this one factor was by no means
determinative.
144
Rent-to-own transactions meet many of these fluid factors.
Later, the lease versus security interest provision in Article 9 was moved to sec-
tion 1-203 and amended to make it absolutely necessary for the customer to be
bound to the entire lease term for the full useful life of the leased goods, in order for
a transaction to be a security interest.
145
This new definition created a sea change in
143
The test focused on whether, at the time the lease was executed, it was reasonably
predictable that the “lessor” will have retained more than a nominal residual interest in the goods.
If it had not, the transaction is in fact a secured transaction because the transferee has received the
full economic ownership, and presumably value, in the goods. A thorough discussion of the
difference between a lease and a security interest can be found in C
OOGAN ET AL., SECURED
TRANSACTIONS UNDER THE UCC § 30.02 (2020). See also In re Pillowtex, Inc., 349 F.3d 711,
717–18 (3d Cir. 2003); In re Our Secret, Ltd., 282 B.R. 697, 701–04 (Bankr. D.N.M. 2002);
Leasing One Corp. v. Caterpillar Fin. Servs. Corp., 776 N.E.2d 408, 407, 409–11 (Ind. Ct. App.
2002); In re Hoskins, 266 B.R. 154, 158–59 (Bankr. W.D. Mo. 2001); Citipostal, Inc. v. Unistar
Leasing, 724 N.Y.S.2d 555, 558 (N.Y. App. Div. 2001); Burkhart v. U.S. Commerce Equip. Fin.
LLC., 2001 WL 984915, at *4 (Tenn. Ct. App. Aug. 28, 2001).
144
Some factors deal with an option exercisable by the transferee to renew the lease or to
purchase the goods. An option to purchase the goods does not convert the lease to a sale and
security interest so long as the transferee must pay more than a nominal consideration. The reason
is that the transferee might not exercise the option and thus the transferor has a residual value. If
the lessee does exercise the option to purchase, at that point its purchase of goods is a separate
transaction from the original lease. On the other hand, if the transferee must pay no consideration
or only nominal consideration, the transferee at the time the lease is executed acquires the total
interest in the goods. Hence, the nominal lease is a disguised security interest. Whether a lease is
a lease or a security interest turns most critically, therefore, on whether the additional
consideration paid by the transferee is nominal. C
OOGAN, supra note 143, at § 30.03[1][c].
145
U.C.C. § 1-203 (AM. LAW. INST. & UNIF. LAW COMMN 2017). Specifically, section 1-
203 was amended as follows:
§ 1-203. Lease Distinguished from Security Interest.
(a) Whether a transaction in the form of a lease creates a lease or security interest is deter-
mined by the facts of each case.
(b) A transaction in the form of a lease creates a security interest if the consideration that the
lessee is to pay the lessor for the right to possession and use of the goods is an obligation for the term
of the lease and is not subject to termination by the lessee, and: (1) the original term of the lease
is equal to or greater than the remaining economic life of the goods; (2) the lessee is bound
to renew the lease for the remaining economic life of the goods or is bound to become the
owner of the goods; (3) the lessee has an option to renew the lease for the remaining eco-
nomic life of the goods for no additional consideration or for nominal additional considera-
tion upon compliance with the lease agreement; or (4) the lessee has an option to become
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 169 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 169 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1463
the definition by providing that there was no need to balance any factors and no
security interest at all, if the lease was “subject to termination by the lessee.”
146
Be-
fore this, whether the lessee could terminate was just one factor.
147
Suddenly, if the
customer did not have to pay the entire lease, then it was no longer a secured trans-
action, but a lease regardless of the rest of the economics. Prior to the enactment of
this amendment, courts used at least sixteen different factors, but the one factor that
was determinative to many courts was whether the “lease” granted the “lessee an
option to become the owner of the property for no additional or nominal consider-
ation at the end of the lease.”
148
Rent-to-own transactions by definition contain the
very option upon which former Article 9 and these cases relied.
It is remarkable that this little-talked-about sea change turned the existing test
on its face and made the absolute promise to pay the one determining factor, elim-
inating intent entirely, along with the previously used economic realities test. By
focusing solely on the absolute promise to pay rather than the economic realities,
our U.C.C. also moved away from international standards on the lease/sale distinc-
tion, which focus primarily on whether the lessee has the option to become the
owner of the goods upon full compliance with the terms of the contract.
149
In any
case, before this U.C.C. amendment, the rent-to-own industry got busy passing the
industry-friendly legislation described in the next Part, perhaps just in case the
U.C.C. changed again.
the owner of the goods for no additional consideration or for nominal additional considera-
tion upon compliance with the lease agreement.
Id. (emphasis added).
146
Id.
147
See, e.g., In re Village Import Enters., 126 B.R. at 308.
148
See Nehf, supra note 59, at 793. As Nehf explains, where the lessee can automatically
become the absolute owner of the property at the end of the lease, “periodic lease payments are
indistinguishable from payments under an installment sales contract, and the lessee has in fact
been purchasing the goods over the contract term.” Id. Some courts disagreed, however. “Relying
on the first sentence of section 1-201(37), which provides that a security interest ‘secures payment
or performance of an obligation,’ several courts have held that, despite the possible transfer of
ownership for no additional consideration at the end of the lease, an RTO contract does not create
a security interest because the consumer undertakes no obligation to repay a debt.” Id. at 793–94.
149
See, e.g., Conditional Sales Act, R.S.N.S. 1989, c 84, § 2(1)(b); Mitsui & Co. (Canada)
Ltd. v. Royal Bank of Canada, [1995] 2 S.C.R. 187 (Can.) (in which the Supreme Court of Canada
confirmed that this wording did not limit the scope of the registration provisions of the Nova
Scotia Act, first enacted in 1930, to “disguised conditional sales agreements”—i.e., lease-option
agreements—where it is plain that the lease payments in reality are going toward the purchase of
the leased goods).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 169 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 169 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1464 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
III. THE ANATOMY OF RENT-TO-OWN
This Part describes how rent-to-own works. It helps put these contracts in con-
text by comparing them to pure lease transactions, in which a person rents an item
for a limited period of time with no expectation of ownership. A good example is a
car rented at an airport. The consumer never plans to own the car and is using it for
a short time. “Rent-to-own” or “rental-purchase” transactions are something of a
hybrid.
150
These contracts are typically written as short-term, weekly or monthly,
obligations, but automatically renew for an extended period.
151
Typically, the con-
sumer becomes the owner on completion of payments over that span.
152
Rent-to-own companies fall within the broad category of lenders who provide
“loans” to low-income consumers at high costs.
153
Other lenders in this category
include payday lenders, tax-refund-anticipation loan providers, traditional check
cashers, foreign remittance shops, auto-title pawn stores, and traditional pawn
shops, all of which share certain predatory characteristics.
154
For the most part, these
lenders are clustered in low-income neighborhoods or outside military bases, their
products are poorly regulated, often with triple-digit interest rates, they sometimes
operate under safe-harbor laws drafted by the industry itself, they sometimes use
threatening bullying tactics to collect debts and late payments, and their products
are often designed to keep consumers in perpetual debt.
155
The name “rent-to-own” says it all. Rent-to-own contracts offer the allure of
renting in order to someday own. Indeed, the majority of rent-to-own customers
hope to someday own the item outright.
156
The cost of these transactions is three or
four times the cash price for the item.
157
150
Martin & Huckins, supra note 54, at 385–86 (discussing typical rent-to-own
transactions); David L. Ramp, Renting to Own in the United States, 24 C
LEARINGHOUSE REV. 797,
797 (1990) (discussing rent-to-own contracts).
151
Id. at 797, 809.
152
Id. at 797.
153
Ed Mierzwinski, The Poor Still Pay More: The Small-Loan Industry Preys on Low-Income
Americans Who Often Have No Choice but to Accept Their Outrageous Payment Terms. But This Big
Business May Be Facing Trouble, 44 T
RIAL 40, 42 (2008).
154
Id.
155
Id. (noting that the “mom-and-pop lenders” of the 1960s are now called rent-to-own
stores, and “sell the American dream of ownership of furniture, appliances, computers, jewelry,
automobile wheel sets, and wide-screen TVs. Business Week said rent-to-own businesses have 8%
(about $20 billion) of the $250 billion ‘poverty business.’”).
156
Lacko, supra note 9, at ES-2.
157
Id. at ES-3.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 170 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 170 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1465
A. Rent-to-Own Fundamentals
Rent-to-own contracts are highly popular and have been since the 1960s.
158
In
2016, the Association of Progressive Rental Organizations reported revenue of $8.6
billion in the United States and also reported an estimated customer count of 4
million between brick and mortar stores and e-commerce.
159
Rent-to-own agree-
ments enable a consumer to rent a product for a set time period without a credit
check or substantial down payment.
160
The consumer is then given the option to
purchase that product by either paying a substantially higher purchase price, or by
completing all self-renewing payments for the set time period.
161
The consumer can
also terminate the agreement at any point with no penalty.
162
According to the con-
tract terms, by just stopping the agreed upon payments, the contract ceases and the
vendor will come and pick up the product.
163
Rent-to-own transaction rates are undeniably high.
164
For example, consider a
typical transaction involving a $300 television. The rent-to-own agreement listed a
seemingly reasonable weekly payment of $16 and after 52 payments, the consumer
would own the television for the total cost of $832.
165
This transaction amounts to
an APR of 254%, though APRs are not provided to customers as we discussed above
in connection with the truth-in-lending analysis.
166
For comparison purposes, the
average APR for credit cards in the United States in 2019 was 15.05% for all ac-
counts.
167
B. Unprecedented Self-Regulation
While rent-to-own transactions appear to us to be disguised security inter-
ests,
168
due to enabling statutes lobbied into law by the rent-to-own industry, they
158
Id. at 2.
159
Richard May, The Shape of Rent-to-Own by the Numbers, ASSN OF PROGRESSIVE RENTAL
ORG. (Aug. 7, 2017), https://www.rtohq.org/2017/08/shape-rent-numbers/.
160
Lacko, supra note 9, at ES-3.
161
Id.
162
Id.
163
Id. at 4.
164
Nehf, supra note 59, at 752.
165
The Consumer Rental Purchase Agreement Act: Hearing on H.R. 1701 Before the Subcomm.
on Fin. Inst. and Consumer Credit of the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs., 107th Cong. 99 (2001)
(statement of Margot Sanders, Managing Attorney, National Consumer Law Center).
166
See supra notes 75–91 and accompanying text.
167
Consumer Credit - G.19, BOARD OF GOVERNORS OF THE FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM
(Aug. 7, 2020, 3:00 PM), https://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/g19/current/g19.pdf.
168
A disguised security interest has been defined by the Fifth Circuit as a transaction labeled
as a lease, but where the agreement is not subject to cancellation by the lessee, and the lessee is
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 170 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 170 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1466 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
are regulated under their own industry-written laws. Few purveyors of credit services
have organized as relentlessly as the rent-to-own industry. Considering payday lend-
ers, mortgage lenders, debt collectors, rent-to-own landlords, credit-reporting agen-
cies, and every other purveyor of credit, none have sought so hard to pass their own
extensive regulatory framework, on both a state and national level.
In the 1980s, the rent-to-own industry convinced more than forty-five state
legislatures ‘to adopt its preferred safe-harbor legislation—treating week-to-
week contracts as renewable leases, not as purchases over time—thus exempt-
ing the business from state small-loan usury ceilings, retail installment sales
acts, and other credit sale laws.’
169
According to many, the industry regulation is toothless and, essentially, non-
regulation.
170
According to James Nehf, the industry sprang up once federal disclosure laws,
like TILA, made it more expensive to lend to low-income individuals.
171
By arguing
that this service was not credit at all, but rather merely renting an item one might
ultimately own, companies could avoid all the new (at the time) federal regula-
tion.
172
They could also avoid Article 9.
173
Avoiding these two regulatory schemes
seemed to be the primary goal of the legislation.
174
As we explained in Part II.B.2 above, the current Article 9 does not cover the
transactions in any case, so the rush to legislate out of it is mysterious. Perhaps the
industry feared that the law would change back, and they would then be subject to
Article 9 as they were under prior U.C.C. law. The primary obligations of Article 9
are to provide notice of default before repossession, to not breach the peace when
bound to become the owner of the goods. In re Pioneer Health Servs., Inc., 759 F. App’x. 240,
243–44 (5th Cir. 2018).
169
Mierzwinski, supra note 153, at 42.
170
See H.R. REP. NO. 107-590, pt. 1, at 37 (2002) (testimony of Hon. Maxine Waters),
stating that:
[t]he Consumer Rental Purchase Agreement Act is special interest legislation at its very worst.
The bill is falsely presented by its industry proponents as pro-consumer and as not pre-emp-
tive of state law. Neither is true. The bill has one purpose and one purpose only: to circum-
vent stronger consumer protections in the Federal Truth-in-Lending Act and in the statutes
of a handful of States that the rent-to-own industry has not been able to overturn.
Id.; see also The Consumer Rental Purchase Agreement Act: Hearing on H.R. 1701 Before the
Subcomm. on Fin. Inst. and Consumer Credit of the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs., 107th Cong. 38
(2001) (statement of Hon. Julia Carson); Consumer Credit Protection Act: Hearing on S. 1152
Before the Subcomm. on Consumer Affairs of the S. Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs,
98th Cong. 1 (1983) (statement of Sen. Paula Hawkins, Chairman, Subcomm. on Consumer
Affairs).
171
Nehf, supra note 59, at 754–55.
172
Id.
173
Id.
174
Id. at 821–22.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 171 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 171 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1467
repossessing, to provide notice of sale of the collateral, to return any surplus back to
the borrower after the sale, if there is one, and to allow the borrower to reclaim the
goods before a sale.
175
One goal of Article 9 is to avoid a forfeiture if there is value
in a repossessed item, and rent-to-own transactions necessarily permit such a forfei-
ture.
176
Since the companies also can re-rent the same repossessed items to other
customers, forfeiture can be more nefarious. Forfeiture of equity deprives customers
of their right to the benefit from the companies’ normal, contractual mitigation of
damages.
177
The industry is also deeply opposed to compliance with TILA, the law that
requires lenders to state the APR on a loan so that customers can compare the cost
of various forms of credit and the credit offered by various providers.
178
In his em-
pirical study of rent-to-own companies, Professor Jim Hawkins found that rent-to-
own companies uniformly reported that, if they had to comply with the obligations
to state an APR for their products, they would leave that market or stop operating
in that state.
179
This extreme desire to not disclose the cost of credit is also mysteri-
ous.
The desire to avoid all forms of consumer credit regulation has been articulated
often. According to Martin and Huckins:
The industry is very concerned with maintaining its unique position in the
marketplace, neither sale nor lease, in order to keep its favorable legal treat-
ment. For example, APRO has counseled its members to avoid marketing
techniques that bring it too close to retail sales. . . . Under a flex-term plan,
for example, the store offers to rent an item for, perhaps, $40 a month, in
which case the customer would become the owner in two years, or for $70 a
month, in which case it would take only one year to own. APRO legal counsel
explains that such a plan makes the term “fair rental value” meaningless and
suggests that the customer is doing something other than merely renting the
item for a month. If the customer merely rents for one month on the $70
plan, he has not gotten anything for his extra $30 a month, creating an unfair,
deceptive transaction.
180
The industry wants to have it both ways. Both they and their customers intend
for the transaction to be an outright sale, and hope that it will be, but they want to
175
Id. at 789–90.
176
Id. at 790–91.
177
See id. at 789–90.
178
The rent-to-own industry likes to call itself a “service,” as if this will preclude the
transaction from being credit. The fact that this is a service, does not make it not credit. All credit
is a service. See Alexandrov, Grodzicki & Bedre-Defolie, supra note 32, at 2 (describing credit as
a service).
179
Jim Hawkins, supra note 12, at 2103–05.
180
Martin & Huckins, supra note 54, at 412 n.187.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 171 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 171 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1468 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
avoid regulation by being governed by lease, rather than credit laws.
181
C. Rent-to-Own Regulation
All but four U.S. states passed industry-sponsored regulation in some form or
another.
182
This Part briefly reviews some of the primary provisions of most of these
laws, typically called Rental Purchase Agreement Acts (“Acts”).
183
The key provi-
sions are that rent-to-own transactions are not “credit transactions” and that rent-
to-own transactions are not covered by either Article 9 or Article 2 of the U.C.C.
184
Given that the transactions are deemed not to be “credit transactions” under these
statutes, they are regulated to a far lesser degree,
185
to the detriment of their typically
disadvantaged customers. The regulations mandate minimum disclosures but few
“substantive limits on the transaction in areas consumer representatives deem most
abusive.”
186
1. The Substance (or Lack Thereof) of Rental Purchase Agreement Acts
To fall within these Acts, the contract must be an agreement for the “use of
goods by an individual for personal, family or household purposes, for an initial
period of four months or less, that is automatically renewable with each payment
after the initial period, that does not obligate or require the consumer to continue
renting or using the goods beyond the initial period and that permits the consumer
to become the owner of the goods.”
187
The first key is to make sure the transactions
are four months long or less, even though they can be renewed as long as it takes to
purchase the item.
188
The meat of the Acts are the disclosures. The primary disclosures require a
description of the goods and whether they are new or used;
189
a statement of the
cash price of the goods, which is illusory;
190
disclosure of periodic payments and
due dates and a total of these payments due in order to own the item; along with an
explanation of how to purchase items at the end of the “lease” or in an early purchase
option. There also must be a disclosure about who must maintain the items; whether
181
Anderson & Jackson, supra note 12, at 304.
182
Id.
183
See, e.g., Rental-Purchase Agreement Act, N.M. Stat. Ann. § 57-26-1 (1995).
184
Anderson & Jackson, supra note 12, at 304.
185
Id.
186
Nehf, supra note 59, at 815.
187
N.M. Stat. Ann. § 57-26-2G (1995).
188
See id. The statute also exempts mobile homes and a few other transactions like safety
deposit boxes. N.M.
STAT. ANN. §§ 57-26-A (3), (5) (1995).
189
N.M. STAT. ANN. § 57-26-5A(4) (1995).
190
Disclosure of the cash price is meaningless, though, because no one goes into a rent-to
own establishment to buy outright and stores can set the cash price at any level they want. Nehf,
supra note 59, at 822–23.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 172 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 172 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1469
the consumer is liable for loss or damage to the goods and who must insure the
goods;
191
a statement that the consumer will not own the goods until the consumer
has paid the total amount necessary to acquire ownership,
192
and a statement that
the consumer may terminate the rental-purchase agreement without penalty by vol-
untarily surrendering the goods “in good repair, reasonable wear and tear excepted,
along with any past due rental payments upon expiration of any rental period.”
193
While lessee rent-to-own companies are provided with explicit damages under
the Act, there is no section providing damages for lessor consumers. One could read
the Act as providing no right to sue by a consumer lessor, but the Act also says that
“[t]his subsection does not bar a consumer then in default on an obligation from
asserting a violation of the Rental-Purchase Agreement Act as an original action or
as a defense or counterclaim to an action brought by a lessor against the con-
sumer.”
194
As for lessee damages,
195
lessees can recover the greater of actual damages
for breach or 25% of the total payments required to owns the item, but only be-
tween $100 and $1,000.
196
Consumers are also liable for costs and attorneys’ fees,
197
and cannot offset their own damages.
198
Regarding the statute of limitations, all
suits must be filed within one year of the last rental payment or within one year of
the rental-agreement violation.
199
Given that a consumer is not likely to know he
or she must sue within a year, this is incredibly short, especially for a contract. Con-
tracts statute of limitations are usually four years.
200
Lessees also have a few defenses,
none particularly generous.
201
This disclosure-based Act falls far short of the protections one gets with other
credit products, such as disclosure of interest rates under TILA, recovery of sur-
pluses, and notice of repossession under Article 9.
191
See N.M. STAT. ANN. §§ 57-26-5A(3), (9) (1995).
192
Id. § 57-26-5A(2).
193
Id. § 57-26-5A(10).
194
N.M. STAT. ANN. § 57-26-11B (1995).
195
Id. § 57-26-11A.
196
Id. § 57-26-11A(1).
197
Id. § 57-26-11A(2).
198
“A consumer may not take any action to offset the amount for which a lessor is potentially
liable under subsection A of this section against any amount owed by the consumer unless the
amount of the lessor’s liability has been determined by judgment of a court of competent
jurisdiction in an action in which the lessor was a party.” Id. at § 57-26-11B.
199
Id. § 57-26-11D.
200
U.C.C. § 2-725 (AM. LAW. INST. & UNIF. LAW COMMN 2017).
201
See Brian Highsmith & Margot Saunders, The Rent-To-Own Racket: Using Criminal
Courts to Coerce Payments from Vulnerable Families, N
ATL CONSUMER L. CTR. 1, 14–15 (Feb.
2019), https://www.nclc.org/images/pdf/criminal-justice/report-rent-to-own-racket.pdf.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 172 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 172 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1470 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
2. Case Law on Rent-to-Own
In Minnesota, New Jersey, North Carolina, and Wisconsin, the industry-spon-
sored legislation did not pass due to fairness concerns for consumers.
202
Under the
existing consumer credit statutes of these states, rent-to-own contracts are credit
transactions,
203
and therefore, in those states, the transactions are considered credit
transactions.
204
The cases rely on each state’s definition of a consumer credit sale.
205
202
Bruce Speight & Greg Hart, Rent-to-Own Ripoff: Why Wisconsin Shouldn’t Exempt the
Predatory Rent-to-Own Industry from Consumer Protection Laws, W
IS. PUB. INT. RES. GROUP (May
13, 2013), https://wispirg.org/sites/pirg/files/reports/The%20Rent-to-Own%20Ripoff.pdf.
Speight & Hart state that:
While some 46 states have enacted industry-friendly laws with these and other weak provi-
sions, a few states, including New Jersey, Wisconsin, Minnesota and Vermont, enforce tough
consumer protection laws. Unable to win in all state legislatures, the RTO industry has also
asked Congress to preempt, or over-ride, these strong state consumer protection laws and
replace them with a weak industry-friendly federal law; thus far, that effort has failed.
Id.; see also Highsmith & Saunders, supra note 201 (observing, in Appendix: State Laws
Authorizing RTO Transactions and Criminalizing Failure to Rental Property, that all states have
laws authorizing RTO transactions except Minnesota, New Jersey, North Carolina, and
Wisconsin).
203
Minnesota, New Jersey, and Wisconsin both require APR disclosures because judicial
decisions have held that the transactions fall within each state’s respective Consumer Credit Sales
Act. See Miller v. Colortyme, Inc., 518 N.W.2d 544, 548, 549 (Minn. 1994) (concluding that
rent-to-own transactions were credit sales under Minnesota’s Consumer Credit Sales Act); see also
Perez v. Rent-a-Ctr., Inc., 892 A.2d 1255, 1270 (N.J. 2006); Rent-A-Ctr., Inc. v. Hall, 510
N.W.2d 789, 795 (Wis. Ct. App. 1993) (holding that Wisconsin’s consumer credit sale act
covered rent-to-own transactions). Also, Vermont requires disclosure but does not call these
“credit.” V
T. STAT. ANN. tit. 9, § 41b(a) (2015); VT. C.P.R. 115.04(b)(4) (1997) (requiring
disclosure on price tag); V
T. C.P.R. 115.04(b)(1) (1997) (requiring disclosure in contract). Nine
other states impose statutory limits on the total costs that rent-to-own firms may charge customers:
Connecticut, Hawaii, Iowa, Maine, Michigan, New York, Ohio, Pennsylvania, and West
Virginia. See Hawkins, supra note 12, at 2108 n.319 (citing Ed Winn III, APRO’s Legal Counsel,
Mem http://www.rtohq.org/rent-to-own/wp-content/uploads/LegUpdate_2006.pdf (last visited
Mar. 29, 2019)).
204
See, e.g., Perez, 892 A.2d at 1270; Miller, 518 N.W.2d at 549.
205
For example, the Wisconsin statute reads:
(9) ”Consumer credit sale” means a sale of goods, services or an interest in land to a customer
on credit where the debt is payable in installments or a finance charge is imposed and in-
cludes any agreement in the form of a bailment of goods or lease of goods or real property if
the bailee or lessee pays or agrees to pay as compensation for use a sum substantially equiva-
lent to or in excess of the aggregate value of the goods or real property involved and it is
agreed that the bailee or lessee will become, or for no other or a nominal consideration has
the option to become, the owner of the goods or real property upon full compliance with
the terms of the agreement.
WIS. STAT. § 421.301 (2020). Minnesota’s statute reads as follows:
Subd. 2. Consumer credit sale. — ”Consumer credit sale” means a sale of goods or services
in which:
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 173 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 173 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1471
D. The Demographics of the Typical Rent-to-Own Customer
The best available data on rent-to-own usage and demographics, as well as cus-
tomer intentions at the time of contracting, comes from a 2000 FTC study involv-
ing interviews with over 500 randomly selected rent-to-own customers.
206
The rent-
to-own industry insists that a large part of its customer base is comprised of well-
heeled customers that rent-to-own to fill a temporary need, such as a large-screen
TV for the Super Bowl.
207
In reality, most rent-to-own consumers are disadvan-
taged.
208
Compared to households that had never used rent-to-own, rent-to-own
customers were more likely to be African-American, were younger and less educated,
and had lower incomes.
209
Rent-to-own customers are far more likely to come from
(a) credit is granted by a seller who regularly engages as a seller in credit transactions of the
same kind;
(b) the buyer is a natural person; and
(c) the goods or services are purchased primarily for a personal, family or household purpose,
and not for commercial, agricultural, or business purpose.
MINN. STAT. § 325G.15 (2019).
206
Lacko, supra note 9, at 1. The major findings of the FTC staff survey included that 2.3%
of United States households had used rent-to-own transactions in the last year, and 4.9% had
done so in the last five years. Id. at 25. This is lower than the usage of payday loans by comparison,
which run 5.5% nationwide. P
EW CHARITABLE TRUSTS, PAYDAY LENDING IN AMERICA: WHO
BORROWS, WHERE THEY BORROW, AND WHY 4 (2012), https://www.pewtrusts.org/-
/media/legacy/uploadedfiles/pcs_assets/2012/pewpaydaylendingreportpdf.pdf.
207
See APRO, THE RENT-TO-OWN INDUSTRY: AN OVERVIEW, https://www.rtohq.org/wp-
content/uploads/2019/06/APRO-Flipbook-About-Us.pdf (last visited Dec. 20, 2020) (“What all
customers have in common is that they have immediate needs for consumer household goods
. . .”).
208
See Eligio Pimentel, Renting-to-Own: Exploitation or Market Efficiency?, 13 LAW & INEQ.
369, 370 (1995); Lee M. Breslau, A Study of Appliance Rental Practices: Appliance Rentals and
Purchases by Low-Income Consumers, 20 C
LEARINGHOUSE REV. 1515, 1516–17 (1987); see also
Rent-To-Own: Providing Opportunities or Gouging Consumers?: Hearing Before the Comm. on
Banking, Fin. and Urban Affairs, 103rd Cong., 1st Sess. 121–22 (1993) [hereinafter “Hearings”]
(testimony of William Leibovici, Assistant Attorney General of Maryland). In these hearings,
William Leibovici stated that:
Everybody seems to agree that the customers of rent-to-own centers are primarily low-in-
come consumers. . .
. In addition to being low-income, a significant number of rent-to-own
customers are seniors. In 1990, the American Association of Retired Persons (AARP) pro-
duced a Senior Consumer Alert in which it stated ‘Older Persons are prime targets of these
[rent-to-own] come-ons.
Id.
209
Lacko, supra note 9, at 1. The report found that:
Thirty-one percent of rent-to-own customers were African American, 79 percent were 18 to
44 years old, 73 percent had a high school education or less, 59 percent had household in-
comes less than $25,000, 67 percent had children living in the household, 62 percent rented
their residence, 53 percent lived in the South, and 68 percent lived in non-suburban areas.
Id.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 173 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 173 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1472 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
communities of color, as African-Americans and Hispanics appear to be overrepre-
sented in rent-to-own transactions.
210
According to a report written for Rent-A-
Center itself, 38.6% of its rent-to-own customers are African-American and 10.9%
are Hispanic despite that at the time of that report, African-Americans constituted
12.1% of the total population and Hispanics, 9%.
211
These rent-to-own customers
also were more likely to have children at home, rent their homes, and live in the
South.
212
They also were more likely to live in the inner city or the country.
213
Regarding economic condition, most consumers who entered into a rent-to-
own agreement made less money than those who had never entered into a rent-to-
own agreement.
214
They also had less education.
215
Of the customers who returned
their rent-to-own item, 24% did so for financial reasons.
216
Almost half of rent-to-
own customers surveyed reported making late payments.
217
Fifteen percent of late
customers reported poor treatment from the lessee, and 11% reported quasi-abusive
techniques from collections departments.
218
E. What Do Customers Really Want in Rent-to-Own Transactions?
A common claim by industry is that many of their customers are not interested
in buying the item they are renting; rather, most just want to use it for a while.
219
This is largely untrue. Seventy percent of customers buy the item they are renting
and this purchasing rate applies across all demographics.
220
The reason the industry
focuses on customers that do not wish to buy is that it makes the transaction look
more like a true, short-term lease than a lease purchase agreement or a credit trans-
action. Continuing with this charade, the industry claims that, at the moment of
210
Pimentel, supra note 208, at 370–71 n.7 (citing Carl C. Hoffmawn & Robert L. Lovler,
Rent-A-Center Final Report (1994) (prepared for the Board of Directors of Thorn Emi Plc, the
Parent Company of Rent-A-Center)).
211
U.S. DEPT. OF COMMERCE, 1990 CENSUS OF POPULATION GENERAL POPULATION
CHARACTERISTICS UNITED STATES 3 (1990).
212
Lacko, supra note 9, at 1.
213
Id.
214
Id.
215
Id.
216
Id. at 62.
217
Id. at 74.
218
Id.
219
See Anderson & Jackson, supra note 12, at 302, stating that:
The rental phase of RTO is well suited to consumers who find themselves in personal, fi-
nancial, or employment situations that are seen as temporary or unpredictable. For this con-
sumer group of renters, the embedded put option is highly valued while the option to secure
an installment agreement at a later date increases in value through time.
Id.
220
Lacko, supra note 9, at ES-1.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 174 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 174 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1473
entering into the transaction, most customers do not wish to purchase the item.
221
This is also untrue. “Sixty-seven percent of customers intended to purchase the mer-
chandise when they [entered] the . . . transaction, and 87 percent of the customers
intending to purchase actually did [so].”
222
The name of these transactions says it
all: the average person “rents” to “own.”
IV. RENT-TO-OWN HOUSING AND SHADOW CREDIT
A close cousin to the rent-to-own transaction for consumer goods is another
shadow credit transaction, the land sale contract, or contract for deed.
223
These
transactions fall somewhere along the continuum of property rights between owners
and renters and classic home mortgage transactions.
224
Buyers purchase their homes
with installment payments and the seller holds on to title to the land and home until
that last payment is made.
225
These transactions allow people with bad credit or no credit to purchase a
home, at least in theory.
226
In practice, they don’t work as well.
227
In many ways,
these transactions combine the worst aspects of traditional home buying, with the
worst aspects of leasing real estate. The buyers often are responsible for repairs and
also fail to build equity.
228
Due to imbalances of power between buyers and sellers, many of these rent-to-
own home buyers never end up owning the home they pay on for several years.
Rent-to-own homebuyers do not typically become homeowners for several rea-
sons: First, the transactions are often not recorded, so there is no paper trail proving
the buyers have actually purchased anything.
229
Second, even in an honest deal,
221
Id. at 10–11.
222
Id. at ES-2.
223
Genevieve Hébert Fajardo, “Owner Finance! No Banks Needed!” Consumer Protection
Analysis of Seller-Financed Home Sales: A Texas Case Study, 20 G
EO. J. POVERTY L. & POLY 429
(2013); cf. Grant S. Nelson, The Contract for Deed as a Mortgage: The Case for the Restatement
Approach, 1998 BYU L. REV. 1111, 1112 (1997); Elizabeth M. Provencio, Moving from Colonias
to Comunidades: A Proposal for New Mexico to Revisit the Installment Land Contract Debate, 3
MICH. J. RACE & L. 283, 293–95 (1997); Grant S. Nelson & Dale A. Whitman, The Installment
Land Contract-A National Viewpoint, 1977 BYU
L. REV. 541, 541–42 (1977).
224
Nelson, supra note 223, at 1112.
225
Nelson & Whitman, supra note 223, at 541.
226
See Eric T. Freyfogle, The Installment Land Contract as Lease: Habitability Protections and
the Low-Income Purchaser, N.Y.U.
L. REV. 293, 304–05 (1987).
227
See Provencio, supra note 223, at 293–95 (describing the debate surrounding installment
land contracts).
228
See Freyfogle, supra note 226, at 295–96 n.12; see also Nelson, supra note 222, at 1113.
229
See Hébert-Fajardo, supra note 223, at 429 (stating that “[t]here are many examples of
families who pay under a contract for deed for years, only to find out that the home has existing
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 174 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 174 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1474 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
there is the problem of forfeiture of equity when a buyer fails to complete the trans-
action—a particularly common and significant problem if the buyer has paid for a
long time.
230
Consumers lose their homes and their equity.
231
Third, unlike outright purchases, the properties do not get inspected before the
transaction begins, so they often have serious defects that the buyer does not know
about and must fix.
232
These defects would be remedied by the landlord in a tradi-
tional rental relationship.
233
Buyers typically pay a significant down payment, so
walking away is expensive. Finally, the effective interest rates on these deals can be
breathtakingly high, especially when compared to traditional bank loans. Rates of 9
to 18% are not uncommon,
234
compared to current mortgage rates of 2.5 to 4%.
235
Over 30 years, these interest rate differentials can amount to hundreds of thousands
of dollars.
236
Typical installment land contract buyers resemble typical household goods
rent-to-own customers. Contracts for deed are often referred to, fittingly, as a “poor
man’s mortgage.”
237
Buyers are typically low-income and more often persons of
color.
238
Buyers seldom request or even know about inspections, appraisals, and title
liens or that the seller plans to evict them and start over with new buyers.”). Professor Hébert
Fajardoa, tells this story from one of her clinic cases:
Selling to a second buyer then trying to evict: Ms. Alvarado lives with her family in Eagle
Pass, Texas, on the border with Mexico. She signed a contract for deed, making a down
payment of $1500 and paying $400 per month for at least three years. The seller never rec-
orded the contract for deed. In 2011, Ms. Alvarado received an eviction notice saying she
would need to leave the property at the end of the month. The seller had sold the property
to another buyer using another contract for deed.
Id. at 431 (emphasis omitted).
230
See Provencio, supra note 223, at 285; see also Freyfogle, supra note 226, at 312.
231
Provencio, supra note 223, at 287.
232
Freyfogle, supra note 226, at 296 n.12.
233
Id. at 296.
234
See Hébert Fajardo, supra note 223, at 429; Shelayne Clemmer, Texas’s Attempt to
Mitigate the Risks of Contracts for Deed—Too Much for Sellers—Too Little for Buyers, 38 S
T. MARY
L.J. 755, 799 (2007) (describing rates as high as 18% for contracts for deed, contracts in which
seller provides financing to the buyer for the purchase of real property—similar to rent-to-own).
235
BANKRATE, LLC, https://www.bankrate.com (last visited Oct. 21, 2020).
236
Id.
237
Hébert Fajardo, supra note 223, at 429.
238
See Stacy Purcell, The Current Predatory Nature Of Land Contracts And How To
Implement Reforms, 93 N
OTRE DAME L. REV. 1771, 1774 (2018), stating that:
In the first half of the twentieth century, land contracts were largely used by members of
minority groups who were shut out of the traditional home buying market. Racist lending
practices prevented African Americans from receiving bank-financed mortgages, so they
turned to land contracts. For example, in Chicago an estimated eighty-five percent of Afri-
can-American homeowners purchased their home with a land contract. These sales heavily
favored the sellers and were often unjust. As is still the case, buyers rarely completed the
contract term and obtained legal title. Instead, they fell behind on payments and lost their
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 175 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 175 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1475
policies.
239
Buyers rarely know to check title records, or to ensure that their deed is
held in escrow until all payments are made.
240
The New York State Department of Financial Services (DFS) claims that rent-
to-own, lease-to-own, or land installment contracts have become new forms of pred-
atory mortgage lending, noting that they are marketed to vulnerable consumers,
promising a path to homeownership, but having them sign agreements that do not
lead to that coveted result.
241
The state of Wisconsin agrees and is suing Vision
Property Management for “misleading and deceiving business practices [that] in-
duce[s] Wisconsin consumers to lease, rent, or purchase uninhabitable proper-
ties.”
242
Wisconsin claims that the company requires tenants to bear the costs of
rehabilitating the property, curing building code violations and paying back taxes,
and if they do not do so, they are evicted in short order.
243
Even more so than rent-
to-own appliance and electronics transactions, an imbalance of power is a defining
feature of rent-to-own real estate contracts.
244
V. RENT-TO OWN HOUSING SHEDS AND NATIVE AMERICAN
PREDATION
As we have explained, the rent-to own industry has successfully created its own
regulation system in most states. This system defines the rent-to-own business as
one that does not provide credit and thus is not bound by the large suite of laws
applicable to consumer credit transactions. As we have also seen, rent-to-own hous-
ing and real estate contracts have the potential to be particularly harmful to con-
homes. The practice “stripped wealth from African-American communities and led to ‘debt
peonage or impoverishment for many black contract buyers, and . . . decay of the commu-
nities in which such sales were concentrated.’”
Id.
239
See Freyfogle, supra note 226, at 305, stating that:
The typical installment contract home buyer has long appeared to courts as a poorly advised,
poorly protected, often lower-income purchaser . . . Because they do not obtain outside fi-
nancing, they do not benefit from the precautions demanded by typical mortgage lenders:
inspections, appraisals, title reports, termite certificates, and other evidence of a property’s
value.
Id.
240
Id.
241
Mortgage Markets: Regulators Look at Rent-to-Own, 51 MORTGAGE & REAL EST. EXECS.
REP. 6 (2018).
242
Ben Lane, Wisconsin Accuses Rent-to-Own Operator Vision Property Management of
Harming Consumers, H
OUSINGWIRE (June 5, 2017), https://www.housingwire.com/articles/
40339-wisconsin-accuses-rent-to-own-operator-vision-property-management-of-harming-consumers.
243
Id.
244
Cf. Provencio, supra note 223, at 305–06.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 175 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 175 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1476 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
sumers as they capitalize on the strong desire to become homeowners. These trans-
actions frequently result in a forfeiture of equity and all the contract terms are col-
ored by a significant imbalance of power. These same characteristics are present in
a new form of rent-to-own housing that has the potential to be even more predatory
than classic rent-to own contracts or rent-to-own real estate contracts. This Part
describes this new development: rent-to-own shed deals in Native American com-
munities.
A. Native Americans are a Vulnerable Target for Rent-to-Own Shed Deals
Native Americans are particularly vulnerable in terms of financial stability. Less
than 50% of all Native people graduate from high school each year.
245
Conversely,
an average of 93% of non-Native students in the United States obtained a high
school diploma.
246
Poverty and unemployment rates are also higher for Native
Americans than other ethnic groups across the nation.
247
In 2017, only 14.7% of
all Native Americans across the nation had a bachelor’s degree.
248
Over 20% of Na-
tive American families live below the poverty line, which is the highest poverty rate
among all ethnic groups.
249
By comparison, the national poverty level was 11.8%
in 2018.
250
Compounding the problem, many Native people lack understanding of
credit reports and credit scores, which is exacerbated by language barriers and inad-
equate access to technology that could otherwise be used to facilitate financial edu-
cation and consumer research.
251
Many have also taken out high-cost predatory
credit and have compromised credit histories and high rates of loan defaults.
252
245
Education, NATL CONGRESS OF AM. INDIANS, http://www.ncai.org/policy-issues/
education-health-human-services/education (last visited Dec. 21, 2020); see also Gaby Galvin,
Tribal Housing Reveals Inequalities in Indian Country, U.S. N
EWS & WORLD REP. (Sept. 23, 2017,
12:00 AM), https://www.usnews.com/news/best-states/articles/2017-09-23/across-the-us-
disparities-in-indian-country-emerge-through-tribal-housing (discussing inequalities between
different Native groups).
246
U.S. DEPT OF EDUC., NATL CTR. FOR EDUC. STAT. ET AL., 2017 STATUS AND TRENDS
IN THE EDUCATION OF RACIAL AND ETHNIC GROUPS 66 (July 2017).
247
Galvin, supra note 245.
248
U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, Table S1501: 2017 ACS 1-year Estimate Subject Tables-
Educational Attainment, https://data.census.gov/cedsci/table?q=s1501&g=
0100000US&y=2017&
tid=ACSST1Y2017.S1501&hidePreview=true (last visited Dec. 21, 2020).
249
U.S. CENSUS BUREAU, Table S1702: Poverty Status in the Past 12 Months of
Families, https://data.census.gov/cedsci/table?q=S1702&tid=ACSST1Y2019.S1702 (last visited
Dec. 21, 2020).
250
Jessica Smega, et al., Income and Poverty in the United States: 2018, U.S. CENSUS BUREAU
(Sept. 10, 2019), https://www.census.gov/library/publications/2019/demo/p60-266.html.
251
Megan Horning, Border Town Bullies: The Bad Auto Deal and Subprime Lending Problem
Among Navajo Nation Car Buyers, 73 N
ATL LAW. GUILD REV. 193, 205–06 (2016).
252
Valentina Dimitrova-Grajzl, et al., Consumer Credit on American Indian Reservations
(Mar. 26, 2014) (unpublished manuscript at 1–4), https://ssrn.com/abstract=2408747. This may
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 176 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 176 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1477
Higher than average rates of poverty, limited education, and a lack of financial
literacy make Native Americans more vulnerable to risky sales contracts such as rent-
to-own agreements. While rent-to-own agreements involving goods such as appli-
ances and electronics can be harmful, rent-to-own housing transactions are expo-
nentially worse for consumers, especially in Native communities.
B. Housing Crisis in Indian Country
Lack of housing in Indian country makes tribal members especially vulnerable
to alternative housing options.
253
“‘Housing needs are very extreme on tribal lands,’
says Housing and Urban Development (HUD) spokesperson Ed Cabrera. ‘They
face a lot of challenges with sanitation, structural deficiencies, homelessness and
other things we take for granted. There’s been improvement in the past couple of
decades, but there are still major problems.’”
254
The importance of affordable hous-
ing is crucial to lifting tribal members out of poverty, obtaining employment, and
improving overall quality of life.
255
Tribal nations rely heavily on federal funding to
support housing development.
256
HUD allocates blocks of grants and loan guaran-
tee programs to the tribes that, in turn, are used by tribal authorities to increase,
improve, and maintain housing.
257
Unfortunately, this leaves tribal members at the
mercy of the tribal housing authorities to utilize insufficient funding to provide
housing.
258
be due a general lack of financial literacy that is certainly not confined to the Native American
sector of consumers.
253
This was the case for one Tribal Member in New Mexico who, as an adult, lived in her
childhood, three-bedroom home with her parents, two brothers, and niece. Space was tight,
privacy was non-existent, and she was eager to get out on her own. Tina had a high school
diploma. She worked full time as a cashier but only made minimum wage. There were not many
options in her community for housing and what little she found, she couldn’t afford. A relative
offered to rent her his 16’x 24’ shed for $150 per month. To her, 384 square feet for $150 per
month was heaven, compared to the cramped quarters in her family’s home. The shed was
insulated, but had no electricity. Extension cords were run from the relative’s main home out to
the shed so that Tina could plug a couple lights in at night, a fan in the summer, and a small
heater in the winter. Eventually, they installed a window A/C unit and plugged that into the
extension cord as well. Tina lived there for six years despite having no running water or plumbing.
Tina, a Tribal member in New Mexico whose name has been changed for this Article, describes
the reasons why she chose to live in a shed cabin for 6 years, and the experience of living in a shed
cabin. See personal communication with Tina, Mar. 3, 2019.
254
Galvin, supra note 245.
255
Id.
256
See generally Addressing the Housing Crisis in Indian Country: Leveraging Resources and
Coordinating Efforts: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, 112th
Cong. (2012) (discussing federal programs to support housing development in tribal nations).
257
Galvin, supra note 245.
258
See, e.g., id. (describing housing crisis in Navajo Nation).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 176 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 176 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1478 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
The Senate Indian Affairs Committee described the crisis in detail in 2015.
259
An earlier HUD report explained:
Decent housing is not readily available in Indian Country; decent and afford-
able housing is even harder to obtain. Overall, 18.4 percent of homeowners
in Native American areas are cost burdened. This means they are spending
more than 30 percent of their income for housing each month. Affordability
problems are even more common for those who do not own their homes: 31.6
percent of renters on Native American lands are cost burdened.”
260
In the same 2009 evaluation, HUD reported that overcrowding affected 16%
of Native American and Alaska Native households in tribal areas.
261
Seventeen per-
cent of these households had one or more people staying with them solely due to a
lack of housing alternatives.
262
Six percent of the homes in the study had incomplete
plumbing and 7% had incomplete kitchens, compared to less than 2% of all United
States households.
263
The researchers concluded that 68,000 housing units would
be required to eliminate the problem of overcrowding in Native communities.
264
This partly explains why Native communities have been so hard hit by the 2020
Coronavirus pandemic. For example, the largest tribe in the United States, the Nav-
ajo Nation, has a higher infection rate than anywhere else in the nation, including
New York and New Jersey.
265
The difficulty of obtaining a mortgage in Indian Country further compounds
the problem. Land in Indian Country is held in trust by the federal government as
a result of the General Allotment Act of 1887.
266
Tribal trust land may not be en-
cumbered by a lien without overcoming substantial hurdles.
267
While section 184
of the Indian Home Loan Guarantee Program was designed to assist lenders in over-
coming these hurdles and providing mortgages to Tribal members, the barriers are
259
Addressing the Housing Crisis in Indian Country, supra note 256.
260
S. REP. NO. 114-117, at 2 (2015).
261
The Native American Housing Needs Study, U.S. DEPT OF HOUSING & URBAN
DEVELOPMENT, https://www.huduser.gov/portal/pdredge/pdr-edge-research-022117.html (last
visited Dec. 21, 2020).
262
Id.
263
Id.
264
Id.
265
Alexandra Sternlicht, Navajo Nation Has Most Coronavirus Infections Per Capita In U.S.,
Beating New York, FORBES (May 19, 2020, 4:04 PM), https://www.forbes.com/sites/
alexandrasternlicht/2020/05/19/navajo-nation-has-most-coronavirus-infections-per-capita-in-us-
beating-new-york-new-jersey/#3e78f0908b10.
266
U.S. DEPT OF HOUSING & URBAN DEVELOPMENT, OFFICE OF POLICY DEVELOPMENT
& RESEARCH, MORTGAGE LENDING ON TRIBAL LAND: A REPORT FROM THE ASSESSMENT OF
AMERICAN INDIAN, ALASKA NATIVE, AND NATIVE HAWAIIAN HOUSING NEEDS 1 (2017).
267
Id. at 19.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 177 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 177 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1479
still such that lenders are reluctant to engage in the process.
268
Lending through the
section 184 program typically takes six to eight months to close because of the steps
required to overcome the trust status of the land.
269
Despite section 184 providing
a 100% guarantee on the loan, lenders often lack the knowledge and/or desire nec-
essary to take on the process.
270
With inadequate housing available, limited financial resources, and often, com-
promised credit, tribal members look outside of the reservation for housing possi-
bilities. For example, shed dealers recognize this opportunity. Many have situated
themselves near New Mexico pueblos in order to offer rent-to-own shed deals to
tribal members. Many of the sheds marketed look more like welcoming cabins than
what you might use for tool storage. They can be equipped with electricity once
delivered and insulated to provide a livable space. Most appealing, the rent-to-own
contracts require no credit check, no commitment, and little down payment, mak-
ing them appear to be a viable option for financially strapped tribal members. Un-
fortunately, like many consumer credit products, they sound better than they actu-
ally are.
C. Rent-to-Own Shed Dealers: The New Predator of New Mexico’s Native Americans
Native Americans have historically been targeted by various predatory institu-
tions in search of the poorest, most vulnerable communities. High interest loan
stores physically surround the Navajo Nation, saddling this particular Native Amer-
ican community with more high interest loans than any other community in the
United States.
271
Likewise, the Navajo Nation is also surrounded by car dealerships
notoriously known for upselling vulnerable customers into a vehicle the salesman
knows they cannot afford.
272
After pressuring the consumer into an expensive car,
the salesperson may inflate the consumer’s stated income to qualify the customer for
financing.
273
The FTC investigated these dealers and ultimately sued them for vio-
lations of the FTC Act, TILA, Regulation Z, and the Consumer Leasing Act, among
268
Id.
269
Id. at viii.
270
Id. at 19–20. Lenders also note that the lack of established credit among Tribal members
provides yet another obstacle preventing them from engaging in offering mortgages in Indian
Country. Id. at 24.
271
Endless Debt: Native Americans Plagued by High-Interest Loans, NBC NEWS: IN PLAIN
SIGHT (Oct. 31, 2014), https://www.nbcnews.com/feature/in-plain-sight/endless-debt-native-
americans-plagued-high-interest-loans-n236706.
272
Horning, supra note 251, at 206–08.
273
Id. at 205 (explaining the sales practices of dealerships surrounding the Navajo Nation,
including misrepresenting buyer’s stated income, knowingly selling vehicles to customers unable
to afford the monthly payment, and relying on repossessions as a second stream of revenue for a
single vehicle).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 177 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 177 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1480 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
other laws, for preliminary and permanent injunctive relief, rescission or refor-
mation of contracts, restitution, and damages.
274
In these car deals, after getting Native American customers into their dealer-
ships, dealers keep the customers there for extended periods of time, hide crucial
parts of the contracts, lie about reported income, and fraudulently qualify buyers
for cars the dealership knows they will never be able to afford,
275
because, in the
end, the dealership knows that car will be repossessed and then be resold for a second
stream of revenue.
276
These dealerships also extensively market their most over-
priced and, in some cases, fraudulent deals to Native communities alone. This type
of targeted marketing has been found to be illegal discrimination due to disparate
treatment and disparate impact.
277
We see similar targeted, discriminatory marketing in the rent-to-own shed in-
dustry. For example, one company has 18 shed dealer locations within New Mex-
ico.
278
See Image 1.
274
FTC Charges Auto Dealerships in Arizona and New Mexico with Falsifying Consumers’
Information on Financing Documents, FED. TRADE COMMN (Aug. 1, 2018),
https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/press-releases/2018/08/ftc-charges-auto-dealerships-arizona-
new-mexico-falsifying; see also Fed. Trade Comm’n v. Tate’s Auto Ctr. of Winslow Inc., 2019
WL 1130006, at *1 (D. Ariz. Mar. 13, 2019).
275
Horning, supra note 251, at 206–08.
276
Id.
277
Creola Johnson, The Magic of Groups Identity: How Predatory Lenders Use Minorities to
Target Communities of Color, 17 G
EO. J. ON POVERTY L. & POLY 165, 197–99 (2010); see
LastWeekTonight, Payday Loans: Last Night with Jon Oliver, Y
OUTUBE (Aug. 10, 2014),
https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=PDylgzybWAw.
278
GRACELAND PORTABLE BUILDINGS, Addendum B-New Mexico Map,
https://graceland.worldsecuresystems.com/states/new-mexico.html (last visited Oct. 21, 2020)
(Graceland locations identified by the letter “G” on the map). This dealer has extremely poor
customer reviews. Graceland Portable Buildings Reviews and Complaints, PISSEDCONSUMER,
https
://graceland-portable-buildings.pissedconsumer.com/review.html, (last visited Dec. 20, 2020).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 178 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 178 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1481
I
Image 1.
All but four locations, located primarily in rural southern New Mexico,
279
are
surrounded by tribal lands. At the Mescalero Nation, there are two dealers, one lo-
cated at each entrance to the reservation. Similar to the car dealerships facing charges
by the FTC, this dealer surrounds tribal land with rent-to-own sales locations. Just
as the Navajo Nation depends on transportation to survive day-to-day life in rural
America, Native communities in New Mexico seek affordable housing. Dealers sell
Native consumers on costly rent-to-own shed deals, knowing that many will not be
able to afford the monthly payments.
280
Eventually, the sheds can be repossessed
279
These southern border locations target another highly vulnerable population: recent
immigrants.
280
NATIONAL BARN & STORAGE RENTAL ASSOCIATION, NBSRA, http://www.nbsra.com/
(last visited Dec. 21, 2020).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 178 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 178 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1482 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
and sold for a second stream of revenue.
281
Indeed it is not uncommon in our clin-
ical law program to hear stories of repossession or to actually see sheds being repos-
sessed. It is difficult to get information about the status of a “repossession”
282
or to
even get an accounting. The fee structures are opaque and at times impossible for
even lawyers to understand. Given the complete lack of governmental oversight, the
potential for abuse is limitless.
283
D. An Insider’s View of Rent-to-Own Predation
The website of the National Barn and Storage Rental Association (NBSRA),
the trade association for the shed industry, explains the industry practices.
284
The
organization’s mission is to “[p]rotect the industry’s future against legislation.”
285
The benefits of being a rent-to-own dealer include that “[t]here is no increased risk
to the [dealer] since the rent-to-own company assumes the risk . . . the dealer re-
ceives full retail price for the structure and frees up capital to allocate in other areas
or build more sheds.”
286
Moreover, as for shed repossessions, these are actually good
for business. According to the website:
Returns are not necessarily a financial loss. The returned shed will attract new
customers since there is a segment of shed buyers looking for a bargain. A
rental return brings customers to the sales lot eager to buy, sometimes this
leads to the sale of a new storage shed or barn.
287
While the NBSRA elucidates the benefits of rent-to-own dealerships, some vet-
erans in the industry disagree, going so far as to warn consumers to beware of rent-
to-own shed deals. Sheds Unlimited has dedicated an entire page of its website to
281
Id. For example, John, from a centrally located Pueblo in New Mexico, used to build
sheds for his community. This was his side job and how he supported his family during his off
season from work. Once Graceland came to town however, he had to close that side business.
“Nobody wanted to wait for me to build a shed, when they could buy one, rent-to-own, for a few
hundred dollars a month.” He was happy for his community until he began to see the negative
impact Graceland was having. “I had to buy my brother-in-law’s shed from him when he got
behind on payments. They were about to come take it and would have if I hadn’t paid it off.
Everyone thinks it’s just a couple hundred dollars until they are making that payment month after
month and then they realize they can’t afford it.” When you inundate a sector of consumers who
are financially vulnerable and in desperate need of housing options, your shed sales are going to
increase. Interview with John, Tribal Member in New Mexico (Feb. 10, 2019) (a Tribal Member
in New Mexico, discussing experiences in Native communities with regards to shed deals).
282
Telephonic Interview with Kenneth Bobroff, President, UNM School of Law (June 21,
2019).
283
Id.
284
NBSRA, supra note 280.
285
Id.
286
Why Rent To Own?, NBSRA (Apr. 4, 2018), http://www.nbsra.com/why-rent-to-own.
287
Id.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 179 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 179 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1483
educating consumers on the dangers of these transactions.
288
They educate consum-
ers that rent-to-own sheds will cost consumers 25–65% more than buying out-
right.
289
The site goes on to warn consumers that, if at any time they stop making
monthly payments, they will lose the shed, even if they have paid 99% of the con-
tract price.
290
Michael W. Mathis, a shed dealer for over 20 years, is so opposed to rent-to-
own shed sales that he created his own blog on the topic.
291
As he explains:
[w]e have been [i]n the storage shed business for almost 20 years, I have per-
sonally taken the time to investigate the possibility of tapping into this addi-
tional market myself, and have been approached by lenders who are more
than willing to work with me in this endeavor, but I have a problem with
offering this mainly my conscience . . . my real problem with Rent to Own is
that I feel we are taking advantage of people. Let’s face it anyone with any
financial insight can see this for what it is A RIP OFF . . . Rent to Own shed
business preys on people who have made poor choices, don’t know better or
unfortunate circumstance [has] put them in bad financial situations.
292
Some larger players in the industry, such as “Tuff-Shed,” seemingly agree with
this opinion of rent-to-own shed agreements. While “Tuff-Shed” did begin offering
rent-to-own options in 2015, they limited rent-to-own contracts to sheds 10x16
and smaller.
293
Sheds sized at 10x16 or smaller are significantly less likely to be used
as homes, thereby reducing the chance of a consumer losing their home to the rent-
to-own agreement.
Rent-to-own agreements for shed dealers are undoubtedly profitable for the
industry. If they weren’t profitable, no shed dealer would offer these types of agree-
ments. However, when those positioned to receive a large cut of that profit publicly
acknowledge the unethical nature of the transaction and refuse to take part, it sends
a powerful message of extraordinary predation.
288
Why NOT to choose a Rent-A-Shed Option, SHEDS UNLIMITED LLC,
https://shedsunlimited.net/why-not-to-choose-a-rent-a-shed-option (last visited Dec. 21, 2020).
289
Id. Our view of rent-to-own customer contracts show that this is an incredibly
conservative estimate based on contracts on file with authors, scrubbed of identifying data.
290
Id.
291
Michael W. Mathis, Rent to Own Storage Sheds - Why You Should Think Twice,
EZINEARTICLE (Feb. 20, 2010), https://ezinearticles.com/?Rent-to-Own-Storage-Sheds—-Why-
You-Should-Think-Twice&id=3798258.
292
Id.
293
Introducing Rent-To-Own with Tuff Shed, TUFF SHED (Feb. 25, 2016),
https://www.tuffshed.com/introducing-rent-to-own-with-tuff-shed.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 179 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 179 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1484 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
E. Comparing the Cost of Credit in Shed Homes to Rent-to-Own Land Sale Contracts
and Mortgages
Interest rates on housing are lower than interest rates on other types of loans.
For example, a credit card rate might average 18–24%, while a home loan in 2020
averages 2.75–3.125%.
294
A very high-interest land sale contract, or mobile home
loan, can run 18%, though rates of 9–10% are currently more common. The inter-
est rate in a typical rent-to-own shed is roughly 40% per annum, 10 times the aver-
age home mortgage rate.
295
These rates are incredibly high, particularly given that
forfeiture of equity is so likely. Clearly additional regulation is needed to ensure that
those on the low end of the economic scale do not pay so much more than the rest
of us for basic shelter.
VI. THE GREATER IMPLICATIONS OF THE CREDIT-NO CREDIT
DISTINCTION ON THE FUTURE OF CREDIT REGULATION
In this Part, we discuss the greater implications of the credit/no credit dichot-
omy, focusing on large-scale societal implications of sheltering shadow credit prod-
ucts from regulation. In considering the narrowest problems we have raised here,
many solutions are viable. For example, if we focus narrowly on the abuses occurring
in the rent-to-own shed industry, we could regulate the rent-to-own shed industry
in the same way we regulate mobile home rent-to-own transactions. In some states,
for example, rent-to-own mobile home transactions are treated as credit because the
stakes are large and the personal property is being used as a home.
296
If one wanted
to think a bit more broadly, one could similarly regulate rent-to-own real estate to
require all the consumer protections of other consumer credit.
297
We could think even more broadly and regulate the entire rent-to-own house-
hold goods industry right back into the consumer credit scheme, where it once sat
before Article 9 was amended and before the rent-to-own industry passed its own
regulatory scheme. In so doing, we would treat rent-to-own like any other consumer
credit transaction. Rent-to-own dealers would be legally required to comply with
interest rate caps, TILA, and Article 9. Consumers could compare the cost of this
credit to market alternatives like retail installment sales contracts, could be free of
294
BANKRATE, supra note 235.
295
Id.
296
See, e.g., N.M. STAT. ANN. § 57-26-3(A)(5) (1995).
297
See, e.g., Nelson, supra note 223, at 1116. Nelson argues that courts should take the
Restatement Third of Property’s approach which treats contracts for deed as mortgages. See id.
Nelson acknowledges that in states where these types of contracts are regulated by statute, it might
be unfeasible to implement this judicial solution. Id. at 1166–67. By adopting the Restatement’s
approach, however, he argues that both buyers and sellers will have their interests protected under
the broad confines of mortgage law. Id.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 180 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 180 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1485
unfair debt collection practices by collection agencies, and could get the repossession
and other protections of Article 9. Lawyers could sue for violations of these laws,
keeping the credit providers honest and the consumers protected. While this may
constrict the availability of rent-to-own transactions, there would likely still be
plenty of players and market alternatives to fill consumer need.
Shadow credit, however, creates concerns broader than just rent-to-own trans-
actions. As one commentator explained as to all of these newer shadow creditor
products, but particularly ISAs in education:
I suspect what is going on is an attempt by the ISA industry to get the camel’s
nose under the tent and become too-big-to-fail. If the ISA industry gets large
enough before facing the regulatory question, the industry will be able to push
back against any regulatory attempts by pointing to potential disruption and
reliance of consumers upon the product. Frankly, this is an issue the CFPB
should be getting out ahead on. The Bureau should be issuing regulatory
guidance on ISAs as part of its regulation of the private student lending mar-
ket. Alternatively, the Bureau could undertake a rule making defining “debt”
under the CFPA.
298
As we have mentioned, payroll advance loans are growing fast, and while they
could be a good market alternative to payday loans,
299
this industry’s claim to be
outside consumer credit regulation is also troubling. The industry’s refusal to com-
ply with usury laws or TILA make the products and their regulation unpredictable
going forward. Indeed, New York State is leading a multi-state investigation into
whether payroll advance companies are, by claiming to be “not credit,” violating
usury laws and other consumer protections.
300
Similarly, bail bonds, buy-now-pay-
later services, and employer payday advances are all credit transactions, though they
claim not to be bound by TILA or other credit laws.
301
The cost of not catching the shadow credit trend before it really takes hold
could be significant. The benefits of non-compliance, charging whatever interest
rates one wants, not disclosing an interest rate, and not complying with repossession
and forfeiture rules are incredibly remunerative. As a result, there is no reason to
believe the growth in shadow credit will not continue to morph, perhaps enough to
deregulate consumer credit.
This issue also has broader implications for the legal system as a whole. There
are endless examples of situations in which form could be elevated over substance,
298
Levitin, supra note 3.
299
Hawkins, supra note 12, at 2112.
300
Suzanne Barly, New York State Regulator Leads Probe into Payroll Advance Industry,
R
EUTERS (Aug. 6, 2019, 10:47 AM), https://www.reuters.com/article/us-new-york-loans/new-
york-state-regulator-leads-probe-into-payroll-advance-industry-idUSKCN1UW218.
301
Alex Kornya et al., Crimsumerism: Combating Consumer Abuses in the Criminal Legal
System, 54 H
ARV. C.R.-C.L. L. REV. 107, 127, 138 (2019).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 180 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 180 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1486 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
to the detriment of our legal system. In these other areas of the law, we are careful
to elevate substance over form, so we can treat all fact patterns, products, and situa-
tions with authenticity, fairness, and consistency under the law. While formalism
and procedural distinctions have their place, we need to be careful how those rules
affect people in practice, and aware of unintended consequences.
302
The substance-over-form doctrine is a major tenet of tax law.
303
Placing form
over substance creates a distressing tendency to mangle basic economic concepts.
304
In both taxation and employment contexts, courts and the IRS routinely look be-
yond labels to determine the true nature of the legal relationship between employers
and employees/independent contractors.
305
Allowing employers to mislabel an em-
ployee as an independent contractor would lead to all kinds of mischief and under-
mine laws intended to protect employees from wage theft and overreaching.
306
There are many, many more examples from the area of taxation.
307
In the area of tribal payday lending, we see another example of how form can-
not be elevated over substance.
308
A lender cannot simply partner with a tribe on a
very minimal level, and then get the sovereign immunity that tribes receive as gov-
ernments.
309
Similarly, minority-owned businesses get certain benefits when apply-
ing for and bidding on government contracts, but one cannot simply form a loose
partnership with one minority group, who has very little control or ownership, and
302
See Edward J. Schnee, Substance-Over-Form Doctrine: The Past, Present and Recommended
Future, 127
J. TAXN 82, 82 (2017) (stating that the “Supreme Court has created numerous
doctrines to implement the Internal Revenue Code. These doctrines have been applied many
times. They have also changed over time. One of these major doctrines is the substance-over-form
doctrine.”); see also David Dyzenhaus, Constituting the Rule of Law: Fundamental Values in
Administrative Law, 27 Q
UEENS L.J. 445, 450 (2002). Another example of the substance over
form doctrine comes from administrative court decisions:
Formalism is formal in that it requires judges to operate with categories and distinctions that
determine results without the judges having to deploy the substantive arguments that under-
pin the categories and distinctions. Since those categories and distinctions must take on a life
of their own in order to operate in this detached way, they are capable of determining results
that contradict the very arguments for these categories and distinctions.
Id.
303
See generally Bryan Camp, Form Over Substance in Fifth Circuit Tax Cases, 34 TEX. TECH.
L. REV. 733 (2003).
304
Id. at 736.
305
Id. at 745.
306
Id. at 744.
307
Id. at 742.
308
See generally De La Torre v. Cashcall, Inc., 422 P.3d 1004, 1009 (Cal. 2018); Nathalie
Martin & Joshua Schwartz, The Alliance Between Payday Lenders and Tribes: Are Both Tribal
Sovereignty and Consumer Protection at Risk?, 69 WASH. & LEE L. REV. 751, 753 (2012).
309
Id. at 753, 755.
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 181 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 181 Side A 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
2020] SHADOW CREDIT 1487
get those benefits.
310
Finally, in the area of securities regulations, federal and many state statutes reg-
ulate “investment contracts” as well as the traditional categories of securities, like
shares of stock, to avoid gamesmanship in the form of transactions.
311
Under the
analysis of the Supreme Court in Howey, what matters is what the transaction really
is, not what it purports to be.
312
The examples above are all from commercial law, but there are many more
examples of items in which we are careful to elevate substance over form in our legal
system. In the area of environmental law, for example, the Environmental Protec-
tion Agency regulates pesticides under the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Ro-
denticide Act (FIFRA).
313
Under section 18 of FIFRA,
314
all pesticides must be reg-
istered and under FIFRA’s implementing rules.
315
These products include all
products used as a pesticide, even if the manufacturer never advertised the product
for this use or even intended that use when the product was produced.
316
In other
words, throughout our legal system, substance beats form, classification matters, and
meaningful regulatory schemes protect both honest businesses and consumers.
VII. CONCLUSION
As some of the examples above show, classification is not just about money.
The legitimacy of the entire legal system rests on honest classification and charac-
terization, calling a spade a spade. As our Supreme Court has noted numerous times,
“[t]he exaltation of form over substance is to be avoided.”
317
Lawyers specialize in
categorizing fact patterns, transactions, and products. How we do this affects much
more than we may realize. Rent-to-own transactions are but one example of trans-
actions that look, act, and clearly are credit, but have been misclassified by the law
310
Id.; see also id. at 753, 757.
311
What is the Howey Test, FINDLAW, https://consumer.findlaw.com/securities-law/what-is-
the-howey-test.html (last visited Dec. 21, 2020).
312
Securities Exchange Comm’n v. W. J. Howey Co., 328 U.S. 293, 300–01 (1947). Under
the Howey Test, a transaction is an investment contract if: “1. It is an investment of money, 2.
There is an expectation of profits from the investment, 3. The investment of money is in a
common enterprise, and 4. Any profit comes from the efforts of a promoter or third party.
Although the Howey Test uses the term “money,” later cases have expanded this to include
investments of assets other than money.” F
INDLAW, supra note 311.
313
Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act, 7 U.S.C. § 136(b) (2018).
314
Id. § 136a(a).
315
40 C.F.R. § 152.15 (2019); see also Why Pesticide Certification?, N.D. ST. UNIV.,
https://www.ag.ndsu.edu/pesticide/WhyPesticideCertification.pdf (last visited Oct. 21, 2020).
316
See, e.g., id. (the substance over form rule causes Avon to need to register Skin So Soft as
a pesticide); see also 40 C.F.R § 152.15 (2019).
317
United States v. DiFrancesco, 449 U.S. 117, 142 (1980).
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 181 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
42938-lcb_24-4 Sheet No. 181 Side B 02/02/2021 10:18:46
C M
Y K
Martin_EIC_Proof_Complete (Do Not Delete) 1/18/2021 6:18 PM
1488 LEWIS & CLARK LAW REVIEW [Vol. 24.4
to be something else, at the behest of the rent-to-own industry. As we have demon-
strated, as rent-to own has morphed into areas beyond household goods, we can see
the harm that shadow credit can impart on individuals, the consumer credit system,
or perhaps even the credit system as a whole.
318
What happens with one credit prod-
uct can happen with others. More critically, what happens in the credit and financial
world can happen in the rest of the legal system. We can watch the legal system
weaken through false classifications. Alternatively, we can stay vigilant in calling a
spade a spade and regulating credit as credit, for the sake of the entire system.
318
Erik F. Gerding, The Subprime Crisis and the Link between Consumer Financial Protection
and Systemic Risk, 5 FIU
L. REV. 93, 93 (2009) (arguing that consumer financial protection can,
and must, serve a role not only in protecting individuals from excessive risk, but also in protecting
markets from systemic risk and that strong “consumer financial regulations can mitigate these
risks in three, non-exclusive ways: (1) by reducing the level of defaults on consumer loans, (2) by
making defaults more predictable, and (3) by reducing the correlation of defaults.”). Professor
Gerding testified before Congress on this same topic in 2019. Emerging Threats to Stability:
Considering the Systemic Risk of Leveraged Lending: Hearing before the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs.,
Subcomm. on Consumer Protection and Fin. Inst., 116th Cong. 2–15 (2019) (statement of Erik F.
Gerding, Professor of Law and Wolf-Nichol Fellow, University of Colorado Law School).