Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
1
DRAFT
Principles of Economics in Context, Second Edition
CHAPTER 31: DEFICITS AND DEBT
You may have seen the national debt clock in New York City that continually shows
how much our debt is increasing by the second. The total amount of the debt, which
exceeds $20 trillion, seems very large. But what does it mean? Why does our country
borrow so much money? To whom do we owe it all? Is it a serious problem? Is it
possible for the United States to stop borrowing? This chapter goes into detail in
answering these questions and examines the relationship between the national debt
and the economy. But first we provide some historical context to the notion of a
national debt.
1. DEFICITS AND THE NATIONAL DEBT
Perhaps because the two terms sound so much alike, many people confuse the
government’s deficit with the government debt. But the two “D words” are very
different. The deficit totaled nearly $700 billion in fiscal 2017, while total federal debt
exceeded $20 trillion by the end of fiscal 2017. The reason the second number is much
larger than the first is that the debt represents deficits accumulated over many years.
In economists’ terms, we can say that the government deficit is a flow variable while
its debt is a stock variable. (See Chapter 15 for this distinction.) As we will see, both
the deficit and the debt have been projected to increase from fiscal 2018 into the
future.
1
The government’s debt rises when the government runs a deficit and falls when it
runs a surplus.
2
Figure 31.1 shows some recent data on the government’s debt,
measured as a percentage of GDP. The two lines on the graph indicate the total
government debt and the part of government debt held by the public (as opposed to
debt held by government agencies). After hitting a high of more than 100 percent of
GDP during World War II, the debt generally declined as a percentage of GDP until
1980. It rose between 1980 and 1996, then declined again relative to GDP until 2000.
Since 2000, the debt has risen, with a particularly sharp increase in the years following
the 2007–2009 recession.
What is the impact on the economy of government debt? One commonly
expressed view of the government’s debt is that it represents a burden on future
generations of citizens. There is some truth to this assertion, but it is also somewhat
misleading. It implicitly compares the government’s debt to the debt of a private citizen.
Certainly, if you personally accumulated a huge debt, it would not be good for your
financial future. But government debt is different in some important ways.
First, about half of government debt held by the public is, directly or indirectly, owed
to U.S. citizens. When people own Treasury bills (T-bills), Treasury notes, or Treasury
bonds, they own government IOUs. From their point of view, the government debt is
an asset, a form of wealth. If your grandmother gives you a U.S. Savings Bond, she is
giving you a benefit, not a burden. These assets are some of the safest ones that you
can own.
Second, government debt does not have to be paid off. Old debt can be “rolled
over,” that is, replaced by new debt. Provided that the size of the debt does not grow
too quickly, the government’s credit is good—there will always be people interested in
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
2
DRAFT
buying and holding government bonds. Most economists use the rule of thumb that as
long as the rate of increase in government’s debt is not significantly greater than that
of GDP for several years in a row it does not represent a severe problem for the
economy. As Figure 31.1 shows, following the 2007–2009 recession, persistently large
deficits caused the debt to rise much more rapidly than GDP. Nonetheless, the debt is
still at a lower level relative to GDP than it was immediately after World War II, which
was followed by nearly two decades of relative economic prosperity.
Figure 31.1 U.S. National Debt as a Percentage of GDP
Source: St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank.
Third, the U.S. government pays interest in U.S. dollars. A country such as
Argentina that owes money to other countries and must pay interest in a foreign
currency (the U.S. dollar) can get into big trouble and eventually be forced to default
on its debt. But it is much easier to manage a debt that is denominated in your own
currency. Even if some of the debt is owed to foreigners, the United States does not
have to obtain foreign currency to pay it. And so long as foreigners are willing to
continue holding U.S. government bonds, it will not be necessary to pay it at all—
instead, the debt can be rolled over as new bonds replace old ones.
But this should not encourage us to believe that government debt is never a
concern. Rising debt creates several significant problems. First, interest must be paid
on the debt. This means that a larger share of future budgets must be devoted to
paying interest, leaving less for other needs. It is also true that the largest holders of
government bonds tend to be wealthier people, so most of the interest paid by the
government goes to better-off individuals. If this payment is not counteracted by
changes in the tax system, it encourages increased income inequality—a growing
concern, as discussed in the previous chapter. Government debt also creates a
problem of generational equity—future taxpayers will have to pay more interest
because of government borrowing today. Thus, it is a burden on future generations in
that debt finance detracts from other important functions that the government could be
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
3
DRAFT
performing. The portion of tax receipts that goes to debt service (paying the interest,
if not the principal, of the government’s debt) is not available for other uses such as
education, health, etc.
A second problem is that in recent years an increasing proportion of the debt has
been borrowed from governments, corporations, and individuals in foreign countries
(Figure 31.2). The interest payments on this portion of the debt must be made to those
outside the country. That means that the United States must earn enough income from
exports and other sources to pay not only for imports but also for interest payments to
the rest of the world. Alternatively, the country could borrow more, but it is best to avoid
this solution, since it would just make the overall foreign debt problem larger in the
long run.
Figure 31.2 Domestic and Foreign Holdings of U.S. Debt
Source: St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank.
Large foreign holdings of debt also pose another problem—what if those foreign
debt holders decided to sell the U.S. bonds that they own? In that case, the
government might have trouble finding enough people who are willing to hold
government bonds (that is, lend money to the government). This could cause interest
rates to rise sharply, which in turn would push the government budget further into
deficit, and could tip the economy into recession.
The question “Is government debt worth it?” can be answered only if we consider
what that debt is used to finance. In this respect, an analogy to personal or business
debt is appropriate. Most people—including economists—do not reject consumer and
corporate debt. Rather, our judgment about debt depends on the benefits received.
For example, if debt is accumulated for gambling, it is a bad idea. If the bet does
not pay off, then it is very difficult to pay the interest on the debt (not to mention the
principal). But if the government borrows to pay for intelligently planned investment, it
can be very beneficial. If the investment leads to economic growth, the government’s
ability to collect tax revenue is enhanced. This kind of borrowing can pay for itself, as
long as the investment is not for wasteful “pork barrel” spending, poorly planned or
unnecessary projects, and so on.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
4
DRAFT
Even if the debt finances current spending, it can be justifiable if it is seen as
necessary to maintain or protect valuable aspects of life. Most people would not be
opposed to borrowing to pay for cleanup after a natural disaster or to contain a deadly
pandemic. For example, Congress appropriated $60 billion in relief funds for Hurricane
Sandy relief in 2013, and over $100 billion for Hurricanes Harvey, Irma, and Maria, as
well as wildfire relief in 2017.
The management of debt involves standard principles of wise stewardship of
finances. When we apply them to government deficits and debt, we need to weigh the
economic benefits of different spending and tax policies.
Discussion Questions
1. What is the difference between the deficit and the national debt? How are they
related?
2. “The national debt is a huge burden on our economy.” How would you evaluate
this statement?
2. THE U.S. NATIONAL DEBT: A HISTORICAL PERSPECTIVE
2.1 TWO CENTURIES OF DEFICITS AND DEBT
Deficit financing has been part of U.S. history from the very beginning. The Continental
Congress of 1776 put the country into debt in order to continue its fight for
independence from Great Britain. As is done today, Congress issued bonds in order
to finance the country’s war effort. There was considerable controversy after the war
regarding the role of the new federal government in absorbing the debts incurred by
individual states. Alexander Hamilton, secretary of the Treasury under George
Washington, was prominent among those who believed that, by introducing greater
flexibility into the money supply, a national debt had the potential to strengthen the
economy and the country. Despite opposition from other political leaders—John
Adams and Thomas Jefferson among them—Hamilton helped set in motion a process
through which the federal government regularly relied on debt to finance its operations.
After the United States became independent from Great Britain, its federal
government generally repaid its debts fairly quickly. The War of 1812, however, proved
very costly, and the national debt approached 15 percent of national income by 1816.
In the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, it was primarily wars that depleted the
government’s finances. The Civil War was especially costly—the debt approached 40
percent of total national income at its peak—but the Mexican-American and Spanish-
American wars also added to the national debt. By 1900 the debt had fallen below 5
percent of total GDP, but the budget deficits during World War I again pushed the
national debt beyond 40 percent of GDP.
In terms of its effect on government finances, the Great Depression of the 1930s
was truly a watershed. The economic crisis ultimately led to President Franklin D.
Roosevelt’s New Deal social programs. From that point on, federal spending on social
programs—in addition to military spending, which soared during World War II and
remained high afterwards—has figured prominently in the total debt figures.
Consequently, since 1931 the U.S. federal budget has been in surplus only seven
years, compared with the years from independence until 1931, during which surpluses
were twice as frequent as deficits. National debt in relation to income rose significantly
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
5
DRAFT
during the 1930s, but World War II had an even greater impact. Because consumer
goods were rationed, savings accumulated, and people used them to purchase U.S.
war bonds (a form of debt), which helped finance U.S. participation in World War II.
After the war, the national debt totaled an unprecedented 122 percent of GDP.
2.2 “SUPPLY-SIDE” ECONOMICS
After World War II, the debt generally declined as a percentage of GDP until 1980.
The national debt was just over $900 billion in 1981, but rose by nearly $2 trillion during
the next eight years. In other words, over those eight years the country incurred twice
as much debt as it had in its first 200 years! How did this happen?
Ronald Reagan’s 1980 presidential campaign leaned heavily on the principles of
“supply-side” economics, which promised that offering more benefits and incentives to
the individuals and groups that held the most wealth and productive capital would
stimulate rapid investment growth and job creation. According to this principle, tax cuts
would pay for themselves through greater revenues from an expanded economy. This
is consistent with the oft-heard but controversial concept of “trickle-down” economics,
which is the idea that benefits enjoyed by the well-off eventually percolate (i.e., trickle
down) to everyone else.
The major policy experiment with supply-side economics was the Economic
Recovery Act (ERA, 1981), which cut income and corporate tax rates, substantially
reducing government revenues. At the same time, military spending increased in the
1980s. Consequently, the annual budget deficit, which had been 2.7 percent of GDP
in 1980, grew to an annual average of about 4 percent during the Reagan presidency
(see Chapter 25, Figure 25.5). A portion of the debt increase was due to cyclical
factors, specifically an unusually deep recession in 1981–1982. Most of it, however,
resulted from the failure of supply-side economics to produce the revenue growth that
was needed to make up for the tax cut.
2.3 1989 TO THE PRESENT
In absolute terms, the national debt continued to grow after Reagan left office, despite
the fact that by then public awareness of the government’s fiscal problems had grown.
In an attempt to address persistent deficits, President George H.W. Bush raised tax
rates slightly and signed a bill in 1990 requiring that all spending increases be matched
by either decreases in spending in other areas or tax increases, in a system known as
PAYGO (“pay as you go”). Despite the introduction of that system, another recession
(1990–1991) and the first Iraq war kept deficits in the range of 4 percent of GDP
annually. It also did not help matters that sizable sums had to be used to bail out many
savings and loan banks that collapsed due to losses from risky and ill-conceived real
estate investments (a precursor of the real estate bubble of the twenty-first century).
In 1992 the national debt was $4 trillion.
Bush’s PAYGO policy was continued under the administration of Bill Clinton.
Congress again raised income tax rates, and the end of the Cold War allowed the
federal government to lower military expenditures (relative to GDP, although not in
absolute terms), a side benefit often referred to as a “peace dividend.” At the same
time, the economy emerged from recession and began a period of sustained growth.
The resulting movement from the trough to the peak of the business cycle from 1992
to 2000 generated surpluses in the overall federal budget from 1998 to 2001, a feat
that had not been achieved since 1969. This period of budget surpluses, however,
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
6
DRAFT
was short-lived.
During the presidency of George W. Bush (2001–2009), a combination of
recession, tax cuts, and increased military expenditures pushed the budget back into
deficit and caused the debt to increase further. By 2008, the debt totaled almost 70
percent of GDP.
The first Obama administration (2009–2013) was spent dealing with the worst
recession since the 1930s. During this period, annual deficits averaged around 8
percent of GDP, and the national debt rose to just over 100 percent of GDP, as the
government deployed an $800 billion fiscal policy package to keep the 2007–2009
recession from turning into a full-fledged depression. Tax revenue fell sharply, from
$2.5 trillion in 2008 to $2.1 trillion in 2009. As is normal in a recession, expenditures
increased due to automatic stabilizers (see Chapter 25, Figure 25.5). The combination
of these factors with continued military expenses in Iraq and Afghanistan led to record
deficits of more than $1 trillion. After 2012 the annual deficit fell to a historically more
normal level around 2.5 to 4 percent of GDP, but as of 2018 the national debt was still
over 100 percent of GDP (see Figure 31.1).
3
With Trump administration tax cuts being
implemented in 2018, deficits started to rise again, and were projected to exceed $1
trillion in 2019, according to the Congressional Budget Office.
4
Discussion Questions
1. Has the U.S. federal government ever had a budget surplus? When was the last
time? Was there ever a time that the government was not in debt?
2. What causes budget deficits? Are budget deficits necessarily a bad thing?
3. THE DEBT AND ITS LINKS TO FINANCE
3.1 TAXONOMY OF DEBT TYPES
In the popular press, one encounters different estimates of the country’s debt, which
can vary considerably depending on whether it refers to government debt or all debt
including government and private debt. U.S. total debt, including both public and
private debt, is over 300 percent of GDP (Figure 31.3). Some confusion has been
caused by differing terminology relating to the debt, so it may be helpful to distinguish
between different categories.
The term “national debt” usually refers to the gross federal debt, which is actually
the total debt outstanding for the federal government (Table 31.1), and is the debt to
which we have referred until now. It is not, however, the same as the debt held by
the public. The gross federal debt includes money that the federal government
“borrows” from other government accounts. Prominent examples include Social
Security and Medicare, which, as noted earlier, are classified as “off budget.” Basically,
when the government collects more in tax revenue for these programs than it pays
out, it realizes an off-budget surplus. It is then in a position to “borrow” the surplus, or
at least a portion of it, as an alternative to borrowing money from the public. So it is
the debt held by the public, not the gross federal debt, that is a direct consequence of
federal budget deficits.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
7
DRAFT
gross federal debt: total amount owed by the federal government to all claimants,
including foreigners, the public in the United States, and other government
accounts
debt held by the public: the gross federal debt minus the debt owed to other
government accounts
Table 31.1 Debt Taxonomy
Debt type
Description
Government
Gross federal debt
Generally synonymous with the national
debt; refers to the total amount of
money owed by the federal
government to all claimants
Debt held by public
Gross federal debt minus debt held in
government accounts
Internal debt
The share of the gross federal debt owned
by domestic individuals or groups
External debt
The share of the gross federal debt owned
by foreign individuals or groups
State and local debt
The total value of all state and local bonds
outstanding
Private
Households and
not-for-profits
Includes mortgage debt, credit card debt,
and bank loans
Financial sector
Total of all corporate debt for financial
industry
Nonfinancial
business
All corporate debt and bank borrowing for
nonfinancial business
As discussed in Chapter 27, the Federal Reserve is an active participant in the
market for U.S. bonds, as it buys and sells them to conduct its open market operations
in hopes of influencing interest rates. So the Fed also holds a significant share of the
federal debt. Its share is also considered a part of the debt held by the public.
One final distinction is between the internal debt and the external debt. The
internal debt refers to the portion of the gross federal debt that is owned by individuals
or groups within the country, and the external debt represents the portion held by
foreigners or foreign groups.
internal debt: the portion of the gross federal debt that is owed to individuals or
groups within the country
external debt: the portion of the gross federal debt that is owed to foreign
individuals or groups
Like the federal government, state and municipal governments also often rely on
borrowing to fund their operations. They issue a variety of bond instruments to acquire
funds from the public, which in a sense add to the country’s total indebtedness. This
is also a point of frequent confusion. In its common usage, the term “national debt”
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
8
DRAFT
usually refers only to the federal portion of the debt. This seems reasonable, because
it is the debt that is directly related to fiscal policy and how it affects the national
economy. Yet if we speak of the total debt of the country, it appears misleading to
exclude the state and local debt. And the picture becomes even more complicated,
because a complete accounting of debt would also include all household debt (e.g.,
mortgage and credit card), financial sector debt, and the debt of nonfinancial business,
which includes both bank loans outstanding and corporate bonds issued to finance
private debt.
Figure 31.3 Total U.S. Indebtedness as a Percentage of GDP
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, FRED Economic Database
If we add all the categories to represent the total indebtedness of the whole country,
we find that, as of 2016, it exceeded 300 percent of GDP, and was more than double
what it had been in the 1970s (Figure 31.3). Such an inclusive debt concept is not of
great significance in ordinary times, since, as discussed in Chapter 26, most of the
debt exists as an asset in someone else’s balance sheet. During the run-up to the
Great Recession, however, the rapidly rising debt, especially notable in the financial
sector, should have been setting off alarm bells, as it meant that the country as a whole
had used up much of the leeway in terms of borrowing capacity that could have been
drawn on to get out of a recession. After the Great Recession, total debt fell as a
percent of GDP despite rising government debt, because the economic downturn
forced households and businesses to reduce their debt levels.
3.2 FEDERAL GOVERNMENT BORROWING: POTENTIAL PROBLEMS
In earlier chapters we saw that when the government borrows money, it issues bonds
on which it must pay interest. The interest payments form part of the annual federal
budget. Figure 31.4 shows how these payments as a percentage of federal spending
have varied over time. Note that interest payments accounted for a much greater
portion of the budget during the 1980s and 1990s than they do now. Considering that
federal debt as a percentage of GDP has risen quite rapidly over the past decade, how
can this be? The answer is that the unusually low interest rates that have prevailed
over the same period make this possible.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
9
DRAFT
Figure 31.4 Interest Payments as Percentage of Total Federal Outlays
Source: St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank.
We have seen in earlier chapters that a weak economy tends to induce lower
interest rates, both naturally and as a consequence of policy measures. If interest rates
are lower throughout the economy, the Treasury can issue new debt (e.g., Treasury
bonds) at a low interest rate. When it does so, it is effectively reducing the portion of
the federal budget that must be set aside for debt service. The phenomenon is not
unlike the low monthly payments a homeowner makes after obtaining a mortgage with
a very low interest rate. The major difference to keep in mind is that, unlike a
household, the federal government has the ability to print money if need be to pay off
its debt.
As of August 2018, the interest rate on a ten-year Treasury bond was 2.87 percent.
This is extremely low from a historical perspective (see Figure 31.5). The ten-year rate
was below 3 percent from 2011 to 2017, even reaching 1.5 percent in 2016. One might
think that at such low interest rates, borrowing was especially cheap, making it a good
time for the government to run a budget deficit and accumulate debt. It is important to
consider, however, that interest rates are likely to rise in future, increasing the burden
of servicing the debt. The argument for adding to federal debt seems stronger if the
government spends on programs that produce a high multiplier effect (Chapter 25).
With low interest rates, the gain from the multiplier effect (in terms of the increase in
aggregate demand) is potentially larger than the loss (in terms of adding to the debt
burden), which would make the net gain positive.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
10
DRAFT
Figure 31.5 The Interest Rate on 10-Year Treasury Bonds
Source: St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank.
It may be counterproductive, however, to allow the debt to grow if it is financing
“low-multiplier” activities. An example is tax cuts for the wealthy, which, as we saw in
Chapter 25, do not produce as much “bang for the buck” as tax cuts for the poor or
new spending on constructive activities. A useful way of understanding the problem is
to imagine the federal government as a private business. Would a business borrow
money at an interest rate higher than its expected rate of return? Of course not. The
government’s situation is a bit more complicated because it needs to assess the
projected “social return” on its expenditures (e.g., a more educated citizenry, better
infrastructure). The problem is that it is seldom easy to express the social return in
dollars.
Another concern with mounting debt is that, if debt relative to GDP becomes
sufficiently large, lenders might start to doubt the borrowers’ ability to repay. If the
doubt were severe and widespread, it could affect the bond market and, as a result,
the national economy. Risk-averse investors would sell their bonds, driving bond
prices down. When bond prices go down, bond yields (rates of return) go up (as noted
in the appendix to Chapter 27), because the amount that the government has to pay
in interest on the bond becomes higher relative to the value of the bond. Any new
bonds that are then issued will have to match this higher rate of return, meaning that
the government will have to pay more in debt service costs in future.
The greater the unease over the borrower’s ability to pay, the higher the interest
rate that the borrower must offer in order to attract lenders. In the summer of 2011
Standard & Poor’s, one of the major ratings agencies, downgraded U.S. government
debt from AAA to AA+ as a result of a political impasse between the Obama
administration and the Republican Congress that created doubt about the reliability of
government debt payments. Fortunately for the United States, even with this
downgrade, its debt remained very much in demand.
A third potential problem with too much debt concerns exactly how it gets repaid.
An indebted country must repay the principal on its debt and service it with interest
payments. To do so, it must either engage in new borrowing, raise tax revenues, or
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
11
DRAFT
monetize the debt. We have seen that increasing tax rates has the potential to reduce
consumption and investment, hurting GDP growth and employment. But it is also
possible to finance a federal budget deficit with bonds that are purchased by the Fed.
5
As we saw in Chapter 27, this amounts to an expansionary monetary policy.
monetizing the debt: the purchase of new debt from the Treasury by the Federal
Reserve
A policy of monetizing the debt risks causing inflation, especially if the increase in
the money supply is large and continues over a long period. If such inflation does
occur, the bond markets would then demand higher interest rates on new debt to
compensate for the anticipated loss from inflation. How serious is this danger? Some
economists believe that a mild to moderate increase in inflation is not necessarily a
problem, especially if it occurs in a depressed economy facing a looming threat of
deflation. As we saw in Chapter 26, deflation would in most circumstances be more
dangerous than inflation, while mild inflation has historically been associated with
economic recoveries and gains in domestic employment. Severe inflation, however,
would be very damaging to the economy, and other economists point to this as a
possible long-term result of increasing government debt. Even moderate inflation has
significant economic implications, since the Federal Reserve is likely to respond to
observed inflation by raising interest rates, as described in Chapter 28, thereby
restraining economic activity and possibly pushing the economy into recession.
Discussion Questions
1. How many different “types” of debt can you think of? Which one do people usually
mean when they speak about the “national debt”?
2. What are some potential problems with excessive federal debt? How can the debt
be managed or repaid?
4. POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE DEBT
4.1 WHO OWNS THE DEBT?
We have already seen that when the federal government goes into debt, it sells
government bonds. But who buys these bonds? It might surprise you to see how
ownership of the gross federal debt is divided up. Federal Reserve and U.S.
government holdings account for over 40 percent of the debt (Figure 31.6). Social
Security is the largest of the government accounts that hold federal debt. Among many
other funds, the principal ones are the funds for federal employee retirement, federal
hospital insurance, and federal disability insurance. State and local governments,
perhaps surprisingly, account for another 3.6 percent of federal debt. States and
municipalities with budget surpluses will often buy federal debt, because it is
considered mostly risk free.
The domestic private sector owns just under 20 percent of the federal debt in the
form of bonds, which are found in a variety of locations: banks, pension plans,
insurance companies, mutual funds, and others, including households. Finally,
foreigners own about one-third (32.5 percent) of all federal debt. This is the U.S.
external debt.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
12
DRAFT
Figure 31.6 Ownership of Gross Federal Debt
Source: Treasury Department, 2016, Tables OFS-1; Distribution of Federal Securities by Class of
Investors and Type of Issues, Table OFS-2; Estimated Ownership of US Treasury Securities and
Table.
In 2018, China and Japan together owned more than 35 percent of the external
U.S. debt (Figure 31.7), a reflection of the large trade surpluses that the two countries
have had with the United States for several decades. As we saw in Chapter 29, when
China and Japan export more to the United States than they import from us, they
acquire a surplus of U.S. dollars, which they then use to buy U.S. federal debt. Why
do they choose to hold U.S. government debt? For the same reason that domestic
investors, state and local governments, and the Social Security trust fund trustees do:
U.S. Federal debt is widely perceived as returning risk-free income.
Twelve countries—Ireland, Brazil, Switzerland, the United Kingdom, Luxembourg,
Taiwan, India, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, Russia, the United Arab Emirates, and
Kuwait—accounted for just over 33 percent of U.S. external debt. Other countries
collectively owned 31 percent of U.S. external debt as of 2018.
Although in absolute terms the U.S. debt is by far the highest in the world, it is a
very different story if we look at total debt in relation to GDP. Japan’s ratio of debt to
GDP has risen since its economic slowdown started in the 1990s and is currently 234
percent of GDP (Figure 31.8). Nevertheless, Japanese bonds are still bought and
traded on the secondary market, which may be a testament to the widespread belief
in the stability of the Japanese economy. This is in contrast to Greece, which has had
to raise its bond rates substantially to attract continued investors, even though its debt
to GDP ratio (187%) is significantly below Japan’s. Italy’s ratio, at 155 percent, also
surpasses that of the United States.
In terms of the rate of increase in the debt, among the countries listed only the UK
surpasses the rate of debt increase of the United States, whose ratio increased from
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
13
DRAFT
64 percent in 2006 to over 100 percent in 2016, impelled by tax cuts and the financial
crisis. Still, the U.S. situation continues to resemble Japan’s, in that growing
indebtedness has not noticeably altered investor confidence, allowing the U.S. bond
yields to remain relatively low.
Figure 31.7 Foreign Holders of Gross Federal Debt
Source: Treasury Department, 2018, Major Foreign Holders of Treasury Securities.
Figure 31.8 Debt-GDP Ratios, an International Comparison
Source: OECD, General Government Debt, www.oecd.org
Note: U.S. debt figures include Federal, state, and local debt.
4.2 THE TWIN DEFICITS
As we have seen, a deficit can refer to a government’s finances or to a country’s trade
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
14
DRAFT
balance. The fact that the two types of deficits are closely linked adds to the not
infrequent confusion about these terms. Indeed, our debt to other countries as
measured in terms of their ownership of our bonds is related both to our budget and
trade deficits. Yet as we can see from Figure 31.9, the trend lines do not always move
together.
Up until the early to mid-1970s, the trade balance in the United States was around
1 percent of GDP, a relatively insubstantial amount, and frequently changed from
surplus to deficit and vice-versa. The federal budget, on the other hand, was
consistently in deficit (with a brief exception in 1969), though mostly at less than 2
percent of GDP. Starting in the mid-1970s, however, both the federal budget and the
trade balance turned sharply more negative. The United States has failed to run a
trade surplus (i.e., exports greater than imports) since then, and its trade deficit has
not been below 2 percent of GDP since 1998, almost reaching 6 percent in 2005 and
2006. The federal budget balance has been even more volatile over this 40- year
period, swinging from a surplus of more than 2 percent of GDP in the year 2000 (one
of only four years since 1969 that the budget was in surplus) to a deficit of almost 10
percent in 2009.
Figure 31.9 United States Twin Deficits as Percent of GDP
Sources: CBO and U.S. Census Bureau
As discussed in Chapter 29, if a country has positive net exports, it means that it
will have a surplus of funds (foreign exchange) to lend to other countries. If, in contrast,
a country has negative net exports, it typically must borrow from foreigners, essentially
to pay for the difference. If the government budget is in deficit, as also discussed in
Chapter 29, this tends to create or increase a trade deficit, unless it is financed by a
surplus of domestic savings—which has generally not been the case for the United
States. Thus, while the two deficits do not move together in lockstep, they will usually
broadly move in the same direction, as shown in Figure 31.9.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
15
DRAFT
4.3 THE BALANCED BUDGET DEBATE
If balancing the budget were legally required, the United States could not have
accumulated a national debt. Hoping to avoid uncontrolled debt dependence, many in
the past have advocated legislation, or even an amendment to the Constitution,
requiring that the budget be balanced. While this idea sounds attractive to many
people, the economic consequences would be severe.
Most states have a balanced budget requirement that forces them to cut services
and government employees during a recession. The federal government often
provides aid to allow states to minimize cost cutting, in an attempt to prevent the
economy from weakening further. States have no other recourse because, unlike the
federal government, they are unable to create additional funds. In large part, this
explains why, as discussed in Chapter 25, states (as well as municipalities) often
practice “procyclical” instead of countercyclical policy, which tends to worsen rather
than counteract recessions.
A balanced budget amendment would effectively make the federal government
little different from the states. Proponents argue that such a law would prevent the
federal government from imprudently running deficits, potentially causing inflation, in
good economic times. But there is a very serious downside, in that such an
amendment would make the federal government powerless to use countercyclical
policy to fight recessions.
In 1985, Congress passed the Balanced Budget and Emergency Deficit Control
Act, more popularly known as the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings Act (named after the
senators who sponsored it). It required that a limit be set on the annual deficit and that
the limit be reduced until a balanced budget was achieved in 1991. While less stringent
than a constitutional requirement, the deficit ceiling was nevertheless strict. Not
meeting it would require spending to be reduced automatically to the point where the
deficit was no higher than the prescribed limit for that year. This proved too much for
Congress, and even for the Supreme Court, which found the automatic reduction
provision unconstitutional.
deficit ceiling: a congressionally mandated limit on the size of the federal budget
deficit
In 2011 and again in 2013 the Obama administration faced a potential crisis over
the near breaching of what is known as the U.S. debt ceiling. (This is different from a
deficit ceiling. According to rules set by Congress, a vote of Congress is required to
increase the debt beyond a set amount, called the debt ceiling.) As the debt
approached the mandated ceiling, the United States faced the prospect of not being
able to borrow fresh funds to pay bonds that were coming due for payment. The risk
of such a default would be a decline in the perceived creditworthiness of the United
States and, as noted earlier, in 2011 Standard & Poor’s lowered the grade of U.S.
Treasury bonds from AAA to AA+, the first time in history that this had happened.
debt ceiling: a congressionally mandated limit on the size of the gross federal debt
Following heated and partisan negotiations, Congress and the President struck a
deal in 2011, allowing the debt ceiling to be raised (by about a trillion dollars). Since
then, debt ceiling deadlines have become an issue every few years, but have generally
been resolved without crisis, given the memory of 2011 and broad recognition of the
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
16
DRAFT
dangers of pushing the country close to the cliff of debt default.
The periodic focus on the debt ceiling is in many ways misleading. If Congress and
the president want to avoid increasing the debt, they would have to agree on a
balanced budget, in which case the debt ceiling would not become an issue. But that
is a lot easier said than done. A balanced budget would either require drastic cutbacks
in popular programs such as Social Security, or significant tax increases. In the long
run, of course, it is important to keep debt levels under control, but it is a mistake to
presume that the federal government should maintain zero debt. The ability to use
deficits at appropriate times to generate a fiscal stimulus is what sets the federal
government apart from the states and cities and possibly protects a weak economy
from sinking deeper.
An alternative approach to balanced budgets is the principle of functional finance,
expounded by economist Abba Lerner, which requires that national governments do
their utmost to ensure that aggregate demand remain at a reasonable level, ideally
achieving full employment. The assumption behind this principle is that the healthy
economic growth that resulted would ensure that the government could sustainably
finance its debt with greater tax revenue. The view is in direct conflict with that of deficit
“hawks,” who would maintain absolute limits on deficit and debt levels.
functional finance: the idea that a sovereign government should finance current
needs and provide for adequate aggregate demand to maintain employment levels
Who are the hawks? Even this is not a simple question; while Republicans are
traditionally regarded as the party of fiscal “prudence,” in recent years both
Republicans and Democrats have found themselves on either side of the controversy.
But there are major differences even among those not so concerned about deficits.
Keynesians like economist Paul Krugman believe that the government should be
spending more in such areas as infrastructure investment; Republican members of
Congress believe that the government should be taxing less. From the standpoint of
fiscal balance, the two approaches are equivalent. But from an equity standpoint they
are very different. Federal government spending tends to benefit the broad population,
while major tax cuts, including the Reagan tax cuts of the 1980s and the Bush tax cuts
of the 2000s, have disproportionately benefited the well-off. (We analyze the 2017 tax
cuts in section 5.2 below). As noted in Chapter 30, tax cuts that primarily benefit upper-
income groups have contributed to the recent intensification of inequality in the United
States.
4.4 IMPOSED AUSTERITY: THE CASE OF THE EUROPEAN UNION
In the years following the fiscal crisis, the member countries of the European Union
(EU) confronted issues similar to those in the United States, but their response was
quite different. Recessions in countries like Greece, Spain, and Portugal caused
government revenues to fall and expenditures to rise, increasing deficit and debt
levels. In Europe, much of the crisis focused on what is called sovereign debtthat
is, government debt, especially government debt in a currency that the government
does not control.
sovereign debt: government debt, especially debt denominated in a currency that
the government does not control
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
17
DRAFT
Nineteen countries within the European Union have adopted the euro as their
currency. In order to participate in the euro currency, EU member countries must meet
certain convergence criteria. One criterion concerns government finances and
requires both that a country’s annual deficit not exceed 3 percent of GDP and that its
national debt not exceed 60 percent of GDP.
6
After the country is accepted into the
eurozone (countries that have adopted the euro as the national currency), the
restriction is relaxed somewhat under circumstances of extreme economic difficulty
(which explains how, for example, Greece, Italy, and others can have a debt-GDP ratio
much higher than 60 percent), but countries must then demonstrate that they are
making progress toward once again achieving the target amounts.
convergence criteria: the requirements that EU member countries must satisfy
as a condition of participating in the eurozone
Table 31.2 shows deficit and debt figures for Portugal, Italy, Ireland, Greece, and
Spain. Although all are still far from satisfying the convergence criteria (though a few
do meet it for deficits), only for Greece have leading experts even discussed possible
expulsion from the eurozone. But this does not mean that governments have not taken
action to reduce their negative budget numbers.
Authorities in the European Union insisted on a policy of austerity for deeply
indebted countries. Austerity policy requires severely indebted countries to reduce
expenditures and/or raise taxes to balance their budgets. The main drawback to such
an approach, as noted, is that it worsens already existing recessionary conditions.
Consequently, the resulting austerity measures pushed unemployment rates in some
of the worst-hit countries to Great Depression levels. Instead of pursuing functional
finance, the affected countries made fiscal balance paramount.
austerity: a policy of deficit cutting that reduces public expenditures or raises taxes
to balance the budget
Greece, Spain, and, to a lesser degree, Portugal have experienced considerable
social unrest as a result of austerity policies. There was widespread resentment of
governments that were willing to bail out investors in the financial industry but then ask
the public to accept higher taxes and spending cuts to pay for the bailouts. The
populations of these countries include millions of retirees who see grave threats to the
government pensions on which they rely for income support in their old age. So despite
pursuing fiscal policies very different from those used in the United States, the
distributional effect was similar—in other words, greater inequality. It is only in more
recent years that the European Union’s austerity policy has been relaxed, with fiscal
and monetary authorities moving modestly in the direction of promoting more
expansionary policy (see Box 31.1).
Since countries that are members of the eurozone do not have their own
currencies, they, unlike the United States, cannot conduct expansionary monetary
policy, and austerity rules require that they implement contractionary fiscal policy.
Their inability to counterbalance contractionary fiscal policy with expansionary
monetary policy severely reduces their policy tools to promote economic recovery. The
ability of indebted eurozone economies to borrow is also constrained, since too much
borrowing could drive the interest rates on their debt to unsustainable levels.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
18
DRAFT
Table 31.2 EU Deficit and Debt Levels in 2016 (percentage of GDP)
Deficit
Debt
Portugal
4.4
146.5
Italy
2.4
157.3*
Ireland
0.6
89.4*
Greece
+0.7
185.2
Spain
4.5
117.2
Source: OECD, www.oecd.org.
*2015
The United States does not confront the same problems, for two reasons. The first
is that, at least up to the present, its bond yields are not nearly as sensitive to its
escalating debt as are yields in other countries. This issue is related to the U.S.
position in the global economy, which, as noted in Chapter 29, has much to do with
the historic prestige and strength of the U.S. dollar. The U.S. dominance in this regard
may change in the future, but as of now the United States enjoys the advantages of
having a “safe haven” currency.
The second reason is that the Fed is far more flexible than its EU counterpart, the
European Central Bank (ECB). The ECB’s singular agenda is controlling inflation, and
it does not consider the fiscal conditions in individual countries. The Fed, in contrast,
has a dual mandate to address both inflation and unemployment, providing more
flexibility to address short-term economic problems.
7
As we have seen since the
financial crisis, the United States has the ability to employ countercyclical fiscal policy
and use monetary policy such as lower interest rates and quantitative easing to try to
spur economic activity. The comparison between the experiences of the United States
and Europe following the fiscal crisis suggest that there are advantages to having
greater leeway in fiscal policy, even at the cost of temporarily increased deficits.
BOX 31.1 THE EU MOVES FROM AUSTERITY TO “FISCAL EXPANSION”
The European Commission (EC) approved a 0.5 per cent “fiscal expansion” across
the euro area in 2017, in the first signal of a shift in the EU’s policy of austerity. In a
communique announcing its autumn 2017 economic package, the EC announced,
“at this point in time, the commission considers that there is a case for a
significantly more positive fiscal stance for the euro area,” though it noted that the
recovery is still not accelerating. The communique stated that, for member states,
the appropriate fiscal expansion could be 0.3 per cent at the lower end of the
scale, or as high as 0.8 per cent in some cases.
Announcing the new development, which was agreed following a meeting of all
28 EU commissioners in Brussels, commission president Jean-Claude Juncker
said the recommendation of a positive fiscal stance would “support the recovery
and the monetary policy of the European Central Bank, which should not bear the
burden alone.”
“Every member state should play its part: those that can afford it need to invest
more, while those which have less fiscal space should pursue reforms and growth-
friendly fiscal consolidation,” he said.
Commissioner for Economic Affairs Pierre Moscovici said this was the first time
the EU had encouraged fiscal expansion, and that it was a reflection of the times,
when many citizens felt let down by globalization and are questioning the EU’s
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
19
DRAFT
policy of austerity. The encouragement of a more positive fiscal stance would help
overcome the risk of “low growth, low inflation,” he said. Moscovici, however,
defended the EU’s budget rules, noting that the stability and growth pact had
helped to bring the overall deficit down from 6 per cent in 2010 to 1.25 per cent in
2016.“We can’t pretend that the stability and growth pact is not working—it is
effective,” he said.
Despite Spain and Portugal missing budget targets this year, the commission
said no regional funds would be withheld from the countries, though they remain
“at risk of non-compliance” with EU rules.
Source: Lynch, 2016.
Discussion Questions
1. Should there be a balanced budget amendment to the Constitution? What
problems might such an amendment create?
2. What is the difference between austerity and stimulus? Which track has the
European Union followed? How is it different from what the United States has
done? Which do you think is a better approach?
5. DEFICIT PROJECTIONS AND POLICY RESPONSES
5.1 DEFICIT PROJECTIONS
The U.S. annual federal deficit declined from a peak of 10 percent of GDP in 2009 to
3.2 percent of GDP in fiscal 2016 (Figure 31.9). The Congressional Budget Office
(CBO), which provides nonpartisan economic analysis for Congress, projects that the
deficit will increase again to about 5 percent of GDP by 2022, and then remain close
to 5 percent for the next six years (Figure 31.10).
8
This is significantly greater than the
annual average over the past 50 years, 3.1 percent, implying a more rapid increase in
overall federal debt.
Figure 31.10 Projected Annual Deficit as a Percent of GDP
Source: Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2018 to 2028
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
20
DRAFT
The federal debt held by the public is projected to increase from about 75 percent
of GDP in 2017 to about 95 percent by 2028 (Figure 31.11). According to the CBO
analysis, which followed passage of the Tax Cut and Jobs Act of 2017: Federal budget
deficits are set to increase rapidly [in 2018] and over the next four years, and then to
remain largely stable relative to the size of the economy—but at a very high level by
historical standards—over the rest of the projection period.”
Figure 31.11 Projection for Federal Debt Held by the Public
Source: Congressional Budget Office, The Budget and Economic Outlook: 2018 to 2028.
In addition to the 2017 tax cuts, the CBO has identified four reasons that deficits
are projected to remain at relatively high levels even as the economy stabilizes:
1. The demographic pressures of an aging population
2. An increase in health-care costs
3. An increase in federal subsidies for health care
4. An increase in interest payments on the federal debt
Note that the first three factors are closely related and suggest that a focus on
health care should be an important component of any significant long-term budgetary
reforms in the United States. The CBO explains:
The aging of the baby-boom generation portends a significant and sustained
increase in coming years in the share of the population that will receive benefits
from Social Security and Medicare and long-term care services financed through
Medicaid. Moreover, per capita spending on health care is likely to continue to grow
faster than per capita spending on other goods and services for many years. . . .
Without significant changes in the laws governing Social Security, Medicare, and
Medicaid, those factors will boost federal outlays as a percentage of GDP well
above the average of the past several decades. . . Unless the laws governing those
programs are changed—or the increased spending is accompanied by sufficiently
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
21
DRAFT
lower spending on other programs, sufficiently higher revenues, or a combination
of the two—deficits will be much larger in the future than they have tended to be in
the past.
9
Social Security and Medicare taxes and outlays are, as we have seen, considered
“off budget.” In other words, Social Security taxes are, for example, meant to finance
Social Security benefits, not military or social expenditures. One might, therefore,
justifiably question whether old age or health-related taxes and spending should be
affected by the debate over the deficit.
The reality is, unfortunately, more complex. Since, as noted earlier, one of the
many federal government creditors (i.e., buyers of Treasury bonds) is the Social
Security trust fund itself, many of the hundreds of billions of dollars held in the fund
are invested in government debt. Social Security recipients are therefore, in part, paid
from the income as federal debt held by the Social Security system comes due. This
reinforces concerns about future sustainability of the deficit. As the number of retirees
grows relative to the working age population (which contributes Social Security taxes),
full payment of Social Security benefits will require an additional contribution from the
Federal budget, increasing the size of the deficit and eventually putting Social Security
payouts in jeopardy(see Box 31.2).
BOX 31.2 HOW CAN THE U.S. SALVAGE SOCIAL SECURITY?
In its most recent report to Congress, the Social Security Board of Trustees
projects that the Social Security program’s funds will be depleted by 2034, after
which only 79 percent of what was promised to American retirees will be paid out.
The “crisis” of Social Security isn’t that it’s going bankrupt or that there won’t be
any benefits paid out after 2034. It’s that the system may not be able to pay all of
what retirees put in and were promised—an issue that, according to many polls, is
very important to many Americans both young and elderly.
What can be done to put Social Security on a sounder basis before 2034? A
number of possible solutions have been proposed:
Raising the payroll tax by about 2 percent, which would be enough to make
Social Security solvent for the next 75 years.
Raising or eliminating the cap on the Social Security payroll tax. The Social
Security tax only applies to income earned below a certain threshold—
$128,400 in 2018. It is thus regressive, taking a higher proportion of income
from lower-income taxpayers. Eliminating the cap would make the tax less
regressive by requiring more affluent taxpayers to contribute more.
Raising the retirement age, which would reduce the amount of benefits paid
out over the lifetime of recipients.
Indexing benefits to inflation using techniques such as the chained CPI
(discussed in Chapter 20) that yield a smaller annual increase in benefits.
There really are only two basic answers to the Social Security problem: increase
revenue or reduce benefits. Any potential solution will thus run into political
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
22
DRAFT
opposition from those who would pay higher taxes or receive lower benefits. To be
politically feasible, any potential compromise needs to be perceived as fair as well
as effective in preserving income security for everyone in the system. Measures
such as raising the retirement age would disproportionately harm lower-income
individuals, as they rely more heavily on Social Security benefits, and would
therefore be likely to encounter significant political opposition.
Source: Bouree Lam, “How Can the U.S. Salvage Social Security? The Atlantic,
April 2016.
The issues of meeting growing needs and of diminishing tax revenues are linked.
Assuming that the CBO projections on deficit increases are correct, lower tax receipts
will aggravate problems such as the adequate funding of Social Security and health
costs. Advocates of the 2017 tax cuts argued that the positive effect of the tax cuts on
the economy will, over the long term, bring in higher revenues—essentially the
“supply-side” argument discussed above. Experience so far has shown that, while tax
cuts can partly “pay for themselves” through promoting higher growth and revenue,
the overall effect of tax cuts is higher, not lower, deficits. Critics of the 2017 tax cuts
point out that lower revenues resulting from the tax cuts, which mainly benefit high-
income individuals and corporations, will increase pressure to cut social programs
such as Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid in the future.
5.2 POLICY CHOICES
The principle that the United States requires long-term budgetary reform is widely
accepted. The 2017 tax cuts, however, brought deficit issues to the forefront as a more
immediate problem. As noted earlier, the deficit had fallen to a low of 3.2 percent of
GDP by 2016, or $527 billion. But as of 2018 the deficit was “set to widen significantly
in the next few years, and is expected to top $1 trillion in 2020 despite healthy
economic growth."
10
In 2018, this projection for a $1 trillion deficit was advanced to
2019 as a result of the Trump administration tax cuts.
11
As implied in the preceding
CBO quotation, the basic math dictates that the choices for reform are limited to three
options:
1. Revenue (i.e., tax) increases
2. Spending decreases
3. Some combination of revenue increases and spending decreases
The controversial issues concern which taxes should be increased (and for whom),
and which expenditures should be cut. The recent patterns of Federal spending and
revenues give some indications of what the options for the future may be. Federal
spending declined from a peak of 24.4 percent of GDP in 2009 to 20.9 percent in 2017.
It is, however, projected to increase somewhat over the next decade, to just over 22
percent of GDP. Most of this increase will be due to either military spending or debt
financing. Non-defense discretionary spending, in contrast, has been declining as a
share of GDP since 2010, and is expected to continue declining, according to the
Center on Budget and Policy Priorities (Figure 31.12).
12
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
23
DRAFT
Figure 31.12: Non-Defense Discretionary Spending as Percent of GDP
Source: Congressional Budget Office; Office of Management and Budget.
Federal revenues increased from a low of 14.6 percent of GDP in 2009 to 18.2
percent in 2015, but are expected to fall again as a result of the 2017 tax cuts. A
combination of increased spending and falling revenues means increasing deficits
(see Box 31.3).
BOX 31.3: DEBT CRISIS COMING?
In April 2018, two groups of economists predicted a coming debt crisis. But they
offered two different perspectives on the causes and cures for the crisis. A group of
conservative economists at the Hoover Institution warned that “rising interest rates
and increasing deficits threaten to build upon each other to send public debt spiraling
upward even faster.” They pointed to “sharply rising entitlement spending” as the
root cause of deficit problems, and recommended that Congress “reform and restrain
the growth of entitlement programs” as a remedy.
13
In response, a group of economists, including former Fed chair Janet Yellen and
a group of former chairs of the White House Council of Economic Advisors, argued
that “it is dishonest to single out entitlements for blame. . . the primary reason the
deficit in coming years will now be higher than expected is the reduction in revenue
from last year’s tax cuts, not an increase in spending”.
14
According to a study by the
Congressional Budget Office, the impacts of the 2017 tax cuts would add more than
$1.8 trillion to deficits over the period 2018-2028, from lost revenue and higher
interest payments.
15
Meanwhile
“the main entitlement programs are Social Security, Medicare, veterans’ benefits,
and Medicaid. These widely popular programs are indeed large and projected to
grow as a share of the economy, not because of increased generosity of benefits but
because of the aging of the population and the increase in economy wide health
costs.”
16
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
24
DRAFT
In addition to cutting entitlement programs, the Hoover Institution economists
suggest increasing revenues with “pro-growth tax and regulatory policies”, and they
see the corporate tax cuts adopted in 2017 as a good first step. Yellen and her co-
authors agree with some elements of corporate tax reform, but they fault the 2017
bill for simply lowering rates while failing to close loopholes. They see the individual
tax cuts as being as “ill-timed stimulus”, providing an unneeded boost to an economy
already close to full employment. They advocate instead “a balanced approach that
combines increased revenue with reduced spending.”
Sources: Boskin et al, 2018; Baily et al, 2018.
A range of possible policies for reducing future deficits can be summarized as
follows:
Revenue Side Policies
Increase revenues through growth-promoting policies. This sounds appealing,
but the historical record shows that the overall effect of broad tax cuts yields
lower, not higher revenues. Some kinds of tax reform, such as lowering rates
while closing loopholes, might be revenue-neutral or revenue-positive.
Increase revenues through repealing tax cuts for upper-income individuals
and large corporations. It would also be possible to increase revenues by
raising tax rates more broadly, but this would tend to accentuate inequality by
penalizing middle and low income earners.
Increase revenue through new, possibly environmentally oriented, taxes such
as taxes on carbon emissions or consumption taxes. These taxes could also
have a regressive effect unless accompanied by rebates for lower-income
taxpayers.
Spending Side Policies
Reduce “mandatory” spending on programs such as Social Security,
Medicare, Medicaid, and the Affordable Care Act. Cuts to these programs are
likely to increase inequity, but spending reductions could be achieved through
holding down health care costs, which has already been achieved to some
extent in Medicare and through Affordable Care Act provisions
Reduce discretionary spending in areas such as military, education,
highways, scientific research, and the environment. Non-defense military
spending is already declining, and with increased infrastructure spending
needs, possibilities for reductions in this area are limited.
Increase efficiency of spending in health care and other areas, seeking more
“bang for the buck” including state-federal and public-private collaboration
initiatives.
To the extent that any of the above policies can be successful in reducing
deficits and long-term growth of the debt, interest costs will also be reduced.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
25
DRAFT
There is broad agreement that some combination of these policies will be needed
to avoid a long-term increase in debt, but which policies to implement remains
controversial.
5.4 DEBT AND DEFICITS IN CONTEXT
The debate over debts and deficits should be placed in a larger macroeconomic
context as well as a social and environmental context. Given the strong negative
impacts of wide inequalities on the social and economic health of a society, it makes
sense that major federal policies, regarding both spending and taxing, should
emphasize reducing inequality. Addressing environmental concerns and improving
infrastructure are also important priorities.
Our review of the history of debt and deficits indicates that neither is inherently bad
for the economy, and that deficits in times of recession may be essential to helping the
economy recover. But some degree of balance is required. Deficits must be limited as
a percent of GDP, and long-term increases in the debt burden should be avoided. This
represents a major challenge, but policies are available to promote both a healthy
economy and a manageable debt, provided such policies can gain sufficient political
support.
Discussion Questions
1. Do you think that we can reduce deficits while also avoiding an increase in tax
rates? Why would political leaders consider tax hikes? Should everyone
experience the same increase?
2. Are there tax policies that can reduce the deficit while also addressing social and
environmental problems?
REVIEW QUESTIONS
1. What is the difference between the national debt and a deficit?
2. What years were debt/GDP levels the highest in the United States? What years
were the lowest?
3. What was the role of the national debt in the early period of U.S. history? What was
Hamilton’s vision for the U.S national debt?
4. How did the national debt picture change with the New Deal and World War II?
5. What factors contributed to the federal surplus during the Clinton administration,
and why did it turn into a deficit in the following Bush administration?
6. Summarize some of the potential problems with government debt.
7. What does it mean to monetize the debt?
8. How do European policies of austerity differ from U.S. policies regarding debt and
deficits?
9. What do we mean by “twin deficits”? How are the two types of deficits related?
10. What are the pros and cons of a balanced budget amendment?
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
26
DRAFT
EXERCISES
1. Go to Federal Reserve Economic Database (http:// research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/),
select ‘browse data by category’ and look in national accounts for recent data on
the U.S. national debt as a percent of GDP and recent figures on budget deficits.
What does this tell you about recent trends? Compare the period 1990–2007 to
more recent years. Do the figures indicate that we may be returning to a more
“normal” situation regarding debt and deficits?
2. Search the Internet and locate relatively recent debt / GDP data for European
countries. Construct a table of eurozone members and their debt / GDP ratios
based on your search. Review the convergence criteria for participation in the
eurozone presented in the chapter. Don’t forget to document your source(s)! What
did you discover in this exercise? Explain your answer.
3. The chapter identifies and explains several reasons why it is inappropriate to
compare the government debt to the debt of a private citizen. Which of these
explanations are consistent with the presentation in the chapter?
a. Governments have the ability to “roll over” their debt more or less endlessly.
b. Governments cannot default on their debt obligations.
c. A significant portion of government debt is owed to U.S. citizens.
d. The U.S. government pays interest on its debt in dollars that it prints.
e. Government debt is always used to finance investment.
4. The chapter identifies and explains several reasons why we are likely to observe
relatively high deficits in the U.S. even as the economy stabilizes. Which of these
explanations is consistent with the chapter’s presentation?
a. Health care costs are expected to continue to increase.
b. Young adults are having too many children and that creates demographic
pressures.
c. Federal subsidies of health care are expected to grow.
d. The rising costs of higher education will contribute to deficits.
e. Interest payments on the debt will likely increase in the future.
5. The chapter is very clear that it’s dangerous to assume that, “government debt is
never a concern.” Which of the following are reasons articulated in the chapter for
why debt can be a concern?
a. Foreign holders of U.S. debt may decide to sell their bonds.
b. A larger share of future budgets must be devoted to interest payments.
c. It is always unwise for governments to get into debt
d. Interest payments to high-income individuals could exacerbate income
inequality.
e. Deficit spending during a recession will only make the economic downturn
worse.
6. Match each concept in Column A with a definition or example in Column B.
Column A
Column B
a. Debt
1. The portion of the gross federal debt that is owed to
individuals or groups within the country
b. Deficit
2. A congressionally mandated limit on the size of the
federal debt
c. Gross federal debt
3. The portion of the gross federal debt that is owed to
foreign individuals or groups
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
27
DRAFT
d. Debt held by the
public
4. A stock variable that represents the accumulation of
deficits over many years
e. Internal debt
5. The gross federal debt minus the debt owed to other
government accounts such as Social Security and
Medicare
f. External debt
6. A policy of deficit cutting that reduces public
expenditures and/or raises taxes to balance the
budget
g. Monetizing the debt
7. A flow variable that measures the excess of
spending over revenue collections
h. Debt ceiling
8. The requirements that EU countries must satisfy as
a condition for participating in the Eurozone
i. Austerity
9. The purchase of new debt from the Treasury
Department by the Federal Reserve
j. Convergence criteria
10. Total amount owed by the federal government to all
claimants, including foreigners, the public in the
United States, and other government accounts
REFERENCES
Baily, Martin Neil, Jason Furman, Alan B. Krueger, Laura D’Andrea Tyson, and Janet
Yellen. 2018. “A Debt Crisis is Coming. But Don’t Blame Entitlements.” The
Washington Post, April 8, 2018.
Boskin, Michael J., John H. Cochrane, John F. Cogan, George P. Schulz, and John
B. Taylor. 2018. “A Debt Crisis is on the Horizon.” The Washington Post, March 27,
2018.
Center on Budget and Policy Priorities. 2017. “Policy Basics: Non-Defense
Discretionary Programs.” August 2017. https://www.cbpp.org/research/federal-
budget/policy-basics-non-defense-discretionary-programs.
Congressional Budget Office (CBO). No date. The Budget and Economic Outlook:
2018 to 2028.
Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2012. “Choices for Deficit Reduction.” November
2012. https://www.cbo.gov/publication/43692.
Congressional Budget Office (CBO). 2018. “CBO’s Projections of Deficits and Debt
for the 2018–2028 Period.” April 2018. https://www.cbo.gov/publication/53781.
Kaplan, Thomas. 2018. “Federal Budget Deficit Projected to Soar to over $1 Trillion
in 2020.” The New York Times, April 9, 2018.
Lam, Bouree. 2016. “How Can the U.S. Salvage Social Security?” The Atlantic, April
2016.
Lynch, Suzanne. 2016. “EU Moves from Austerity to ‘Fiscal Expansion’.” The Irish
Times, November 16, 2016.
Principles of Economics in Context, Second EditionSample Chapter for Early Release
28
DRAFT
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development, General Government
Debt. https://data.oecd.org/gga/general-government-debt.htm.
Federal Reserve Economic Data, St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank.
https://fred.stlouisfed.org/
U.S. Treasury Department. 2016. Tables OFS-1; Distribution of Federal Securities by
Class of Investors and Type of Issues, Table OFS-2; Estimated Ownership of US
Treasury Securities and Table.
U.S. Treasury Department. 2018. Major Foreign Holders of Treasury Securities.
Wasson, Erik, and Sarah McGregor. 2018. “U.S. Deficit to Surpass $1 Trillion.”
Bloomberg News, April 9, 2018.
NOTES
1
The federal fiscal year runs from October to September, so fiscal 2017 is October 2016 to
September 2017, and fiscal 2018 is October 2017 to September 2018.
2
Although the arithmetic requires that the debt rise when the government is in deficitbecause the
only way to finance a deficit is to borrow moneyin the case of a surplus it is possible for the
government to hold some funds in reserve, for example, to finance future expenditures. It is usually
the case, however, that governments will use some or all of a surplus to reduce existing debt.
3
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, FRED Economic Database, Federal Debt: Total Public Debt as
Percent of Gross Domestic Product. https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/GFDEGDQ188S.
4
Wasson and McGregor, 2018.
5
This process is often described or depending on one’s viewpoint, derided as “printing money.”
6
The other three, which need not concern us here, are (1) an inflation rate no more than 1.5 percent
higher than the average in the three best-performing EU members; (2) not having devalued domestic
currency for at least two years; and (3) long-term interest rate no higher than 2 percent above that in
the three best EU inflation performers.
7
The “dual mandate” results from amendments to the Federal Reserve Act in 1977. Prior to 1977, the
Fed did not have a history of pursuing job growth and was viewed primarily as an inflation fighter.
8
Congressional Budget Office, 2018.
9
Congressional Budget Office, 2012.
10
Kaplan, 2018.
11
Wasson and McGregor, 2018.
12
Center on Budget and Policy Priorities, 2017.
13
Boskin et al, 2018.
14
Baily et al., 2018.
15
Kaplan, 2018.
16
Baily et al., 2018.