THE PRESIDENT’S
COMMISSION ON AN
ALL-VOLUNTEER
ARMED FORCE
FEBRUARY 1970
-
Official editions of the report of The President’s
Commission on an All-Volunteer Armed Force may
be freely used, duplicated, or published, in whole or
in part, except to the extent that, where expressly
noted in the publications, they contain copyrighted
materials reprinted by permission of the copyright
holders.
Library of Congress Catalogue Number: 78-605447.
ii
Dear Mr. President:
Thomas s. Gates
PRESIDENT’S COMM,SSlON ON AN ALL-VOLUNTEER ARMED FORCE
71‘ 1*51so* CL,. *.w.
w.**I*~TO*. D.C. 2054s
February 6, 1970
Dear Mr. President:
It was an honor to be named by you to membership on the President’s
Commission on an All-Volunteer Armed Force. I looked forward
to serving on this Commission because it confronts an extremely
important issue. Unfortunately, a combination of a minor illness in
December and an operation at the beginning of January prevented
my participating in the last five Commission meetings during which
specific recommendations and various drafts of the report were
discussed.
Because I was able to play only a small part in its shaping I did not
feel it was proper for me to sign the report, and advised the Chairman,
Thomas Gates, accordingly in late December.
I am writing now to express my regret at not being able to sign this
report. Although I have been unable to share in its specific recom-
mendations, I would like to endorse the basic idea of moving towards
an all-volunteer armed force, and to express my hope that you will
be able to take steps in the near future to reduce reliance on
conscription.
Respectfully,
/
Roy Wilkins
The Honorable Richard M. Nixon
The White House
Washington, D. C.
FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE MARCH 27, 1969
STATEMENT BY THE PRESIDENT
ANNOUNCING THE CREATION
OF THE COMMISSION
To achieve the goal of a” all-volunteer force we will require the best
efforts of our military establishment and the best advice we can
obtain from eminent citizens and experts in many related ‘helds of
national endeavor. For this purpose, I have today appointed a”
Advisory Commission on a” All-Volunteer Armed Force under the
Chairmanship of the Honorable Thomas S. Gates, Jr., former Sec-
retary of Defense.
I have directed the Commission to develop a comprehensive plan for
eliminating conscription and moving toward a” all-volunteer armed
force. The Commission will study a broad range of possibilities for
increasing the supply of volunteers for service, including increased
pay, benefits, recruitment incentives and other practicable measures
to make military careers more. attractive to young men. It will
consider possible changes in selection stahdards and in utilization
policies which may assist in eliminating the need for inductions. It
will study the estimated costs and savings resulting from an all-
volunteer force, as well as the broader social and economic implica-
tions of this program.
The transition to a” all-volunteer armed force must, of course, be
handled cautiously and responsibly so that our national security is
fully maintained. The Commission will determine what standby
machinery for the draft will be required in the event of a national
emergency and will give serious consideration to our requirements
for a” adequate reserve forces program.
I have instructed the Department of Defense and other agencies of
the Executive Branch to support this study and provide needed
information and assistance as a matter of high priority.
vii
PRESIDENT’S COMMISSION ON AN
ALL-VOLUNTEER ARMED FORCE
Thomas Gates
CHllRYlM
Thomas Curtis
Frederick Dent
Milton Friedman
Crawford Greenewalt
Alan Greenspan
Chairman of the Executive Committee of
Morgan Guaranty Trust Co., former
Secretary of Defense. New York City
Vice-President and General Counsel,
Encyclopedia Britannica, former
Congressman from Missouri and ranking
Republican on Joint Economic Committee,
United States Congress. St. Louis, Missouri
President, Mayfair Mills, Spartanburg,
South Carolina
Paul Snowdon Russell Distinguished
Service Professor of Economics,
University of Chicago. Chicago, Illinois
Chairman, Finance Committee,
E. I. duPont de Nemours and Co.
Wilmington, Delaware.
Chairman of the Board, Townsend-
Greenspan &Co. Economic consultants.
New York City
VI”
Alfred Gruenther
Stephen Herbits
Theodore Hesburgh
Jerome Holland
John Kemper
Jeanne Noble
Lauris Norstad
W. Allen Wallis
Roy Wilkins
Former Supreme Allied Commander,
Europe. Washington, D. C.
Student, Georgetown University Law
Center. Washington, D. C.
President, University of Notre Dame,
Chairman, US. Commission on Civil
Rights. South Bend, Indiana
President, Hampton Institute.
Hampton, Virginia
Headmaster, Phillips Academy.
Andover, Massachusetts.
Professor, New York University.
Vice President, National Council of Negro
Women. Former member, National
Advisory Commission on Selective Service.
New York City
Chairman of the Board of Owens-Corning
Fiberglass Corp. Former Supreme Allied
Commander, Europe. New York City
President, University of Rochester.
Rochester, New York
Executive Director, NAACP.
New York City
ix
COMMISSION STAFF
Executive Director
William H. Meckling
Diictors of Research
Deputy Executive Director
Dr. Stuart Altman
David I. Callard
Dr. Harry J. Gilman
David Kassing
Editor
Dr. Walter Y. Oi
Richard J. Whalen
Research Projects
Lt. Cal. Ames Albr-Potential
for Civilian Substitution (U.S.
A ml y)
Robert Barre-Oficer Rrcrrrit-
“lent
Lt. Cal. Herman Boland-Re-
serve Requirements and Sup-
ply (U.S. Army)
Dr. Alvin Cook-Air Force En-
listment
Alan Fechter-Army Ettlistmmts
Brian Forst-Personnel Reqrtire-
nwnts
Burton Gray--Navy Enlistments
Dr. Harry Grubert--Navy Reen-
listments
Ronald N. Hansen-The Con-
scription Tax
Stewart Kemp-Recruiting Prac-
tices
Mordechai Lando-Conscription
of Physicians
James McConnell-Conscription
in Europe
Judith Blaine
Mary Clark
Patricia Flanary
Eleanor Gages
William Holahan
Research
J. Houston McCulloch-Civilian
Earnings
Gary Nelson-Arnry Rrenlist-
mmts
Dr. Dave M. O’Neil-Costs of
Military Personnel Turnover
John L. Rafuse-Conscription in
America
Dave Resume--Utilization of
Skills by the Armed Forces
Dr. Larry Sjaastad-The Con-
scription Tax
David Stigler-Conscription and
the Constitution
John Sullivan-Qlralitative Re-
quirements of Enlisted Men
Dr. Rodney Weiher--Navy Re-
enlistments
Dr. Robert White-Air Force
Enlistnwnts
Capt. Robert Wilburn-Air
Force Reenlistments (U.S. Air
Force)
Dr. Desmond P. Wilson--Vet-
cram in Society
Assistants
Jesse Horack
Andrea Horn&t
Ruth Kurtz
Joanne Linnerooth
Mary Ostrander
x
Data Processions
James Parsells
Shelia Rafferty
tmce statI
Dimitrios Drivas
Robin D. Margenau
Candy Haga
Warren Parker
Dorothy Hitselberger
Marty Roberts
Rose Lawrence
Allaire Williams
Consulting Organizations
Center for Naval Analyses
Institute for Defense Analysis
Rand Corporation
CONTENTS
Part1
INTRODUCTION
Chapter 1
PROTECTING THE FREE SOCIETY 5
Chapter 2
THE DEBATE 11
Chapter 3
CONSCRlPTION ,IS A TAX
Chapter 4
MILITARY PERSONNEL REQUIREMENTS
Chapter 5
COMPENSATION AND MANAGEMENT
OF MILITARY PERSONNEL
Chapter 6
OFFICER PROCUREMENT AND RETENTION
Chapter 7
RECRUITMENT
Chapter 8
CONSCRIPTION OF PHYSICIANS
Chapter 9
RESERVES
Chapter 10
THE STANDBY DRAFT
Chapter 11
BUDGETARY IMPLICATIONS
Chapter 12
OBJECTIONS TO AN
ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCE
Chapter 13
CONSCRIPTION IN AMERICA
Chapter 14
RECENT FOREIGN EXPERIENCE
WITH VOLUNTARISM
Chapter 15
ALTERNATIVES TO AN
ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCE
Appendix A
BUDGET EXPENDITURES FOR ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCES
Appendix B
MILITARY AND CIVILIAN COMPENSATION
Appendix C
REVIEW OF THE 1966 DEPT. OF DEFENSE DRAFT STUDY
203
23
35
49
69
83
87
97
119
125
129
159
169
173
117
197
xiii
PART I
INTRODUCTION
The Commission’s report consists of two parts-the first,
Chapter I and 2; and the second, Chapters 3 through 15.
In Chapter 1 we take up the questions we recognized as
critical from the outset: Is an all-volunteer force feasible? Are there
practicable reforms in present procedures that will maintain voluntary
forces of the size and quality deemed necessary for national security?
Chapter 1 summarizes the considerations underlying our conclusion
that an all-volunteer force is feasible and lists our recommendations
for major reforms.
Chapter 2 deals with another set of questions: Regardless
of whether an all-volunteer force is feasible, is it desirable? Will
voluntary recruitment weaken our democratic society and have
harmful political and social effects? The Commission has studied
such issues at great length, in the light of whatever relevant evidence
we could assemble. Chapter 2 notes some of the main objections
raised to ending conscription and summarizes our responses to them.
In Part II of the report, the Commission presents the pertinent
evidence gathered during its inquiry and the analysis underlying its
recommendations which form the essential background of the
Commission’s findings.
Of course, the members of the Commission, in expressing
their individual views on this broad range of issues, would choose
a variety of phrases to express their particular emphases and there-
fore should not be held individually responsible for each and every
sentence of the report.
1
CHAPTER 1
PROTECTING THE FREE SOCIETY
Since the founding of the republic, a primary task of the
government of the United States has been to provide for the
common defense of a society established to secure the blessings
of liberty and justice. Without endangering the nation’s
security, the means of defense should support the aims of the
society.
The armed forces today play an honorable and important
part in promoting the nation’s security, as they have since our
freedoms were won on the battlefield at Yorktown. A
fundamental consideration that has guided this Commission is
the need to maintain and improve the effectiveness, dignity, and
status of the armed forces so they may continue to play their
proper role.
The Commission has not attempted to judge the size of the
armed forces the nation requires. Instead, it has accepted a
range of estimates made for planning purposes which anticipate
maintaining a total force in the future somewhere between
2,000,OOO and 3,000,OOO men.
We unanimously believe that the nation’s interests will be
better served by an all-volunteer force, supported by an
effective stand-by draft, than by a mixed force of volunteers
and conscripts; that steps should be taken promptly to move in
this direction; and that the first indispensable step is to remove
the present inequity in the pay of men serving their first term in
the armed forces.
The United States has relied throughout its history on a
voluntary armed force except during major wars and since
1948. A return to an all-volunteer force will strengthen our
freedoms, remove an inequity now imposed on the expression
of the patriotism that has never been lacking among our youth,
promote the efficiency of the armed forces, and enhance their
dignity. It is the system for maintaining standing forces that
minimizes government interference with the freedom of the
individual to determine his own life in accord with his values.
The Commission bases its judgments on long-range
considerations of what method of recruiting manpower will
strengthen our society’s foundations. The Commission’s
members have reached agreement on their recommendations
only as the result of prolonged study and searching debate, and
in spite of initial division. We are, of course, fully aware of the
current and frequently emotional public debate on national
priorities, foreign policy, and the military, but are agreed that
such issues stand apart from the question of when and how to
end conscription.
To judge the feasibility of an all-volunteer force, it is
important to grasp the dimensions of the recruitment problem
in the next decade. If conscription is continued, a stable
mid-range force of 2.5 million men (slightly smaller than
pre-Vietnam) will require 440,000 new enlisted men per year.
To maintain a fully voluntary stable force of the same effective
strength, taking into account lower personnel turnover, we
estimate that not more than 325,000 men will have to be
enlisted annually. In recent years about 500,000 men a year
have volunteered for military service. Although some of these
volunteered only because of the threat of the draft, the best
estimates are that at least half - 250,000 men - are “true
volunteers.” Such men would have volunteered even if there
had been no draft, and they did volunteer in spite of an entry
pay that is roughly 60 percent of the amount that men of their
age, education, and training could earn in civilian life.
6
The often ignored fact, therefore, is that our present
armed forces are made up predominantly of volunteers. All
those men who have more than four years of service - 38
percent of the total - are true volunteers; and so are at least a
third of those with fewer than four years of service.
The return to voluntary means of raising and maintaining
our armed forces should be seen in this perspective. With true
volunteers now providing some 250,000 enlisted men annually,
a fully volunteer force of 2.5 million men can be achieved by
improving pay and conditions of service sufficiently to induce
approximately 75,000 additional young men to enlist each year
from the 1.5 million men who will annually turn 19 and who
will also meet the physical, moral, and mental requirements. A
voluntary force of 3.0 million men would require 400,000
enlistments each year, or 150,000 additional volunteers from
the 1.5 million eligible 19-year olds. Smaller forces would
require fewer than 75,000 additional volunteers annually.
Reasonable improvements in pay and benefits in the early years
of service should increase the number of volunteers by these
amounts.
In any event, such improvements are called for on the
ground of equity alone. Because conscription has been used to
provide raw recruits, the pay of men entering the services has
been kept at a very low level. It has not risen nearly as rapidly
as the pay of experienced military personnel, and it is now
about 60 percent of comparable civilian pay. Similarly, the pay
of first- term officers has not been kept in line with the pay of
more experienced officers, or with comparable civilians.
Correcting this inequity for first-term enlisted men and
f&t-term officers will add about $2.7 billion to the defense
budget in fiscal 1971. Regardless of the fate of the draft, the
Commission strongly recommends elimination of this
discrimination against first-termers.
If the Commission’s recommendations are put into effect
for fiscal 1971, they will entail a budget increase of an
estimated $3.3 billion for the following expenditures:
Basic pay increase
(Billions) $2.68
Proficiency pay
.21
Reserve pay increase .I5
Additional medical corps expense .12
Recruiting, ROTC and miscellaneous 08
s3.24
7
The additional proficiency pay is required to attract
individuals in the first term with special skills and talents. The
additional reserve pay extends the increase in pay provided for
the active-duty forces to the reserves. and is called for as a step
toward a voluntary reserve. The additional outlay for a
voluntary medical corps is for increased pay to medical officers.
for medical student fellowships. and. where possible, for
contracting with civilian physicians to provide medical services
now rendered by military physicians.
Because most of this budget increase takes the form of
personal income, $540 million of it will be recovered by the
Treasury in federal income tax collections. The net increase in
the budget in fiscal 1971 after taking these tax collections into
account, will be $2.7 billion.
The Commission recommends that these additional funds
be provided effective July I. 1970. We believe, on the basis of
our study, that the increased pay and other recommended
improvements in personnel management will provide enough
additional volunteers during the transition to achieve an
all-volunteer force by July I. 197 I.
When force levels are stabilized, the additional
expenditures needed in the transition to a voluntary force will
be partly offset by savings engendered through lower turnover
and a reduction in the number of persons in training status.
Combining the expenditures to eliminate the present
inequity for first-turners, and other steps necessary to move to
an all-volunteer force with the savings that will accrue. the
Commission estimates that the added budget required to
maintain a fully voluntary force on a stable. continuing basis is:
S I .S billion for a 2.000.000 man force
$2. I billion for a 2300.000 man force
$4.6 billion for a 3.000.000 man force
These are net amounts. reflecting the personal income tax
collections that would be recovered.
Although the hrtdgrrctr,~~ e.~~errse of a volunteer armed
force will be higher than for the present mixed force of
volunteers and conscripts, the
actuul cost
will be lower. This
seemingly paradoxical statement is true because many of the
costs of manning our armed forces today are hidden and are not
8
reflected in the budget. Men who are forced to serve in the
military at artificially low pay are actually paying a form of tax
which subsidizes those in the society who do not serve.
Furthermore, the output of the civilian economy is reduced
because more men serve in the military than would be required
for an all-volunteer force of the same strength. This cost does
not show up in the budget. Neither does the loss in output
resulting from the disruption in the lives of young men who do
not serve. Neither do the costs borne by those men who do not
serve. but who rearrange their lives in response to the possibility
of being drafted. Taking these hidden and neglected costs into
account, the actual cost to the nation of an all-volunteer force
will be lower than the cost of the present force.
The Commission has attempted to allow for the
uncertainties of the future. In the event of a national emergency
requiring a rapid increase in the number of men under arms, the
first recourse should be to ready reserves, including the National
Guard. Like the active duty forces, these reserves can and
should be recruited on a voluntary basis. Whatever advantages
may be claimed for it, conscription cannot provide emergency
forces: it takes many months of training for civilians to become
soldiers. However, to provide for the possibility of an
emergency requiring a major increase in forces over an extended
period, we recommend that machinery be created for a standby
draft,
to take effect by act of Congress upon the
recommendation of the President.
The draft has been an accepted feature of American life
for a generation, and its elimination will represent still another
major change in a society much buffeted by change and alarmed
by violent attacks on the established order. Yet the status quo
can be changed constructively, and the society improved
peacefully, by responsible and responsive government. It is in
this spirit that the Commission has deliberated and arrived at its
recommendations. However necessary conscription may have
been in World War II, it has revealed many disadvantages in the
past generation. It has been a costly, inequitable, and divisive
procedure for recruiting men for the armed forces. It has
imposed heavy burdens on a small minority of young men while
easing slightly the tax burden on the rest of us. It has
introduced needless uncertainty into the lives of all our young
men. It has burdened draft boards with painful decisions about
who shall be compelled to serve and who shall be deferred. It
9
has weakened the political fabric of our society and impaired
the delicate web of shared values that alone enables a free
society to exist.
These costs of conscription would have to be borne if they
were a necessary price for defending our peace and security.
They are intolerable when there is an alternative consistent with
our basic national values.
The alternative is an all-volunteer force, and the
Commission recommends these steps toward it:
I. Raise the average level of basic pay for military
personnel in the first two years of service from $180
a month to $315 a month, the increase to become
effective on July I, 1970. This involves an increase in
total compensation (including the value of food,
lodging, clothing and fringe benefits) from $301 a
month to $437 a month. The basic pay of officers in
the first two years should be raised from an average
level of $428 a month to $578 a month, and their
total compensation from $717 a month to $869 a
month.
2. Make comprehensive improvements in conditions of
military service and in recruiting as set forth
elsewhere in the Report.
3. Establish a standby draft system by June 30, 1971 to
be activated by joint resolution of Congress upon
request of the President.
10
CHAPTER 2
THE DEBATE
“We have lived with the draft so long,” President Nixon
has pointed out, “that too many of us accept it as normal and
necessary.” Over the past generation, social, political, and
economic arrangements have grown up around conscription that
touch our lives in a great many ways. The elimination of the
draft will inevitably disrupt these arrangements and may be
disturbing to some. But beyond these narrow, often overlooked
interests lie broader considerations which have prompted
defenders of conscription to argue that an all-volunteer armed
force will have a variety of undesirable political, social, and
military effects.
In our meetings we have discussed the opposing arguments
extensively. As our recommendatiohs disclose, we have
unanimously concluded that the arguments for an all-volunteer
force are much the stronger. Yet, there can be no question of
the sincerity and earnest conviction of those who hold the views
we have rejected. In fairness to them, and to acquaint the
Nation with both sides of the issues, this chapter summarizes
11
the main arguments raised against the volunteer force and offers
answers to them. In succeeding chapters (noted in parentheses)
these arguments are taken up in detail.
A general point should be made here. The elimination of
conscription admittedly is a major social change, but it will
not
produce a major change in the personnel of our armed forces.
The majority of men serving today are volunteers. And many
who are now conscripted would volunteer once improvements
were made in pay and other conditions of service. Therefore,
the difference between an all-volunteer force and a mixed force
of conscripts and volunteers is limited to that minority who
would not serve unless conscripted and who would not
volunteer in the absence of conscription. An all-volunteer force
will attract men who are not now conscripted and who do not
now volunteer but who will do so when military service imposes
less of a financial penalty than it currently does.
Contrary to much dramatic argument, the reality is that an
all-volunteer force will be manned largely by the same kind of
individuals as today’s armed forces. The men who serve will be
quite similar in patriotism, political attitudes, effectiveness, and
susceptibility to civilian control. The draft does not guarantee
the quality of our armed foraes, and neither will voluntarism.
There are no simple solutions or shortcuts in dealing with the
complex problems that must always concern us as a free people.
Arguments against an all-volunteer force fall into fairly
distinct, though sometimes overlapping categories, one of which
is feasibility. Summarized below are some of the main
objections under this heading.
Objection 1: An all-volunteer force will be very
costly - so costly the Nation cannot afford it.
Answer: The question of how much the armed forces
cost is confused with the question of who bears those
costs. It is true that the budget for a voluntary force
will generally be higher than for an equally effective
force of conscripts and volunteers; but the cost of the
voluntary force will be less than the cost of the mixed
force. This apparent paradox arises because some of
the costs of a mixed force are hidden and never
appear in the budget.
12
Under the present system. first-term servicemen
must bear a disproportionately large share of the
defense burden. Draftees and draft-induced
volunteers are paid less than they would require to
volunteer. The loss they suffer is a tax-in-kind which
for budget purposes is never recorded as a receipt or
an expenditure. We estimate that for draftees and
draft-induced volunteers the total tax amounts to $2
billion per year: an average of $3.600 per man. If
Government accounts rrtlected as income this
financial penalty imposed on first-term servicemen. it
would become clear that a voluntary force costs less
than a mixed force. One example of real cost savings
that will accrue is the reduction in training costs as a
result of the lower personnel turnover of a voluntary
fODX.
Conscription also imposes social and human
costs by distorting the personal life and career plans
of the young and by forcing society to deal with such
difficult problems as conscientious objection (chapter
3).
Objection 2: The all-volunteer force will lack the
flexibility to expand rapidly in times of sudden crises.
Answer: Military preparedness depends on forces in
being, not on the ability to draft untrained men.
Reserve forces provide immediate support to active
forces, while the draft provides only inexperienced
civilians who must be organized, trained. and
equipped before they can become effective soldiers
and sailors - a process which takes many months.
The Commission has recommended a standby draft
which can be put into effect promptly if
circumstances require mobilization of large numbers
of men. History shows that Congress has quickly
granted the authority to draft when needed (chapter
IO).
Others contend that an all-volunteer force will have
undesirable political and social effects. Some of these objections
are given below.
13
Objection 3: An all-volunteer force will undermine
patriotism by weakening the traditional belief that
each citizen has a moral responsibility to serve his
country.
Answer: Compelling service through a draft
undermines respect for government by forcing an
individual to serve when and in the manner the
government decides, regardless of his own values and
talents. Clearly, not all persons are equally suited for
military service - some are simply not qualified.
When not all our citizens can serve, and only a small
minority are needed, a voluntary decision to serve is
the best answer, morally and practically, to the
question of who should serve (chapters 3 and 12).
Objection 4: The presence of draftees in a mixed
force guards against the growth of a separate military
ethos, which could pose a threat to civilian authority,
our freedom, and our democratic institutions.
Answer: Historically, voluntary service and freedom
have gone hand in hand. In the United States and
England, where voluntarism has been used most
consistently, there is also the strongest tradition of
civilian control of the military. There are
responsibilities to be met in maintaining civilian
control, but they must be exercised from above
rather than at the lowest level of the enlisted ranks.
They reside in the Halls of Congress, and in the White
House as well as in the military hierarchy.
In either a mixed or volunteer force, the
attitudes of the officer corps are the preponderant
factor in the psychology of the military; and with or
without the draft, professional officers are recruited
voluntarily from a variety of regional and
socioeconomic backgrounds. It is hard to believe that
substituting a true volunteer for a draftee or a
draft-induced volunteer in one of every six positions
will so alter the military as to threaten the tradition
of civilian control, which is embodied in the
Constitution and deeply felt by the public. It is even
less credible when one considers that this substitution
14
will occur at the lowest level of the military ladder,
among first-term enlisted men and officers, and that
turnover of these first-term personnel in an
all-volunteer force will be approximately
three-fourths of that in a comparable mixed ~force.
The truth is, we already have a large professional
armed force amounting to over 2 million men. The
existing loyalties and political influence of that force
cannot be materially changed by eliminating
conscription in the lowest ranks (chapter 12).
Objection 5: The higher pay required for a voluntary
force will be especially appealing to blacks who have
relatively poorer civilian opportunities.
This,
combined with higher reenlistment rates for blacks,
will mean that a disproportionate number of blacks
will be in military service. White enlistments and
reenlistments might decline, thus leading to an
all-black enlisted force. Racial tensions would grow
because of white apprehension at this development
and black resentment at bearing an undue share of
the burden of defense. At the same time, some of the
most qualified young blacks would be in the
military - not in the community where their talents
are needed.
Answer: The frequently heard claim that a volunteer
force will be all black or all this or all that, simply has
no basis in fact. Our research indicates that the
composition of the armed forces will not be
fundamentally changed by ending conscription.
Negroes presently make up 10.6 percent of the armed
forces, slightly less than the proportion of blacks in
the Nation. Our best projections for the future are
that blacks will be about 14 percent of the enlisted
men in a conscripted force totalling 2.5 million
officers and men, and 15 percent in an all-volunteer
force of equal capability. For the Army, we estimate
that the proportion of blacks will be 17 percent for
the mixed force and 18 percent for the voluntary
force as compared to 12.8 percent in the Army
today. To be sure, these are estimates, but even
15
extreme assumptions would not change the figures
drastically.
If higher pay does make opportunities in an
all-volunteer force more attractive to some particular
group than those in civilian life, then the appropriate
course is to correct the discriminations in civilian
life - not introduce additional discriminations against
such a group.
The argument that blacks would bear an unfair
share bf the burden of an all-volunteer force
confounds service by free choice with compulsory
service. With conscription, some blacks are compelled
to serve at earnings below what they would earn in
the civilian economy. Blacks who join a voluntary
force presumably have decided for themselves that
military service is preferable to the other alternatives
available to them. They regard military service as a
more rewarding opportunity, not as a burden. Denial
of this opportunity would reflect either bias or a
paternalistic belief that blacks are not capable of
making the “right” decisions concerning their lives
(chapter 12).
Objection 6: Those joining an all-volunteer force will
be men from the lowest economic classes, motivated
primarily by monetary rewards rather than
patriotism. An all-volunteer force will be manned, in
effect, by mercenaries.
Answer: Again,
our research indicates that an
all-volunteer force will not differ significantly from
the current force of conscripts and volunteers.
Maintenance of current mental, physical, and moral
standards for enlistment will ensure that a better
paid, volunteer force will not recruit an undue
proportion of youths from disadvantaged
socioeconomic backgrounds. A disproportionate
fraction of the 30 percent presently unable to meet
these standards come from such backgrounds, and
these men would also be ineligible for service in an
all-volunteer force. Increasing military pay in the first
term of service will increase the attractiveness of
military service more to those who have higher
16
civilian earnings potential than to those who have
lower civilian potential. Military pay is already
relatively attractive to those who h3w very poor
civilian alternatives. If eligible. such individunls are
now free to enlist and. moreover, are free to remain
beyond their first term of service when military pay is
even more attractive.
Finally. how will
“mercenxirs”
suddenly
emerge in the armed forces as a result of better pay
a II d other conditions of service? The term
“mercenary” applies to men who enlist for pay alone.
usually in the service of a foreign power. and
precludes all other motives for serving. Those who
volunteer to serve in the urmed forces do so for a
vnricty of reasons. inclnding a sense of duty.
Eliminating
the financial prnalty first-term
servicemen presently suffer. and improving other
conditions of service, will not suddenly change the
motives and basic attitudes of new recruits. Also. can
we regard as mercenxies the career commissioned
and noncommissioned officers now serving beyond
their first term? (chapter I?).
Objection 7: An all-volunteer force would stimulatr
foreign military adventures, foster an irresponsible
foreign policy, and lessen civilian concern about the
use of military forces.
Answer: Decisions by a government to use force or to
threaten the use of force during crises are extremely
difficult. The high cost of military resources, the
moral burden of risking human lives. political costs at
home and overseas. and the overshadowing risk of
nucle;~ confrontation ~ these and other factors enter
into such decisions. It is absurd to argue that issues of
such importance would be ignored and the decision
for war made on the basis of whether our forces were
entirely voluntary or mixed.
To the extent that there is pressure to seek
military solutions to foreign policy problems, such
pressure already exists and will not be affected by
ending conscription. The volunteer force will have the
17
same professional leadership as the present mixed
force. Changes in the lower ranks will not alter the
character of this leadership or the degree of civilian
control.
A decision to use the all-volunteer force will be
made according to the same criteria as the decision to
use a mixed force of conscripts and volunteers
because the size and readiness of the two forces will
be quite similar. These military factors are key
determinants in any decision to commit forces.
Beyond initial commitment, the policy choice
between expanding our forces by conscription or by
voluntary enlistment is the same for both the
all-volunteer force and a mixed force of conscripts
and volunteers. The important difference between the
two forces lies in the necessity for political debate
before
returning to conscription. With the
all-volunteer force, the President can seek
authorization to activate the standby draft, but
Congress must give its consent. With the mixed
system, draft calls can be increased by the President.
The difference between the two alternatives is crucial.
The former will generate public discussion of the use
of the draft to fight a war; the latter can be done
without such public discussion. If the need for
conscription is not clear, such discussion will clarify
the issue, and the draft will be used only if public
support is widespread (chapter 12).
Other critics of an all-volunteer force argue that it will
gradually erode the military’s effectiveness. Some of their main
concerns are taken up below.
Objection 8: A voluntary force will be less effective
because not enougli highly qualified youths will be
likely to enlist and pursue military careers. As the
quality of servicemen declines, the prestige and
dignity of the services will also decline and further
intensify recruiting problems.
Answer: The Commission has been impressed by the
number and quality of the individuals who, despite
conscription, now choose a career in the military. The
18
fact that we must resort in part to coercion to man
the armed services must be a serious deterrent to
potential volunteers. A force made up of men freely
choosing to serve should enhance the dignity and
prcstigc of the military. Every man in uniform will be
serving as a matter of choice rather than coercion.
The Commission recognizes the importance of
recruiting and retaining qualified individuals. hit has
recommended improved basic compensation and
conditions of service, proficiency pay and accelerated
promotions for the highly skilled to make military
career opportunities more attrxtive. These
improvements, combined with an intensive recruiting
effort, should enable the military not only to
maintain a high quality force but also to have one
that is more experienced, better motivated, and has
higher morale (chapters 4, 5, 7, and 12).
Objection 9: The defense budget will not be increased
to provide for an all-volunteer force, and the
Department of Defense will have to cut back
expenditures in other areas. Even if additional funds
are provided initially, competing demands will, over
the long term, force the Department of Defense to
absorb the added budgetary expense of an
all-volunteer force. The result could be a potentially
serious deterioration of the nation’s overall military
posture.
Answer: Ultimately, the size of the military budget
and the strength of our armed forces depend upon
public attitudes toward national defense. Since World
War II, our peacetime armed forces have been
consistently supported at high levels. The public has
supported large forces because it has felt them
essential to national security. The change from a
mixed force of volunteers and conscripts to an
all-volunteer force cannot significantly change that
feeling.
The contention that an all-volunteer force is
undesirable because it would result in smaller defense
forces raises a serious issue regarding the conduct of
government in a democracy. Conscription obscures a
19
liiLO,l 0 7” s
part of the cost of providing manpower for defense.
When
that
cost is made explicit, taxpayers may
decide they prefer a smaller defense force. If so, the
issue has been resolved openly, in accord with the
Constitution,
and in the best tradition of the
democratic process. Those who then argue that too
little is being devoted to national defense are saying
that they are unwilling to trust the open democratic
process; that, if necessary, a hidden tax should be
imposed to support the forces they believe are
necessary (chapters 3 and 12).
20
PART II
CHAPTER 3
CONSCRIPTION IS A TAX
Any government has essentially two ways of accomplishing
an objective whether it be building an interstate highway system
or raising an army. It can expropriate the required tools and
compel construction men and others to work until the job is
finished or it can purchase the goods and manpower necessary
to complete the job. Under the first alternative, only the
persons who own the property seized or who render
compulsory services are required to bear the expense of building
the highway or &using project. They pay a tax to finance the
project, albeit a tax-in-kind. Under the second alternative, the
cost of the necessary goods and services is borne by the general
public through taxes raised to finance the project.
Conscription is like the first alternative .~~ a tax-in-kind. A
mixed force of volunteers and conscripts contains first-term
servicemen of three types ~ (I) draftees (2) draft-induced
volunteers and (3) true volunteers. Draftees and draft induced
volunteers in such a force are coerced into serving at levels of
compensation below what would he required to induce them to
23
volunteer. They are, in short, underpaid. This underpayment is
a form of taxation. Over 200 years ago, Benjamin Franklin, in
commenting on a judicial opinion concerning the legality of
impressment of American merchant seamen, recognized the
heart of the issue, and even estimated the hidden tax. He wrote:
“But if, as I suppose is often the case, the sailor who is pressed
and obliged to serve for the defence of this trade at the rate of
25s. a month, could have ~.lSs, in the merchant’s service,
you take from him 50s. a month; and if you have 100,000 in
your service, you rob that honest part of society and their
poor families of &250,000. per month, or three millions a year,
and at the same time oblige them to hazard their lives in
fighting for the defence of your trade; to the defence of which
all ought indeed to contribute, (and sailors among the rest) in
proportion to their profits by it; but this three millions is more
than their share, if they did not pay with their persons; and
when you force that, methinks you should excuse the other.
“But it may be said, to give the king’s seamen merchant’s
wages would cost the nation too much, and call for nm~e
taxes. The question then will amount to this; whether it be
just in a community, that the
richer
part should compel the
poorer to fight for them and their properties for such wages as
they think tit to allow, and punish them if they refuse? Our
author tells us it is legal. I have not law enough to dispute his
authority, but
I
cannot persuade myself it is
equitable.”
The levy of taxes-in-kind is not a modern innovation. Such
taxes have existed throughout history. The impressment to
which Benjamin Franklin objected is an example. Also, it was
common practice in the Middle Ages to require specific service
of citizens in farming, construction, defense and other activities.
Traditionally, however, in the United States, taxes-in-kind have
been rejected for three
reasons.
First, they deprive individuals
of their freedom to pursue their careers where and how they
choose -in essence their tight to liberty and the pursuit of
happiness. Second, they are often accompanied by serious
inequities; i. e., a few people are forced to bear the burden of
accomplishing a
task
for the general good of the government
and its citizens. Third, they tend to conceal taxes and
government expenditures so that both the general public and
public officials are misinformed as to the costs of government
services.
Under conscription, each inductee and reluctant volunteer
is compelled to render services to the government. He is
24
required to pay a tax - a tax paid (and collected) in kind rather
than cash - but the form of the payment does not alter the
substance of the relationship. The amount of the tax is the
difference between the pay that the inductee or reluctant
volunteer actually receives as a first-term serviceman and the
pay that would be required to induce him to enlist. Even true
volunteers who serve in a mixed force are paid less than they
would receive in a volunteer force. In that sense, they too are
taxed by conscription.
Prevailing government accounting practices do not
recognize taxes paid in kind. Therefore, the tax on first-term
servicemen never gets recorded in the budget either as revenue
or as expenditure. In an all-volunteer force, the additional
military compensation will be paid in cash or other benefits,
and the taxes to make those payments will be collected in cash.
Recorded budget expenditures will have to be increased to
reflect these payments. This is the source of the budget
“increase” we have estimated for an all-volunteer force. If
current government accounting practices fully reflected
revenues and expenditures, whether in money or in kind, there
would be not a budget increase, but a budget decrease.
The real significance of the larger recorded budget for an
all-volunteer force is the adjustment of the burden of defense
costs. What appears on the surface to be an increase in
expenditures is actually a shift in the tax burden from first-term
servicemen to taxpayers at large. If government accounts
reflected taxes-in-kind, tax revenues from first-term servicemen
would go down with the inauguration of an all-volunteer armed
force, and (assuming a balanced budget) tax revenues from the
genera1 public would go up.
This shift in tax burden lies at the heart of resistance on
“cost” grounds to an all-volunteer armed force. Indeed, this
shift in tax burden explains how conscription gets enacted in
the first place. In a political democracy conscription offers the
general public an opportunity to impose a disproportionate
share of defense costs on a minority of the population.
We have made estimates of the amount of the tax-in-kind
imposed on draftees and draft-induced enlistees for the period
immediately prior to Vietnam, adjusted to reflect changes in
civilian and military compensation through 1969. The tax can
be separated into two components: first, the financial loss
suffered by draftees and draft-induced enlistees because their
25
total military compensation (including veterans benefits) falls
short of the income they would have earned in civilian life; and
second, the additional burden measured by the excess of
military over civilian compensation that would be required to
induce these same individuals to become true volunteers. We
estimate that the financial loss due to the first of these, the
difference between military compensation and potential civilian
earnings, was $1.5 billion for draftees or draft-induced
volunteers in the pre-Vietnam force. To induce these same
individuals to become true volunteers we estimate would have
required an additional $500 million. Thus the total implicit tax
on draftees and draft-induced volunteers was $2.0 billion.
This implies an average tax rate of 48 percent of the
income that draftees and draft-induced enlistees would have
earned in civilian life. Taking into account the personal income
tax they paid, their total tax rate was 5 I percent. In 1967, the
average personal income tax paid by all persons whose gross
earnings were equal to the amount that would have been earned
by draftees and draft-induced enlistees as civilians, was less than
IO percent of that gross income. Since draftees and
draft-induced enlistees have fewer than the average number of
dependents, it is estimated that they would have paid perhaps as
much as 15 percent of their gross income in personal income
tax. Hence, draftees and draft-induced enlistees are bearing a
tax burden over three times that of comparable civilians.
This concept of the tax does not include the income loss
suffered by true volunteers whose military compensation is held
below the level which would be required to maintain an
all-volunteer force, nor does it include the amount by which
all-volunteer pay rates would exceed the pay levels at which
some of the current draftees and draft-induced enlistees would
enter on a voluntary basis. The sum of these two amounts has
been estimated at $ I .25 billion annually, again for the period
immediately prior to Vietnam.
As is pointed out in detail later in this chapter, the concept
of the implicit tax considered above does not fully encompass
the costs of conscription. Prospective inductees also incur costs
in their efforts to escape conscription ~ costs which manifest
themselves in a variety of ways such as additional college
attendance, movement
into occupations which
carry
deferments, immigration, etc. Indirect evidence suggests that
26
these costs may be 1.5 times the implicit tax, or about $3.0
billion. They can be viewed as the cost of collecting the implicit
tax. Thus for each $1 .OO of tax-in-kind collected, an average of
$2.50 is foregone by the public. Quite apart from
considerations of equity and freedom, this feature of
conscription is enough to call it into question.
The fact that conscription imposes a tax is not in itself
immoral and undesirable. Taxes are required to enable
iovernment to exist. What is of questionable morality is the
discriminatory form that this implicit tax takes; and even more,
the abridgement of individual freedom that is involved in
collecting it.
The tax is discriminatory because the first-term servicemen
who pay it constitute a small proportion of the total
population. During the next decade the number of males
reaching age 19 each year will average 2.2 million. To maintain
a stable mixed force of 2.5 million men at present relative
military/civilian pay levels, draft calls will average about
100,000 per year. We estimate that draft-induced enlistments
might be 75,000 per year. Therefore the draftees and draft-
induced enlistees paying the tax-in-kind will represent only 8
percent of the male population reaching age 19 each year.
The extent of the discrimination resulting from
conscription depends on the proportion of the population
forced to serve, and on the level of compensation provided to
those who serve. When a large fraction of the population is
conscripted as it was, for example, in World War II, the tax is
levied on a larger fraction of the population. Even then,
however, the discrimination is by no means eliminated. Not
everyone eligible to serve does so. Moreover, such wars do not
occur every generation, hence some generations never pay
though they benefit from the defense provided by others. Even
in World War II, the 16.4 million men who served in the armed
forces represented only 12 percent of the total population, 17
percent of the adult population and 56 percent of the adult
male population between I8 and 45.
Defenders of conscription often argue that every young
person has the duty to serve his country. The above discussion
makes it clear that the real question is not whether young
people have such a duty, but whether that duty does not extend
to the entire populace. Is it right and proper that a large tax be
confined to a small fraction of our young able-bodied males in
27
order to relieve taxpayers in general from having to pay higher
taxes?
In addition to being discriminatory, conscription as a tax is
also generally regressive, falling on individuals whose income is
low. The amount of benefits in the form of defense that
individuals receive as a consequence of the tax is not related to
the amount of tax they pay. Finally, and most importantly, the
tax requires payment in kind, rather than money, and the
payment in kind takes the form of involuntary service.
It is unlikely that any Congressman would ever propose
enactment of a general tax of the kind now imposed by the
draft. If one ever were proposed, it would have little chance of
being approved by Congress. If approved by Congress, it is hard
to imagine that it would be held constitutional by the courts.
This is a hidden tax which persists only because it is obscure.
No tax is perfect, of course, but it is hard to imagine a means of
imposing the cost of defense, or any other Government activity
for that matter, more in conflict with accepted standards of
justice, equality and freedom in the United States.
THE COST OF AN ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCE
The larger budget required to sustain an all-volunteer
armed force is frequently referred to as the “cost” of such a
force. We have deliberately refrained from using that language.
We have done so in order to stress the difference between “costs”
on the one hand and “budget expenditures” on the other.
Budget expenditures need not correctly reflect costs. Indeed, as
we have indicated above, government accounting practices do
not recognize the expenditure in kind implicit in conscription.
To that extent the cost of a mixed voluntary/conscript force is
consistently understated in the budget. But the cost of such a
force is also understated in other ways.
When the hidden costs of conscription are fully
recognized, the cost of an all-volunteer armed force is
unquestionably less than the cost of a force of equal size and
quality manned wholly or partly through conscription. The
all-volunteer costs are lower for four reasons.
I. Conscription leads to low reenlistment
rates among
first-term servicemen, thereby increasing turnover rates. Most
inductees and draft-induced volunteers are not seriously
28
interested in careers in the military. First-term reenlistment
rates for inductees pre-Vietnam were about one-fourth as high
as for enlistees. In an all-volunteer force, first-term reenlistment
rates will be higher than those currently experienced because
those who enlist will be more likely to choose the military as a
career. Moreover, the term of service for inductees is only two
years while regular army enlistments are three years and Air
Force and Navy enlistments are four years. With an all-volunteer
force these longer terms of enlistment will also reduce turnover
and the need for accessions.
Both factors will generate real cost savings. For a mixed
voluntary/conscript force of 2.5 million men we estimate that
annual first-term accessions in FY 1977 to 1979 would have to
be 452,000.For an all-volunteer force with equal effectiveness,
accessions would be only 342,000, or 110,000 less. Lower
accessions will mean a smaller training establishment; that is,
fewer trainers, trainees and support personnel and less training
equipment and facilities. We estimate this will reduce the cost
of a stable 2.5 million man peacetime force by $675 million per
year.
In addition to the savings in training costs, there will also
be savings in the number of personnel who are in a non-effective
status because of transfers generated by high personnel
turnover. An all-volunteer force will have fewer separations,
hence fewer changes of status to accommodate separations. This
also will result in cost savings. The number of servicemen in
ineffective status will decline as will transportation and
administrative costs. We estimate that these savings will be $68
million per year for a stable peacetime force of 2.5 million men.
In our study we have recognized these particular cost
reductions by appropriately reducing the required size of the
forces. Thus, a mixed voluntary/conscript force of 2.5 million
men is equated to an all-volunteer force of 2.44 million. The
latter represents the same effective force as the former taking
account of the savings in training and transients which we
estimate will accrue.
2. Conscription
induces the military services to use
manpower inefficiently. They make manpower decisions on the
basis of the costs as they perceive them, namely, those that are
reflected in their budget. Because budget expenses significantly
understate the cost of first-term servicemen, the services are led
29
to use more of them than they otherwise would. This is not
because they are profligate or inept. By minimizing the costs as
they see them of meeting specific security requirements, they
are behaving as the nation would want them to behave. The
problem arises because conscription greatly understates these
costs.
When military compensation is raised to a level consistent
with an all-volunteer armed force, the services will find it
desirable to economize on manpower. In particular, they will
discover ways to substitute non-human resources for manpower
in a wide variety of activities. They will find it desirable to
mechanize tasks now performed manually, and to emphasize,
even more than at present, durability, reliability and ease of
maintenance in the design of equipment and vehicles and in the
construction of facilities. It would be a prodigious research
effort to examine each activity for potential savings from such
substitutions. Moreover, as a practical matter, there will be a
long pericd of transition before the process of effecting such
substitutions is completed. For these reasons we have not
attempted to estimate the total savings that could result from
labor-saving substitutions if the forces were all-volunteer.
We have, however, examined one area of potential
substitutions; namely, that of using civilians instead of military
personnel in particular positions. Conscription leads to the
assignment of servicemen to some billets which could be filled
by civilians at lower costs. If a civilian is hired, the Defense
Department must pay the full cost thereof, but if a first-term
serviceman is used the price is only his military compensation.
An extensive study was conducted of specific billets where
potential savings from such substitutions exist. These savings
accrue because military training costs are reduced or because a
civilian can be hired at a salary below the real cost of a
serviceman performing the same task, that is, below the salary
required to fill the position with a volunteer. We estimate that
for a force of 2.5 million men, 117,000 civilians could be
substituted for servicemen at a savings of perhaps $100 million
per year.
3. Conscription, whether by lottery or by Selective Service, is
relatively insensitive to the alternative value of the draftee in
the civilian economy and to his tastes for military employment.
Thus, suppose a draftee or draft-induced volunteer is compelled
30
to enter the service who would do so voluntarily only if he were
offered $8,000 per year. If there exists a true volunteer who
would be equally productive in the military, prepared to enlist
for $6,000 per year, the difference of $2,000 is an additional
real cost imposed by the draft. The $2,000 can reflect either a
difference in the productivity of the two persons in the civilian
economy, or differences in taste for military life. Whichever it
is, the loss is a real cost (and a waste) in precisely the same sense
as is any other cost.
4. Finally, there are many subtle costs imposed by
conscription that are no less real for their subtlety. Their effects
ramify throughout society, impinging on a variety of individual
and institutional decisions.
The costs imposed on potential draftees are perhaps the
most obvious. The draft erodes ideals of patriotism and service
by alienating many of the young who bear the burden.
American youths are raised in an atmosphere where freedom
and justice are held dear. It is difficult for them to cope with a
situation which falls far short of these ideals just as they enter
adulthood. The draft undermines identification with society
just at the age when young men begin to assume social
responsibilities. It thwarts the natural desire of youths to
commit themselves to society.
Many of the implicit costs of the draft arise out of the
system of deferments and exemptions currently in effect, and
out of the qualification requirements for military service.
Young men distort their career and personal plans to take
advantage of opportunities to postpone or avoid being drafted.
They enter college when they otherwise would not. They stay
in school longer than they otherwise would. They accept
employment in positions they otherwise would not take. They
marry and have families before they otherwise would. There is
no doubt that the costs of these distorted choices are real and
often cruelly high. Popular support for making 19 the year of
primary draft eligibility stems largely from the desire to reduce
uncertainty and improve opportunity for personal planning.
“Channeling” young men into colleges, occupations, marriage
or fatherhood is not in their best interests nor those of society
as a whole.
The procedures of the selective service system also impose
hidden costs. In many ways the young registrant is denied due
31
process of law. He is confronted with an intricate legal maze
and denied the right of counsel and judicial review during its
normal operation. To get his case before the courts, the
potential draftee must risk jail sentences of up to five years. The
operation of the draft abridges constitutional rights in many
other ways. For example, a registrant must get permission to
travel outside the country. In addition to the loss of rights,
there is the problem of determining who is entitled to
exemption as a conscientious objector. These, decisions are
inherently difficult to make, and are harmful both to the group
deciding and the persons requesting conscientious objector
status. The process weakens the political fabric of our society
and threatens the delicate web of shared vaIues that alone
enables a free society to exist. These problems are completely
avoided by an all-volunteer force.
Each problem faced by the individual registrant has a
counterpart in the institutions with which he must deal. In
addition to draft-induced volunteers for the military, selective
service results in draft-induced college students, draft-induced
ministerial students, draft-induced husbands and fathers, and
draft-induced employees in exempt occupations.
The draft creates unnecessary problems for the military.
Selection by lottery compels some to serve who have neither a
talent nor a taste for military life, resulting in misfits and
maladjustments to military service. Draftees who cannot adjust
must nevertheless serve out a two-year tour. These men present
morale and disciplinary problems which otherwise would not
arise. Some spend much of their military service in
confinement, because it is so difficult for them to adjust to
military service. Dissent within the military presents particularly
ticklish problems for the armed forces of a free nation. The
problems raised by the forced military service of those who are
unwilling or unable to adjust to military life will be largely
overcome by voluntary recruiting.
Because of the influence of the draft, our schools and
colleges must choose among more applicants than would
normally apply. Inevitably they admit some young men more
interested in exemptions than education. The presence of these
individuals adds to the forces of disruption on the campus,
imposing costs on all members of a university community.
Employers, too, must sort out true volunteers from
draft-induced applicants for jobs which provide exemptions.
32
For example, when school teachers are deferred, some young
men will become teachers for a short time, even though they
would rather follow another profession. They will stay in
teaching only as long as they require an occupational
deferment. This results in higher turnover and less experienced
and less dedicated teachers for the young of the country.
It is difficult to add up these costs and measure their
overall impact on society. Yet it is easy to cite examples of
serious problems created by the draft, which voluntary
recruiting would eliminate.
33
CHAPTER 4
MILITARY
PERSONNEL REQUIREMENTS
In planning
for an all-volunteer armed force, the size and
quality of future military forces are critical variables. Small
forces or those of low quality, could be raised on a voluntary
basis, even if military compensation were reduced. Very large
forces or those of high quality would require substantial
increases in military pay.
The size of active duty forces since World War II, shown in
table 4-1, has fluctuated widely. After reaching a peak of 3.6
million men during the Korean War, the armed forces slowly
declined in size toward an apparent equilibrium level of 2.5 to
2.6 million men. Although the Vietnam War reversed this trend,
the President’s budget message of April 1969 suggested that,in a
post-Vietnam environment, active duty force levels be stabilized
at a level of 2.0 to 2.5 million men.
Because of the uncertainties surrounding force plans for a
post-Vietnam environment, the Commission decided to analyze
the manpower and budgetary implications of four alternative
active duty force levels, 2.0, 2.25, 2.5, and 3.0 million men.
These four force levels cover a reasonable range of alternative
peacetime active duty forces that might be needed to insure
national security.
TABLE 4-I.-Active duty force strength
[selected fiscal years 1950-69 and projections]
Fiscal war
Total
DOD Active duty as
lmillions)
oercent
of 18-45 male Domhtion
The armed services’ demand for the nation’s manpower
resources is indicated by the size of the active duty forces as a
percentage of the male population 18-45 years of age,shown in
the last column of table 4-1. The comparatively small force of
2.5 million men in FY 1960 represented 7.9 percent of this
male population. In light of the projected growth of the male
population, all four alternative force levels constitute smaller
percentages of the projected 18-to-45-year-old male population
in 1975.
Over the past two decades, the structure of the armed
forces has changed substantially (see table 4-H). The service
structure is important because the Army is the only service that
has consistently required draftees to meet its strength
objectives. (The Navy and Marine Corps have occasionally
issued draft calls to meet temporary shortfalls, but the Air
Force has never used the draft.) Prior to Korea, the Army made
up 41 percent of all active duty forces. The post-Korean
reduction in forces of the late 1950’s was accompanied by a
shift which gave larger shares of the defense responsibility to
36
the Navy and Air Force. Since the escalation of American
involvement in Vietnam, the ground combat forces of the Army
and Marine Corps have become a larger fraction of the force, as
shown in table 4-H. The service distribution of the four future
forces shown in table 4-H reflects a slight reversal of the trend
of the late 1950’s. The Army, for example, represents 40
percent of the 2.5-million-man force compared with only 35
percent for the 1960 active duty force. The relative size of the
Army in force plans is important because the projected
shortfalls in recruitment are largest for the Army.
TABLE 4-Il.--Distribution
of active defy force
strength
by service
[selected fiscal years 195049 and projections]
Distribution (percent)
Navy
Marine Corps Air Force
26 5
26
22 7 28
22 7 33
25 7 33
25 7 31
22 9
25
24 6
25
24 6
27
25 9 29
26 6
29
Substantial numbers of civilians and reservists supplement
the active duty forces in the overall defense manpower picture,
as shown in table 4-111. The ratio of civilians to active duty
personnel [column (5) of table 4-1111 has declined over the past
15 years. Many positions in the force structure currently
manned by uniformed servicemen could be staffed with civilians
at lower budgetary costs and with no loss in immediate
effectiveness. In addition, the substitution of civilians for
servicemen reduces the demands for new recruits. Civilians
typically need less training, involve fewer transfers of personnel,
and require lower levels of compensation, especially in an
all-volunteer force. Civilians, however, are only imperfect
37
substitutes for uniformed personnel, because they cannot be
involuntarily mobilized and moved in the event of an
emergency. The scope of civilian substitutions is, therefore,
limited by the military’s need to provide positions for rotational
assignments and career development.
TABLE 46Ill.-Active duty, civilian, and paid drill reserve strength
[in thousands] FY 7947-1969
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
(6)
Ratios:
Fiscal
Total Total
Paid drill Ratios: paid drill/
year DOD’ civilian reserve civ/DOD DOD
1947.~ .~~~~~~~~~~ 1,563 1,060 231 .67 .15
1952~ ~~~~~~~~ 3,636 1,650 506 .45 .14
1957.~ ~.~~~~~~~
2,796
1,429 1,047
.51 .37
1962~~~~~~~~~~~~ 2,606 1,241 669
.44 .32
1965~~~~~ 2,655
1,164
933
.44 .35
1969~~~~~~~~~ 3,460 1,456 960
.42 .26
. Active duty military Delson"el only.
A position-by-position analysis of the opportunities for
civilian substitution was not possible within the scope of this
study because of limitations of time and resources. However, a
careful aggregative study of individual occupational specialties
was conducted, ranking the various occupations by the degree
to which they were purely military. This study concludes that
approximately 95,000 positions in a force of 2 million men
could be staffed by civilians with no loss in effectiveness. Larger
civilian substitutions could be achieved at larger force levels.
The budgetary savings (in constant 1969 prices) which would
result from carrying out the proposed civilian substitution
programs range from $90 million for the 2.million-man force to
$125 million for the 3-million-man force. If these programs are
implemented, the proportion of total defense manpower which
is civilian will increase from 31 percent to about 34 percent,
thereby reversing the trend of the past I5 years.
The reductions in the size of each of the active duty
uniformed forces that would result from civilian substitution
are shown in table 4-IV. The impact of civilian substitution on
required accessions is slow to take effect, and its fullimpact is
not felt until 1978. Rotation policies and the size of overseas
deployment have an important effect on the potential for
38
civilian substitutions. The potential is greatest in the Air Force,
where the majority of the force is stationed in the continental
United States. In the Army and Marine Corps the opportunities
are limited by relatively large overseas deployments and
rotation policies.
TABLE 4-W.-Substitution potential a// services
[in thousands]
Size force Army NWY USMC USAF DOD
2.0 million
Officer
Enlisted .~~..
Total
2.25 million
Officer
Enlisted......
Total
2.5 million
Officer
Enlisted......
Total
3.0 million
Officer..~..-~~~
5.2 5.1 0.6 9.4 20.3
0.0 6.6 6.6
59.7 75.3
5.2 13.9 7.4 69.1 95.6
5.9
5.6 0.7 10.3 22.5
0.0
9.6 7.9 66.0 63.7
5.9
15.4 6.6 76.3 106.2
6.6 6.2
0.6
11.3 24.9
0.0 10.6 6.9 72.2 91.9
iii 17.0
9.7 63.5 116.6
6.9
7.0
0.9
12.4 29.2
Enlisted~.-... 0.0 12.1 10.2 79.1 101.4
=
- -
T0ka-m.~~ 19.1 11.1 91.5 130.6
When the forces have reached their post-Vietnam
equilibrium levels, a program of civilian substitutions should be
ildtiated and carried out over a three-to-four-year period. Too
rapid replacement of uniformed personnel by civilians might
seriously impair the attractiveness of military careers. It is also
recommended that civilian manpower ceilings be relaxed to
enable the Department of Defense to follow more rational
manpower management policies. Prior attempts to accomplish
civilian substitution (in fiscal years 1952, 1955, 1962, and
1965), were curtailed, abandoned, or even reversed because of
civilian manpower and budget ceilings. The Department of
Defense should have the flexibility to vary the ratio of civilians
to military personnel within a total budget constraint. To
establish an economic balance between civilian and military
39
personnel. the Department of Defense should undertake a
position-by-position analysis, review the criteria to determine
whether a particular position should be militxy or civilian. and
develop better data to estimate the real economic costs of
military and civilian personnel.
Trained reservists provided much of the manpower for the
rapid expansions of active duty forces during the Korean War
and the Berlin crisis of 1961-67. However, reserves have not
been activated in significant numbers for the Vietnam War.
Reference to table 4-111 reveals that the size of the paid reserve
forces has remained stable over the past decade. Details
regarding the size and composition of the reserves in an
all-volunteer force are more fully discuwd in Chapter 9.
EFFECTIVE FORCE STRENGTHS
The six of the active duty forces does not directly reflect
defense capability. The servicemrn who have already completed
basic military and technical training are the ones who provide
defense capability. Recruits. instructors, and support personnel
at training bases only indirectly contribute to defense by
supplying future trained personnel. In addition to these
non-effective training billets. other positions in the active force
structure must be set aside for personnel in transit between
duty assignments or interned as patients and prisoners. With
lower personnel turnover, each recruit spends a smaller fraction
of his service career in training or in other forms of
non-effective status. Because it will have fewer non-effective
men. an all-volunteer force can be smaller than a mixed force of
conscripts and volunteers but still provide the same effective
strength.
Personnel ttwnovrr in an all-volunteer force will be reduced
for sevrral reasons. If the draft is continued. it is projected that
about 42 percent of accessions into the Army (for a force of 3.5
million men) will be drafters who serve for only two years,
compared with three and four-year tours for voluntary
enlistments. Moreover. the re-enlistment rates of draftees and
draft-motivated volunteers are considerably lower than those of
men who voluntarily choose military service. Finally. the pay
increase needed to move to an all-volunteer force includes
somewhat higher pay for second-term enlisted men. which will
further increase the reenlistment rate.
40
When these factors are taken into account, we estimate
that the turnover of enlisted
personnel in an all-volunteer Army
will be only I7 percent per year, compared with 26 percent for
a mixed conscript/volunteer Army of the same size. With this
reduction in turnover, the enlisted strength of an all-volunteer
force could be 5 percent less than that of a mixed force, while
retaining the same number of effective men in non-training and
non-transient positions. Put another way, I3 percent of a mixed
force is assigned to non-effective positions at training bases or
in transit, while only 9 percent of the all-volunteer force will be
so occupied. These manpower savings are greatest for the Army,
which is projected to realize the sharpest reduction in personnel
turnover rates as a result of moving to a voluntary system.
In developing estimates of overall accession requirements
for uniformed personnel, the sizes of all-volunteer forces were
reduced to provide the same effective strengths as the four
mixed forces in table 4-11. The manpower savings that derive
from lower personnel turnover are evident from the data in
table 4-V, which shows enlisted strengths for forces of equal
effectiveness.
TABLE 4-V.-Equal eifectiveness all-volunteer and draft forces
[in thousands]
DOD DOD Army
Army
Total enlisted enlisted enlisted enlisted
strength strength strength
strength
strength
(in millions) (draft) (all-volunteer) (draft) (all-volunteer)
2.0 .~~~.~~~~.~~~~~~ 1,713 1,663 642 624
2.25~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 1.930 1,666 721 692
2.5 ~~~~~~~~~~~~.... 2,146 2,069 666 627
3.0 ~~~~~~~~~~~~.~~. 2,597 2,559 1,120 1,047
The higher retention rate for true volunteers inevitably
produces a more experienced force. Our projections indicate
that, by 1980, 45 percent of Army enlisted men will have four
years or more of service experience, as compared with 31
percent for a mixed force of the same size. Since experience
involves on-the-job-training, a more experienced force is more
productive than a less experienced one. Military officers agree
41
that one career enlisted man is worth more than one first-term
serviceman, but few officers are willing to indicate the precise
trade-offs. Although the all-volunteer and mixed forces in table
4-V have the same numbers of effective men in non-training and
non-transient positions, the all-volunteer forces actually provide
greater effectiveness because they possess more experience.
The concept of effective force strength is equally
applicable to officers. Because officers typically receive their
training before they are commissioned, it is difficult to estimate
their non-effective training time. Moreover, training times and
costs vary widely, being highest for an Academy graduate who
goes on to night training, and lowest for a chaplain who receives
a direct appointment.
In estimating the budgetary savings resulting from lower
turnover among commissioned officers, we have disregarded
non-effective training times. We have instead based our
estimates on the arerage cost of $12,000 for training an officer
in either the college or non-college officer training schools that
have been used in the past to meet fluctuating demands for
officers.
REQUIRED ACCESSIONS UNDER ALTERNATlVE
MANPOWER PROCUREMENT SYSTEMS
The tlow of accessions (voluntary enlistments and
draftees) required to maintain a given force depends on the size
of the force and the losses from active duty ranks. These
requirements can be met either on a purely voluntary basis or
through a mixture of enlistments and inductions. With an
all-volunteer force, smaller flows are required for two reasons.
First, true volunteers serve longer, thereby reducing losses due
to separations upon completion of initial obligated tours.
Second, the same effective force strength can be maintained
with a smaller total active duty force.
The annual flows of accessions required to sustain the four
mixed force levels using a lottery draft are presented in the first
and third columns of table 4-VI. If the draft is abolished and all
recruits are true volunteers, the same effective force strength
can be maintained by the smaller annual flows of required
accessions shown in the last two columns of table 4-VI. An
all-volunteer force with the same effective strength as a
2.5.million-man mixed force requires 25 percent fewer
accessions per year than the mixed force. The reduction in
42
TABLE
4-W.--Required accessions lo enlisted ranks
[annual averages FY 1979-67 in thousands]
Continued draft
All-volunteer
DOD
Army
total strength draft
(in millions) DOD
CAIS
Armv DOD Armv
2.0 ~~~~~~~~ 312 19 136 259 104
2.25~~~~.~~. 362 46 170 290 116
2.5 440 96 235 332 146
3.0 ~~~~~~~~ 564 164 340 410 192
required accessions resulting from the move to an all-votunteer
force is considerably smaller for officers. The projections in
table 4-VI pertain to the period 1979-81 after the greater
retention rates for an all-volunteer force have taken effect. In
the transition to stable force levels, accession requirements for
the all-volunteer forces are slightly higher especially in the case
of the Army, where the average annual requirements for FY
1973-75 are 188 thousand, compared with 148 thousand for
FY 1979-81.
QUALITATIVE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE ACTIVE
DUTY FORCES
Members of the armed services today must possess more
skills than their predecessors in World War II and Korea. This
trend is indicated by the data in table 4-VII which shows the
occupational’mix of enlisted men in the Department of Defense
and the Army. In 1953, 18 percent of all enlisted men were
assigned to ground
combat occupations that require
comparatively little technical skill. The proportion of enlisted
men in these relatively unskilled occupations has declined over
time. Indeed, the projections of the force structure in a
post-Vietnam environment show that only 11 percent will be in
the ground combat forces. The declining importance of the
ground combat forces cannot be attributed to a relative
reduction in the size of the Army. In the Army occupational
structure, the percentage of enlisted men in the ground combat
occupations is projected to fall from 29 percent in FY 1963 to
2 1 percent in the forces of tomorrow. The services’ demand for
highly skilled men to staff electronics and other technical
occupations has climbed over time.
43
TABLE 4-VII.-Percentage distribution of enlistedmen
by major occupation
[selected fiscal years. 1945-741
Occupation
16 14 14 15
10
10 13 15 10 11
7 6 8 14
17
20 16 19 16 16
23 26 25 24 24
7 8 7 7 7
15 13 12
12 13
35 32
5 9
7 a
19 16
12 14
3 5
19 16
29 26 21
9 7 7
9 15 16
19 19 22
16
16 17
4 4
4
14 13 13
Two features of the changing occupational structure of the
armed services are important. An increased demand for skilled
personnel characterizes the civilian economy as well as the
services. Thus, the services must compete with the civilian
sector for those youths who in increasing numbers enter the
labor force with more education and greater technical
background than young men two decades ago. The other aspect
of this phenomenon is the growing similarity of the military’s
skill requirements to those of the civilian sector. Various
estimates suggest that 20 to 30 percent of active duty billets are
directly related to combat missions. The remaining positions are
required for logistical support, administration, maintenance and
training ~ all of which have counterparts in the civilian
economy.
QUALIFICATION STANDARDS FOR ENLISTED MEN
Admission to the enlisted ranks of the military services is
now limited to men who satisfy three kinds of criteria: mental,
44
physical, and moral. The physical and moral standards have
remained stable over the past two decades. Although mental
standards have exhibited some short-run variations. they have
generally risen over time. The mental ability of a recruit is
measured by his score on the Armed Forces Qualification Test
(AFQT). Recruits are divided into five mental groups. Men in
the lowest mental group. group V. are exempt by law from
military service. The mental group distribution of accessions in
the two war years, FY 1953 and FY 1969. are shown in table
4-VIII, along with a distribution for a recent peacetime year,
FY
1965.
TABLE 4-VIII.-Menial group distribution Of enlistments and
inductions: DOD
[in thousands]
Mental
group
FY 1953 FY 1965 FY 1969
Number Percent Number Percent Number Percent
The proportion of accessions in the top three mental
groups was 63 percent in 1953, at the peak of the Korean
expansion, and 76 percent in 1969, at the peak of the Vietnam
expansion. During the intervening years the proportion in
Categories I-111 was higher, reflecting the selectivity possible
with the draft during peacetime. Another indication of the
quality of enlisted personnel is the fraction of voluntary
enlistees who are high school graduates. The proportions for
1959 and 1969 are given in table 4-1X.
The services argue that they must have high-quality
recruits for the following reasons:
I. The machinery of modern warfare requires recruits
who have the mental capability to absorb complex
technical training.
2. Training costs can he reduced by limiting enlistments
to highly qualified individuals, even though men with
45
less mental ability could be taught the requisite skills
with enough training investment.
3. The disciplinary problems created by men in the
lowest mental group contribute to administrative
costs and detract from force effectiveness.
4. Given the normal attrition and losses due to
non-re-enlistment, the services must have a large
fraction of highly qualified recruits to provide the
raw material to staff the non-commissioned officer
ranks.
Are the services’ quality standards too high? Mental
standards were raised significantly between 1957 and 1965,
when enlistments of individuals in mental group IV (AFQT
scores of IO to 30) were limited. In late 1965, the Department
of Defense initiated the New Standards Program (Project
lOO,OOO), which directed the services to accept 100,000 mental
group IV enlistments each year. The services complied and also
redesigned many training programs to place less emphasis on
written and verbal skills and more on manual talents.
Experience gained from this program shows that men with
lower AFQT scores and less schoolivg can achieve acceptable
levels of performance. Moreover, the new-standards men have
not caused appreciably greater disciplinary problems.
In our study the number of Category IV enlistees has been
limited to a maximum of 20 percent in any service. The
recommendations for enlisted compensation are therefore
designed to provide that a minimum of 80 percent of the
accessions be from categories I through III. In addition, the
recommendation in chapter 5 to expand the use of proficiency
pay and to encourage accelerated promotions provides a
46
selective mechanism to help sustain the quality of military
personnel. When these are combined with more intensive
recruiting and improvements in military personnel management,
the services should be able to maintain the high quality of their
forces.
41
CHAPTER 5
COMPENSATION AND MANAGEMENT
OF MILITARY PERSONNEL
Pay is not the only, and perhaps not even the primary
motivating force for joining or remaining in the military
services. A sense of duty, a desire for adventure or travel,
society’s esteem for military service, a desire for training, the
quality of military life and the general conditions of military
service - all affect individuals’ decisions. Some of these
non-pecuniary factors are beyond the control of the services.
Others, however, can be controlled, and the Commission is
recommending a number of changes in military manpower
procurement and management practices to improve the
non-monetary conditions of military life and thereby help
increase the attractiveness of military careers. These steps will
contribute to the attainment of an all-volunteer force, but are
not sufficient in themselves. Military compensation in the early
years of service is now so low that it will not sustain an
all-volunteer force of the quality desired. Until that condition is
corrected, an all-volunteer force caimot be realized.
Our studies show that the increments in pay, and therefore
49
the incremental budgetary outlays, necessary to provide a
voluntary force in the 1970’s of about the same size as our
pre-Vietnam force are fairly small; that they are, in fact, only
about as great as those that are required to correct the
inequities that have developed in the structure of military
compensation during the 21 years that the draft has been in
effect.
The increase in military compensation that is required to
sustain an all-volunteer force of any given size depends upon
three factors: (a) the number of accessions that will be needed
each year, (b) the number of truly voluntary accessions that are
forthcoming at current levels of pay, and (c) the extent to
which increases in compensation increase the flow of
volunteers. The annual flow of accessions required to maintain
the projected all-volunteer forces was discussed in chapter 4.
The extent of voluntarism in the present force is summarized in
table S-1. The next to the last line of table 5-I shows that even
under the extremely low levels of entry pay that prevailed in
the pre-Vietnam period, the vast majority of those in the then
current active duty forces were true volunteers (2.1 of the 2.6
million or about 77 percent of the total force were true
volunteers). Indeed, the estimated number of true volunteers
even in the Vietnam period (2. I million) represents a significant
fraction of any of the four projected forces the Commission has
considered.
The number of volunteers in table 5-I suggests that the
forces under study can be attained on a voluntary basis.
However, the data also show that unless pay is increased, there
will be shortfalls in first-term enlistments, particularly in the
Army. For instance, in 1965, true volunteers constituted 76
percent of the total DOD enlisted forces. In the Army, however,
only 65 percent of enlisted men were true volunteers.
For a stable force of pre-Vietnam size, the remaining 35
percent of Army enlisted men (either draftees or draft-induced
volunteers) could have been replaced by true volunteers,
through increasing voluntary enlistments by about 5 1,000 men
per year. Similarly, the entire armed forces in I965 could have
been put on a voluntary basis by adding about 4,000 officer and
84,000 enlisted true volunteers per year. As discussed in chapter
4, smaller forces would actually require even fewer additional
true volunteers. With a continuously rising population 17 to 21
50
TABLE 6-l.-Number of volunteers on pre-Vietnam and Vietnam active duty
[thousands]
June 30,1965
1,974
1,022 53
968
1,006 418 90
328
2,981
1,440
144 1,297
766 291 22 269
1,772
710 112
598
81.1 59.5 49.3 78.2 46.1
years of age. the task of providing these additional volunteers is
not insurmountable.
The problem of attracting more officer volunteers is
discussed in detail in chapter 6. It is important to note here that
the shortfall of officer volunteers is small ~ especially in view of
the discrimination which has prevailed in the treatment of pay
for first term officers. Between 1948 and 1965, or between the
year the post World War II draft law was first passed and the
most recent peacetime year, the average basic pay of officers
with two or more years of military service increased 45 percent
while that for officers with less than two years of service
increased only about I3 percent.
The history of discrimination against first term enlisted
men is even more striking. During the I948 to 1965 period the
pay of enlisted personnel with two or more years of service
increased about 45 percent compared to 4 percent for those
with less than two years of service. During the period
1948-1969 the same comparisons show increases of 111 percent
and 60 percent respectively. In other words, the basic pay for
enlisted recruits increased little more than half as much as that
for those with two or more years of service.
Comparisons with civilian pay in table 5-11 also point to
the relatively low levels of entry pay. Columns 4 and 5 of table
5-11 show the ratios of regular enlisted and regular officer
compensation to the earnings of their respective civilian
counterparts. Although; in general, officers fare relatively better
than enlisted men, officer compensation in the first two years
of service is below that of comparable civilians. Similarly, based
on regular compensation, enlisted pay during the first two years
of service is less than 60 percent of comparable civilian pay.
Comparisons based on total military and civilian compensation
(column 5 of table S-11) also reveal that enlisted entry pay is
significantly below that which the average first-term serviceman
would have earned in the civilian economy.
THE EFFECT OF PAY ON RECRUITING AND
RETAINING VOLUNTEERS
The data presented in table 5-11 suggest the importance of
pay as an inducement to enter and remain in the military. For
example, the deficits for the officers are smaller than for
enlisted personnel. That result is to be expected given that
officer entry pay is relatively higher than enlisted entry pay.
52
TABLE 5-Il.-Enlisfed men’s and comparable civilian compensation profiles by length of service
[1970 pay rates] 1
Y%iE
of
service
Total military
Regular
compen-
military sation as a
compensation percent of
Regular Total Total as a percent of total civilian
military
military civilian
total civilian compen-
compensation :! compensation z comwnsation 1
compensation sation
$ 2,776 $ 3,251
$ 5,202 53.4 62.5
3,357 3,935 5,803 57.8 67.8
4,496 5,275 6,370 70.6 82.8
4,909 6,249 6,908 72.2 90.5
5,783 8.516 7,409 78.1 114.9
6,172 8,151 7,876 78.4 103.5
6,636 8,741 8,306 79.9 105.2
6,845 9,125 8,691 70.8 105.0
7,242 9,505 9,065 79.9 104.9
7.715 9,825
9,327
82.7 105.3
8,290 10,643 9,956 83.3 106.9
8,964 11,611 10,298 87.0
112.8
10.483 14.047 10,723 97.8 131.0
Footnotes are found at the end of tile table,
TABLE 5-Il.-Continued
Officers’ and comparable civilian compensation profiles by length of service [1970 pay rates] 1
Total military
Regular compen-
military sation as a
Years
compensation
Regular
percent Of
Total Total
as a percent of total civilian
Of military military civilian total civilian
compen-
service compensation 2
compensation 3
compensation 4 compensation sation
1 ~.~~~~ $ 7,337 $ 6,422 $ 8.558 65.7 98.4
2 ~~~~~~~~ 7,566
6,740 9,291 61.5 94.1
3 .~~~~~~~~~~~.... 9,145 10,732 9,957 91 .a 107.6
4 ~~~.~~~~~~~ 10,906 12,674 10,556 103.3 122.0
5 ~~~~~~ 11,963 14,466 11,089 107.9 130.6
6 ~~~~ ~~~ 12,277 15,050 11,555 106.2 130.2
7 ~~~~~~~~~~~~.... 12,779
15,600
12,021
106.3 132.1
8 .~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 12,056
16,214
12,466
103.0 129.6
9-10 ....~~~~~~~~~~~~ 13,245 16,759 13,243
100.0 126.5
11-12 .~~...~..~...~~~ 14,056 10,144 14,669 95.7 123.5
13-16 ~~~~.~~~~.~ 14,966 19,545 15,844 94.6 123.4
17-20 ....~~~~~~~~~~~~
16,159 21,290 16,470 96.1 129.3
21 + ~~~~ ~~~ 19,142 26,771 17,765 107.6 150.7
TABLE WI.-Footnotes:
Voluntary enlisted deficits are highest in the Army. This result
too, is to be expected, given that entry level pay is lowest for
enlisted personnel and that the non-monetary conditions of
service are less attractive in the Army than in the other three
military services.
In addition to this indirect evidence, we have used several
methods to estimate directly the effect of increases in first and
second term pay on voluntary enlistments and reenlistments.
Based on these studies, and on the observed impact on retention
of proficiency pay and the variable reenlistment bonus, we
estimate that a IO percent increase in the current value of
first-term regular military compensation will result in an
increase of about 12.5 percent in the voluntary enlistment rate
from the 17 to 21 year old civilian population. In the case of
the Army, a 40 percent pay raise would increase the voluntary
enlistment rate from about 1.388 to about 2.079 per 100 men
in the 17 to 21, age cohort. The same percentage increase in
officer compensation will induce a roughly comparable rise in
the voluntary enlistment rate from the college population.
The Commission’s compensation recommendations are
designed both to eliminate past inequities and to assure the
services a flow of enlistments of the quantity and quality that
will be required to maintain a base force of about 2.5 million
men and women. Smaller forces could be maintained with
smaller increments in pay, while larger forces would require a
larger increase in pay.
The Commission has made two kinds of pay
recommendations, those requiring implementation prior to or
concomitant with the transition to an all-volunteer force, and
those equally necessary for reasons of equity and efficiency, but
not essential to the achievement of an all-volunteer force. In the
former category are increased basic pay, the extension of skill
differentials to the first-term population, and an increase in
hostile fire pay. In the latter category are the development of a
military salary system comparable to that in the civilian sector,
including the substitution of cash for some benefits that are
now provided in-kind, and the modification of the present
retirement system, including the introduction of vesting.
56
Basic Pay
The recommended increases in basic pay are designed to
provide the Army with the quantity and quality of volunteers
required for an overall force level of approximately 2.5 million
men. The evidence is overwhelming that, if compensation is set
at levels which satisfy Army requirements, the other services
will be able to attract enough qualified volunteers to meet their
respective requirements.
The Commission urges that its recommendations be
enacted with a minimum of delay and recommends an effective
date of July 1, 1970. Since there is a good chance that civil
service and military pay will also increase during fiscal 197 1, we
have assumed a basic pay increase of 8 percent on July 1, 1970
for all military personnel. The pay rates in table S-111 reflect a
combination of that across-the-board increase with the
recommended pay raises designed to achieve an all-volunteer
force of 2.5 million men. The latter increase raises the current
value of enlisted basic pay during the first-term of service by
about SO percent. The recommended increase for those in their
second term of service is about 9 percent. Officers in their first
3 years of service receive a 28 percent basic pay raise.
Table S-111 shows that these recommended increases
merely “straighten” the regular military compensation line;
they give individuals in their initial years of service about the
same pay relative to civilian compensation as the career force
receives. These pay raises for first-term personnel are justified
on equity grounds alone.
This recommended pay increase will add $2.69 billion to
the budget in fiscal year 1971, but this added outlay will be
smaller in future years if forces decline to the 2.5 million man
level and, also, as a result of the further manpower reduction
produced by lower turnover in the ah-volunteer force which will
decrease the force strengths required to provide a given level of
defense capability (see chapter 4). Since military pay is either
high or low only in relation to civilian earnings, annual
adjustments in military pay will be necessary to ensure that
they remain competitive.
The pay recommendation incorporated in table S-111 is
intended to apply to the 2.0, 2.25, and 2.5 million forces, but
they are actually in excess of those required for either the 2 or
57
TABLE 5-Ill.--Recommended pay profiles for enlisted personn.6l for July 7.1970
Regular Total
military military
compensation compensation
as a percent of as a percent of
Years Regular Total Total Total
Of military military civilian civilian
service compensation 1
compensation 2
compensation 3 compensation
1 ..~. $ 4,498 $ 5,041 86.5 96.9
2 4,917 5,631 84.7 97.0
3 5,311 6,237 83.4 97.9
4 5,735
7,195 83.0 104.2
5 8,143 9,131 4 82.9 123.2
6 6,530 8,597 82.9 109.2
7 6,880 9,055 82.8 109.0
8 7,203 9,582 82.9 110.3
9-l 0 ......~~~~~~ 7,510 9,838
82.8 108.5
11-l 2 ..~~~~~~.... 7,721 9,745 82.8 104.5
13-16 ~~~...~ 8,296 10,550 83.3 106.0
17-20 ~~~~~ 8,989 11,816 87.1 112.8
21 + ~~~~~~~~~~~~ 10.489 14.053 97.8 131.1
TABLE 5-lll.-Continued
Recommended pay profiles for officers for July 1, 1970
Regular
Total
military military
compensation compensation
as a percent of as a percent of
Years Regular Total Total
Total
Of military
military civilian civilian
service compensation 1 compensation 2 compensation 3 compensation
1 .~.. $ 0,868 $ 9,952 103.6 116.3
2
9,635 10,608 103.7 116.3
3 _.._....... 10,315 11,902 103.6 119.5
4 10,923 12,865 103.5 122.1
5
~. 11,999
14,520
108.2
130.9
6
12,313 15,077 106.6 130.5
7
~. 12,810 15,897 106.6 132.2
6
12,890 16,243
103.2
130.1
9-10 .~~ ._....... 13,271 16,756
100.2
126.5
1 l-l 2 . -~~~
14,080 18,128
95.6
123.4
13-16 ..~~ 15,006 19,534
94.7 123.3
17-20 .._.. -..~ 16,192
21,293 98.3 129.3
21 + ..~.~~~ 19,166
26,757 107.9 150.6
1. *, B”d ? see footnotes *, 3, and . resceBctivB,y 0, table WI ear ,hB de,initionO 0, reg”,*r military conlpe”.
Sam”, total mi,itw campnsation, and tota, CiYilian compnsa,ion.
d se0 tootnote r Of tam 5-i I.
2.25 million man forces. Indeed, the figures in table S-l suggest
that no pay increase is required to provide an all-volunteer force
of 2 million men and that a relatively small increase over
current levels is required to induce the additional volunteers
necessary for a 2.25 million man force. The Commission
recommends this pay raise for all three of the above named
forces on equity grounds alone. The 3.0 million man
all-volunteer force will require a pay increase above that shown
in table 5-111. The extra increase required for the 3 million man
force would add $2.21 billion more to the budget in the years
1977-1919.
Skill Differentials
The basic pay recommendations in table S-III are designed
to cover the majority of the enlisted force. However, the armed
forces must attract some persons with special skills or unusual
aptitudes. The military services have the authority to offer
higher pay to suyh individuals by offering higher grades when
they enter service or by increasing the speed of promotion. To
some extent both of these practices are being followed by the
services. These practices should be broadened and formalized,
to make military careers more attractive to high quality
personnel.
To ensure further the maintenance of the quality of
military personnel, proficiency pay should be made available to
those in critical occupations after the satisfactory completion of
advanced training. Currently, proficiency pay is available only
to those in the career force. These recommendations should
enable the services to satisfy their needs for exceptional
personnel. It is estimated that an additional $214 million per
year will be required to cover the expenditures for this purpose.
Hostile Fire Pay
Military service demands a high degree of personal
commitment and exposes most servicemen to risks and
hardships that are generally greater than those found in the
civilian economy. Beyond that, a small fraction of the military
force is sometimes required to serve under conditions of risk to
life and limb that are not only greater than those faced by most
service personnel, but exceptionally high even among those
serving in a combat zone.
60
As a matter of equity as well as to provide compensation
flexibility in conflict situations, the Commission recommends
that a new and higher maximum level of hostile fire pay of
$200 per month be enacted. Eligibility for this maximum level
of hazardous duty pay should be restricted to those who in the
course of their duties are regularly exposed to hostile fire and
only for the period of such exposure. The current levels of
hazardous duty pay should be provided to others in the combat
zone who take higher than normal risks but are not regularly
exposed to hostile fire.
Since the specific number of individuals who will serve
under such extreme hazardous conditions is likely to be small,
we have not estimated the budgetary implications of this
proposal.
Development of a Military Salary
System of Pay
Military pay today is a conglomeration of current and
future pay and benefits that are difficult to enumerate and even
more difficult to measure and evaluate. Military pay lacks
visibility. It functions as a continuous source of controversy. It
is inequitable. It is inefficient in attracting and retaining desired
personnel.
All of these deficiencies, and especially the last two, result
from the different ways of paying individuals performing the
same task, and from the large proportion of pay that is provided
either in-kind or as retirement income. This in-kind and
deferred compensation has little value for a new recruit or a
first-term setiiceman trying to decide whether to reenlist.
Recognizing these defects, a Department of Defense study
group recommended the introduction of a “salary” system of
pay in which allowances for quarters and subsistence would
have been combined with basic pay to provide a “salary”. The
Commission supports this recommendation.
Retirement Vesting
Because military retirement benefits are budgeted each
year out of current funds, servicemen have never acquired
vested retirement rights except those which arise after one has
served long enough (19% years) to be eligible to retire. This
policy has a number of undesirable effects.
61
First, because retired pay is deferred it has little value for
an individual in his early years of service, even if he is seriously
considering a military career. It is worth nothing to the
serviceman who does not plan to make the military a career.
Yet, the armed forces need both non-career and career
personnel.
Retirement benefits have the additional disadvantage of
being worth too much to the individual who is beyond his tenth
or eleventh year of service. He cannot afford to separate from
the service because of the benefits for which he will qualify
after another 9 or 10 years. Because of this potential loss, the
military rarely discharges individuals who have served more than
say, IO years.
Also, the substantial retirement income available after 20
years of service (when some enlisted men are only 37 years old)
induces many individuals to retire as soon as they are eligible.
The combination of retirement income and civilian earnings is
very attractive. Men who retire early are often those with
superior civilian earning opportunities and they are precisely the
individuals the services would like to retain longer. The
Department of Defense group organized to study compensation
recognized the shortcomings of the present retirement system.
They recommended: increasing military pay sufficiently to
enable military personnel to contribute 6% percent of their
salaries annually to their retirement account without any loss in
net income, the introduction of partial vesting after 5 years of
service, and a reduction in the retirement income available in
the years prior to the normal retirement age. The
recommendations incorporated provisions to ensure that those
who entered the services under the old retirement system would
suffer no loss.
The Commission supports these recommendations
regarding retirement benefits. The Commission also believes
that it would be equitable and desirable to give officers and
enlisted men the same vested retirement rights as civil service
employees currently have.
Compensation-in-kind and Fringe Benefits’
Many recommendations have been made for increasing
military compensation-in-kind including improved housing,
62
educational programs, dental care for dependents, etc. The
quality of military life needs to be improved generally, and such
programs would surely contribute to that end.
Nevertheless, we have decided against recommending
general increases in such benefits or in income-in-kind items of
pay. We have done so because the military pay package already
has a substantially larger proportion of such items than is found
in the civilian sector of the economy and because we believe
that general increases in non-cash pay would be an inefficient
means of compensating military personnel.
Funds that are used to construct and maintain housing can
also be used to increase basic pay, and funds to sponsor
educational programs can be used to provide dental care for
dependents. Thus, the question is not whether such benefits are
desirable, but whether they are the most effective form of
compensation. Providing compensation in cash has an inherent
advantage in that context ~ it allows each individual to decide
how he or she will use whatever he earns. He can thus get the
full value of whatever costs are incurred by the government in
paying him. When he is compensated in non-cash form,
however, the value of what he receives is often less to him than
its cost to the government. Meanwhile, he is encouraged to
consume more of particular goods or services than he otherwise
would. Non-cash pay also tends to result in inefficient patterns
of compensation by favoring some individuals (heavy users of
these items) over others, independent of performance. For
example, most military non-cash pay is of little value to young
men and women. Therefore it is not very effective in helping to
attract and retain new personnel. Finally, as was learned in the
Defense Department
study,
the effect of non-cash
remuneration on enlistments and retentions is attenuated
because such compensation is not very visible. While
compensation-in-kind is sometimes justifiable for tax reasons in
the civilian economy, that reason does not apply to military
compensation since the government is both payer of the cash
compensation and recipient of whatever taxes are collected.
However, special circumstances in the military often
warrant pay-in-kind. At remote bases, housing and other
services often would not be available unless provided under
military auspices, and in many instances, military personnel are
63
required to live on base. Under such circumstances
accommodations and services should be made attractive and
efficient so as to enhance the conditions of military life.
MANAGJZMENTOFMILITARYPERSONNEL
The Commission believes that in addition to the
recommendations above there are several opportunities available
to increase voluntarism, particularly among higher quality
personnel, by improving the conditions of military service and
the quality of military life.
Terms of Enlistment
One of the conditions of military service that distinguishes
it from civilian employment is the practice of requiring enlisted
personnel to obligate themselves for specific limited terms of
service. An enlisted man is required periodically to declare his
intentions to remain in the military, and he is permitted to
resign only when he reaches such a decision point. We believe
that this policy is not necessary, and that it adversely affects the
attractiveness of military service. We recommend elimination of
the present system of obligated terms of service so that enlisted
personnel would be recruited and retained on the same basis as
commissioned officers. Within the limits prescribed below, this
means that enlisted men would generally be granted discharges
upon request.
The right of enlisted men to a discharge should be limited
in the following ways:
(a) The Defense Department should have the authority
to deny such discharges in an emergency, just as it
does with officers.
(b) Enlisted men should be obligated to fulfill terms of
service commensurate with the cost of the training
they receive. This should apply not only to new
recruits, but also to those receiving advanced training.
The Defense Department should undertake a study to
determine the length of obligated service to be
required for various training programs. Such a study
would specify a minimum term of service for new
recruits. We do not contemplate that it would be
64
reasonable to require terms of service of less than
approximately two years for recruits.
(c) The Defense Department should have the right to
deny discharges to enlisted personnel who have
received orders for overseas, duty or sea duty.
If the Defense Department adopts this policy as to
obligated terms of service, the services should simultaneously
establish procedures for periodic reviews designed to identify
and separate servicemen who are not performing satisfactorily.
Though this change may appear dramatic, the
abandonment of the present system of fixed enlistment terms
should not create serious problems for the military. Such a
system has not harmed the officer corps. The increased freedom
of choice should make military service more attractive and
enhance the dignity of an enlisted career.
Choice o/f Military Occupation
The Commission recommends an expansion of the current
program whereby enlistees are permitted to specify their choice
of occupation as a condition of enlistment. Such a policy
should increase the efficiency of manpower utilization within
the military and, also, by reducing the uncertainty of military
life, increase the attractiveness of a military career.
The Commission believes that expansion of the existing
program will not weaken the services’ ability to fulfill their
mission, even though it may increase somewhat the cost of
managing the recruitment facilities. The services do not appear
to have experienced any ill effects from their present policy of
giving individuals a choice of their service branch and, to a large
extent, their occupational field.
Lateral Hiring
Many of the functions performed in a modern military
organization have parallels in the civilian economy, for example,
construction, supply and logistics, personnel management,
equipment
and facilities maintenance, research and
development, and medical service. With minor exceptions the
officers and the enlisted personnel who staff these functions in
the military are products of the military personnel system. They
enter the service as untrained recruits, take basic and advanced
65
formal or on-the-job training, and acquire the experience
necessary to function effectively while on a military assignment.
The similarity between military and civilian functions, however,
suggests that military positions might in many instances be
filled by already skilled individuals who transfer from the
civilian economy.
Lateral hiring ~ the hiring of skilled personnel into the
armed services at pay grades commensurate with their training
and experience - offers the services an opportunity to enlarge
the manpower pool from which they draw. In the past they
have resorted to lateral hiring to procure personnel with special
skills. During World War II the practice was used extensively,
not only for enlisted personnel but also for officers. Also, the
military has consistently permitted doctors, dentists and
lawyers to enter the services at officer ranks above the usual
entry level.
Currently, the largest enlisted lateral hiring program is the
Navy’s “Direct Petty Officer Procurement Program” which has
been used since 1965 to man Naval construction battalions.
Under this revival of the World War II Seabee program over
5,000 civilian construction workers have been hired into pay
grades E4 through E7 with a service obligation of two and
one-half years. The program is apparently a success. Draft
pressure, higher pay and the shorter service obligation (two and
one-half rather than the normal four years) have allowed the
Navy to be highly selective.
The Army has used lateral hiring to recruit medical and
dental technicians at entry pay grades of E4 and E5. Each
lateral enlistee receives about 16 weeks of basic and advanced
training. The Army also plans to introduce a program for
selected engineer occupational fields which are significantly
undermanned.
These examples, however, are the exception rather than
the rule. On balance, the services have used lateral hiring
sparingly. At worst they have limited the payment of
reenlistment bonuses to those who re-enlist within six months
of discharge so that a qualified trained veteran who has been
out longer is offered no special incentive to return.
There are, of course, inherent limits to lateral entry. Not
all military occupations have civilian counterparts, and even
where such counterparts exist it may be less costly for the
military to provide
the training and experience.
66
Notwithstanding the limiting considerations, the military are
sacrificing an important opportunity by severely restricting the
use of lateral entry. Moreover, lateral entry would help dissolve
the barrier which some feel separates the military from civilian
society.
Entitlements
At present, enlisted men who are not E4’s with four or
more years of service are not entitled to dislocation allowance
and reimbursement of family travel expense when .they are
ordered to a new duty station. This discrimination imposes an
unnecessary hardship on first-term servicemen. The Commission
recommends that entitlement to reimbursement of family travel
expense and dislocation allowance be extended to all enlisted
personnel.
67
CHAPTER 6
OFFICER PROCUREMENT
AND RETENTION
Regardless of the type of procurement system used, the
officer corps is a crucial element in the effectiveness of any
military establishment. An all-volunteer armed force must
attract an adequate supply of officers from the limited number
of individuals in the population who possess the necessary
leadership qualities and motivation.
In recent years the major portion of the officer corps has
been recruited from the ranks of college graduates. While it is
important to continue to attract college-graduate officers. the
decision to staff the officer corps almost entirely with college
graduates was somewhat arbitrary and came about in part
because of the favorable recruiting climate provided by the
draft. Without the draft, a college- graduate officer corps will be
more difficult to recruit and will require higher pay levels than
one which includes home non-college graduates. To balance the
need for highquality officers with the extra cost that a
voluntary all college graduate force will entail. we assume in our
estinlates that about 90 percent of the officers entering the
69
service each year will be college graduates. It is expected that
most non-college graduates will either have graduated from
two-year college programs or have at least two years of college.
Staffing the non-specialist portion of the officer corps in
an all-volunteer armed force will be somewhat easier than
recruiting the enlisted force. Two main reasons underlie our
optimism. First, except during the Vietnam escalation of recent
years, little difficulty has been encountered in recruiting new
officers from among college graduates. While the draft has been
an important positive factor in this recruiting, the flow of
volunteers has been impressive in view of the relative ease with
which college graduates could avoid military service through the
middle 1960’s.’ Also to be taken into account is the relatively
large proportion of first-term officers who remain in the
military beyond their obligated period of service. Over 70
percent of officer personnel are currently beyond their
obligated period of service and, therefore, can be considered
career officers.
The second reason for optimism stems from the large and
growing pool of educationally qualified young men who will be
available in the 1970’s for military service as officers. Since
1960, the number of male college graduates has grown from
230,000 per year to 390,000 per year ~ an increase of 70
percent. By 1980, this number will increase 25 percent more to
490,000 amx~ally.~ With an armed force of 2.5 million, the
annual requirement for new officers is not likely to exceed
30,000. This number can be met by recruiting about 7 percent
of the yearly graduating classes of U.S. colleges and universities
in the mid-l 970’s.
PROCUREMENT
Most commissioned officer procurement programs are
designed chiefly to attract college graduates. These sources of
officers can be divided into four major groups: Reserve Officer
Training Corps (ROTC) and other in-college programs. Officer
Candidate programs. service academies. and direct
appointments. In addition. there are a number of programs
which provide Warrant Officers. Limited Duty Officers. and
Temporary Officers. By and large this range of programs has
met the needs of the services even when these have changed
rather drastically. The smne major programs. perhaps modified
in form, can be expected to supply the hulk of new officers in
an all-volunteer armed force.
RESERVE OFFICER TRAINING CORPS (ROTC) AND
OTHER COLLEGE PROGRAMS
By far the largest single source of newly commissioned
officers is the Reserve Officer Training Corps. Designed
primarily for four-year colleges. it accounted for 26 percent of
all new officers in the period just preceding the Vietnam war.
(See table 6-l.) An additional IS percent of officers
commissioned in FY 1965 were obtained from a variety of
in-college programs. Chief among these are the Reserve Officer
Corps (ROC) in the Navy and the Platoon Leader Corps (PLC)
in the Marine Corps. The major distinction between these
programs and the ROTC program is that military training is
provided entirely during the summer at special training centers
run by the military. whereas the ROTC cadet receives a major
portion of his training at his university during the school year.
Because of the long lead time - two to four years - required
for increasing the supply of officers from these sources. their
relative importance declined during the rupid troop build-up in
the early stages of the Vietnam War.
The importance of ROTC officers varies considerably from
service to service. In FY 1965. they accounted for about 60
percent of newly commissioned Army officers, slightly less than
35 percent of new Air Force officers. and less than IS percent
of new Navy officers. In the Marine Corps only about 7 percent
of the new officers were commissioned through the Navy-run
ROTC program. The great majority of Marine officers were
recruited from the PLC program.
At the completion of an ROTC student’s college education
he is required to serve a minimum term of obligated service.
This minimum currently varies from service to service and
according to the type of program. All scholarship recipients,
regardless of service. must serve four years of active duty. For
71
non-scholarship holders, the minimum is two years in the Army,
three in the Navy and Marine Corps, and four in the Air
Force. The two-year Army obligation was in part designed to
be consistent with the active duty obligation of a draftee. We
have assumed in our projections that in a voluntary force the
minimum Army ROTC obligation will be three years.
During the last few years, a number of schools either
ended their ROTC programs, or indicated they planned to do so
in the near future. While it is not clear whether these are
isolated events or the beginning of a trend, there is little doubt
that some type of college recruiting program will continue in
the future. For planning purposes, we assumed that ROTC will
continue to be the major source of new officers for the Army
and Air Force. The problem of declining ROTC enrollment is
discussed later in the chapter.
A number of Department of Defense studies have recently
been undertaken concerning the future of ROTC. While
differing somewhat in goals and procedures, all recommend an
increase in the number of ROTC college scholarships. We
endorse this recommendation and encourage the use of such
scholarships as a way of attracting applicants not likely to enter
the program without them - especially those whose skills or
aptitudes are in short supply in the military. In our projections
of potential officer supply without a draft, we assumed an
increase of 4,500 scholarships a year for each service (Marine
Corps included in Navy total) producing 1,000 additional
ROTC officers a year per service (See table 6-H). The total cost
of such a program will be between $25 and $30 million per year
and is included in our estimates of the increased budgetary
expenditures associated with the creation of an all-volunteer
officers corps.
With an all-volunteer armed force, one must expect that
fewer students will volunteer for ROTC training, particularly in
the first two years. Hence many schools may find that they can
no longer operate viable programs. To insure that ROTC
instruction remains available to interested students, it may be
advisable in the future to establish area training centers. Thus
students from a number of schools in one geographic region
could participate in the same training program.
Serious consideration should also be given to the increased
use of scholarship and non-scholarship Reserve Officer Corps
and Platoon Leader Corps-type programs. Unlike the present
7s
Fiscal
Year
1971
1972
1973
2
1974
1975
1976
1977
1978
1979
1980
TABLE 6-IL-Army commissioned officer requirements and potential supply in an all-volunteer force
[2.5 million man force /eve/]
Potential supply
ROTC ocs
~__
Scholar- Nonscholar- College Noncollege
Academy' ship'
ship:' graduates4 graduates;' Others B
Total
900 1,400 11,200 200 1,000 1,400 16,100
900 1,500 8,000 300 1,000 500 12,200
1,000 2,000 5,700 300 1,000 600 10,600
1,000 2,500 3,200 400 1,000 1,000 9,100
1,000 2,500 3,100 500 1,000 700 6,800
1,000 2,500 4,100 500 1,000 700 9,800
1,000 2,500 5,100 500 1,000 800 10,900
1,000 2,500 6,000 600 1,000 800 11,900
1,000 2,500 6,800 600 1,000 800 12,700 9,000 +3,700
1,000 2.500 7,300 600 1,000 800 13,200 9,400 +3,800
Required
accessions
16,800
5,300
7,100
11,400
6.700
8,500
9,900
9,500
Estimated
SUrplUS
Or
shortage
- 700
+ 6,900
+3,500
-2,300
+ 100
+1,300
fl,OOO
+2,400
ROTC. such programs do not require the stationing of
permanent units on ij great nx\ny campuses. With the
introdu&ion of an iill-volunteer force and the reduction in the
size of each ROTC unit. the per-graduate expense is likely to
rise. If much of the military training can be provided during the
summer in training stations which receive applicants from many
schools. there is a good possibility that substantial savings can
be realized.
OFFICER CANDIDATE PROGRAMS
While officer candidate
progmms were originally
established to train officers recruited from the enlisted ranks.
they have increasingly been used in recent years to supplt‘ment
the flow of new college graduates into the officer corps. The
large demand for new officers created by the Vietnam buildup.
however, required the Army, in particular, to allow significant
numbers of non-college graduates to enter its OCS program.
OCS programs are more responsivr than ROTC to changes in
military requirements, requiring a lead time of three to nine
months as opposed to two to four years for the ROTC. With an
all-volunteer force. each service will require more flexibility in
the recruiting of officers. In addition to new college graduates.
the services will doubtless seek to attract somewhat older
civilians who desire to enter one of the more specialized and less
physically demanding branches of the military. Such volunteers
will require some military training. which is likely to be most
efficiently provided through OCS-type programs.
ACADEMIES
A small but highly important number of new officers are
commissioned annually by the service academies. Ranging in
size from about 3 percent of the annual number of entering
officers in the Army to more than 6 percent in the Navy.
academy graduates form an important component of each
service’s officer corps. Their high career motivation is clearly
shown by the fact that upon completion of their obligated tour
of active duty (now 5 years). between 80 and 90 percent can be
expected to remain in the service. as opposed to less than 50
percent for ROTC scholarship graduates and under 1-5 percent
for OCS graduates.
With the planned expansion of the U.S. Military Academy
and.the Air Force Academy. academy graduates in 1973 will
77
number about 1,840. For the foreseeable future, even with an
all-volunteer force, we do not anticipate a need to increase
further the size of the academies. Such expansion would be very
costly and it is also highly desirable that military officers
continue to be recruited from a wide range of civilian colleges
and universities.
DIRECT COMMISSIONING PROGRAMS
Each service requires many individuals possessing
non-combat type skills available in the civilian population.
These include chaplains, lawyers, physicians, dentists, and
specially trained technicians. Because of the importance and
special problems connected with the recruitment of physicians,
a separate study was undertaken by the Commission. The
highlights of this study are reported in chapter 8. By and large,
because appointment officers perform the same tasks in the
military as in the civilian sector, they usually receive no extra
military training. Such direct appointments have accounted for
about 20 percent of new officers each year.
Since a major portion of these officers would not have
entered military service without the draft, an all-volunteer force
will necessitate more in-service training and further increases in
the substitution of civilians for military personnel. In addition,
we would suggest that procedures be established to attract
civilians who already possess the necessary training, by offering
advanced officer grades. Such lateral hiring generally should be
limited to those specialties which require an individual to
possess technical skills learned in the civilian sector and to those
tasks and functions which must be performed by a military
officer.
WARRANT, LIMITED DUTY AND TEMPORARY
OFFICERS
Each service includes men who hold the rank of officer but
who are not considered part of the regular commissioned officer
corps. Included in this group are Warrant Officers, Limited
Duty Officers and Temporary Officers. Such ranks are designed
for non-college graduates who occupy positions which require
greater technical skills and carry larger responsibilities than the
enlisted grades. In most instances, such officer ranks are
awarded to superior enlisted personnel. The Army, however,
actively recruits civilian two-year college graduates and men
78
with some college for their helicopter pilot warrant officer
p*0gMlL
The increased availability of four-year college graduates
during the 1960’s resulted in a decline in the use of these
programs. Expanded officer requirements during the Vietnam
buildup have reversed this trend. To facilitate the transition to,
and the maintenance of, an all-volunteer armed force, we
assumed in our analysis that greater use will be made of these
sources of officer manpower.
PROJECTED SUPPLY OF ARMY OFFICERS IN AN
ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCE
The problem of maintaining a voluntary Officer Corps is
more difficult in the Army than it is in the other services. If the
level of officer compensation is high enough to meet Army
accession requirements, it will also be adequate for the Air
Force, Navy, and Marine Corps. For that reason the analysis of
officer supply f&uses on the Army.
The most important source of supply of Army officers is
ROTC. We have derived estimates of the number of Army
officers which ROTC will produce in an all-volunteer
environment for the period 1971 to 1980, from an analysis of
ROTC enrollments at schools where participation is voluntary
These projections are calculated on the assumption that: (I) the
draft is ended in 197 1; (2) the level of war intensity declines by
1972 to the pre-buildup level of 1964; and (3) military pay
relative to civilian earnings is increased to comparability, as
described in chapter 5, table 5-111.
The ROTC supply figures are shown in table 6-11 along
with estimates of supply from the other officer procurement
programs. Because of the special benefits inherent in receiving
an ROTC scholarship or enrolling in the U.S. Military Academy,
we anticipate that both programs will continue to be fully
subscribed in an all-volunteer armed force, and will produce the
expected number of annual accessions. The technique for
estimating output from the other procurement sources is
summarized in the footnotes to table 6-I.
The total potential flow of men into the Army officer
corps will continue at a high level through FY 1972 because of
draft-induced volunteers remaining in the pipeline. The lowest
level of Army ROTC entrants, we estimate, will be in FY 1975.
19
Most officers commissioned in that year would have entered the
ROTC program in 1971 ~ a time when the negative impact of
the war on enrollments will probably be at its height. After FY
1975, as the war’s impact on past enrollments diminishes and
more men enter as a result of the pay raise, potential supply will
increase. Except for FY 1974, the estimated supply will be
more than adequate to meet anticipated accession requirements
to maintain the Army Officer Corps in a 2.5 million man force
without the draft. This one year shortfall can easily be offset by
permitting more accessions in the previous two years. Hence, we
feel justified in concluding that the recommended all-volunteer
pay profile plus anticipated increases in the ROTC scholarship
program will be sufficient to maintain the officer corps for each
service at required levels for an all-volunteer armed force of 2.5
million or less. In the late 1970’s the supply estimates shown in
table 6-11 are sufficient to staff the officer corps in a 3.0 million
volunteer armed force. To insure that the required number of
accessions for such a larger force would be forthcoming,
however, we have included in our cost estimates for the 3.0
million man force a further increase in officer pay.
RETENTION
In an all-volunteer force, more officers will stay beyond
their initial obligated period of service than with a draft. Those
who today constitute true volunteers ~ individuals who would
have entered military service without the draft ~, will make up a
larger proportion of first-term officers, and their demonstrated
higher retention experience will increase overall first-term
retention.
First-term retention in the current force varies
considerably from one procurement source to another and from
one service to another. For those procurement programs
including a large concentration of draft-motivated volunteers,
which will not be as important in an all-volunteer force, the
proportion remaining beyond the obligated period of service is
relatively low. In this category, in particular, are
college-graduate OCS officers in the Army and Navy where
first-term retention rates are less than 30 percent. At the other
end of the spectrum, at least 80 out of every 100 academy
graduates can be expected to remain beyond their obligated
80
period of service. Overall, the Air Force has the highest
first-term retention rate and the Army, the lowest.
The impact on turnover of eliminating the draft can be
appreciated by analyzing the results of a Department of Defense
survey of active duty personnel. As shown in table 6-111, among
officers serving their original obligated tour of duty, 46 percent
of those who indicated they would have entered the military
without the draft said they planned to remain on active duty
until retirement. Of those who were considered draft-motivated
volunteers, only 16 percent said they expected to remain in the
service.
The survey results generally confirm expected differences
in retention between services and sources of commission. From
all sources of commission, the Army is revealed to have the
smallest proportion of career-motivated first-term officers,
while the Air Force has the largest. For each service, even
among those who were considered to be draft-motivated
volunteers, academy graduates consistently record the highest
overall expected retention rate. High retention rates are also
shown for ROTC and OCS entrants into the Air Force and OCS
graduates in the Army. During the period prior to the survey,
both the Air Force and Army OCS programs jncluded mostly
non-college graduates. These results reveal the high career
motivation of such officers and suggest that, if difficulty is
experienced with recruiting new college graduate officers in an
all-volunteer environment, serious consideration should be given
to expanding the non-college officer commissioning programs.
Another interesting aspect of these results is that among
the “true volunteers”
recruited through the more
draft-motivated procurement programs, such as college-graduate
OCS, the proportion expecting to make a career in the military
was relatively small. This suggests that even with an
all-volunteer force and more career-oriented accessions,
turnover still will be substantial and a continuous flow of
civilianeducated college graduates will enter the force each
year.
Although these derived career rates are lower than actual
first-term rates, the relative differences between the true
volunteer rate and the draft-motivated volunteer rate were used
to estimate the increase in officer retention that will accompany
a shift to an all-volunteer force.
81
TABLE
&Ill.-Expected career retention rate of first-term officers by service and source of commission 1
1964
Source of Commission
Academy
0.60
.65
.27
.64
.66
.41
.59
.63
.16
.53
.53
-
.60
.67
.26
ROTC
0.26
.42
.lO
.I7
.31
.06
.18
.2a
.09
.36
.43
.21
.43
ocs
(college
graduate)
0.16
.24
.14
-
-
-
.15
.25
.14
.19
.24
.13
ocs
(noncollege
Direct
graduate) 5 appointment
0.44 0.16
.62 .31
.27 .06
.46 .12
.63 .31
.27 .04
- .24
- .36
- .13
- .67
- .67
- -
.44 .15
.55
-
.62
.27
.19
-
.27 .05
CHAPTER 7
RECRUITMENT
An expanded and more effective recruiting effort will help
supply an all-volunteer force with the desired quality of
enlistees. The Commission therefore suggests that the armed
services devote an increased proportion of their resources to
recruiting and especially to Army recruiting. Studies indicate
that a relatively small increase in recruiting expenditures would
produce as much as a 10 to 20 percent rise in enlistment rates.
Also, modification of existing procedures and increased
financial support should yield substantial gains in recruiter
productivity.
Since 1961, as shown in table 7-1, the relative proportion
of the military’s manpower budget devoted to recruiting has
remained constant and the number of recruiters has also not
increased.
In view of the increased need for enlistments since 1965,
the stability of relative recruiting expenditures and the number
of recruiters are surprising. They reflect the low priority
assigned to recruiting so long as the draft is available to ensure
an adequate supply of manpower for the lower ranks. Clearly,
elimination of the draft will increase the need for effective
recruiting and the budget required. Even if conscription were to
continue, the services should devote increased resources to
attracting “true” volunteers rather than settling for draftees
because the former are more likely to make the military a
career.
TABLE
7-l.-Recruiting resources, 1961-69
Total recruiters
all services
7,114
7,219
7,070
6,903
7,056
7,241
7,371
7,176
6,987
Obviously, the military benefits more from its investment
in an individual who chooses to enlist for three years than from
another who is drafted for two. If instead of drafting 33 men
who will serve for a total of 66 years (2 years each), the Army
can recruit 22 men for a total of 66 years (three years of service
each), it will need to train I I less men over that three-year
period. Since one trainer (or supporting person) is required for
I I recruits each year, enlisting rather than conscripting 22 men
will save one trainer. In fiscal 1965, average enlistments per
recruiter were roughly 55. A study conducted that year
indicated that additional recruiters easily achieved an annual
minimum of 22 enlistments and thus “saved” one trainer.
Therefore, regardless of whether the draft is maintained, there
seems substantial opportunity for the productive addition of
more recrujters.
Recruiters play an important role in influencing young
men to enlist in the armed services. Ideally, recruiters should be
dedicated career men who are skilled in the art of salesmanship.
Highly qualified men are in great demand within any institution
and the services cannot necessarily have their best men serve as
84
recruiters. Nevertheless, a prospective recruiter should have a
positive attitude toward the military as a profession, some
aptitude for a public relations role and a genuine desire to
undertake recruiting duty. There is no reason why able
recruiters should be automatically rotated to other assignments.
Instead, successful recruiters should be allowed to extend their
tours of duty, while the unsuccessful are assigned elsewhere.
Every recruiter should receive adequate training hefore
assignment to the field. Such training may be more valuable iI. it
involves greater student participation and less memorization of
information and procedures. It would also be desirable for
recruiters in the field to share their experience with trainees in
school.
Also recommended is an improved incentive system for
recruiters. Recognition of successful recruiters could take the
form of financial compensation such as extra pay or bonuses as
well as accelerated promotions.
We also advocate elimination of the present system under
which each district, city and individual recruiter receives an
enlistment quota. Substantial evidence indicates that this
system eliminates the incentive to seek enlistees in excess of
one’s quota.
In addition, the quotas are not always set at appropriate
levels. Studies show that cities which do not meet their quotas
usually have significantly higher enlistment rates, and that
additional recruiters in cities where quotas are met would
substantially increase enlistment rates. Elimination of the quota
system ahd institution of more positive incentives should result
in higher productivity per recruiter.
In allocating additional resources to recruiting, two- and
three-man offices in cities should receive greater priority than
one-man offices in smaller communities. Studies have shown
that more recruiters at stations in large cities yield greater
returns than an equal increase in the number of recruiters in
one-man offices in small towns. A greater concentration of
recruiting efforts at such stations should be coordinated with
more indirect selling and advertising in these larger markets.
More advertising in mass media will be both required and
rewarding once an all-volunteer force has been instituted, for
the elimination of conscription will coincide with improved
incentives in the military. Visits to high schools by recruiters,
films, performances by special military units, and other
85
appearances will continue to contribute to a positive image for
the military.
The British have used such supplementary techniques as
the “buddy” system in which enlisted men help persuade their
friends to volunteer. This and other new techniques should be
tested, especially during the transition to an all-volunteer force.
86
CHAPTER 8
CONSCRIPTION OF PHYSICIANS
The very troublesome problem of conscription of medical
doctors has been the subject of independent inquiry by the
Commission. Our studies suggest that a variety of steps can be
taken to reduce the need for such conscription. Each of these
measures will individually contribute something toward
eliminating the doctor draft. but we are not certain that they
are adequate. Fortunately, given the reduction in forces now
planned and the students already committed to military service,
there is time not only for further study, but for
experimentation with some of the measures suggested, such as
increased compensation for military physicians and fellowship
programs for medical students.
Eighty percent of all male physicians in the United States
under 35 have served in the armed forces or have held reserve
commissions. No other group in our society has had such heavy
relative demands placed upon it for military service. Only four
percent of male physicians under 35 who are eligible for service
have not yet served. In the last four years. more than 4,500
87
doctors entered active duty service annually - fully 60 percent
of the number graduating from medical schoo1 each year.
Physicians also suffer the greatest financial loss by having
to serve. The pay and allowances received by a young doctor
entering military service are approximately one-half the amount
he could earn as a civilian. Despite relatively rapid promotions,
special pay, continuation pay, etc., a medical officer is
significantly underpaid throughout his career. Primarily for this
reason,
doctors
do not usually remain in the military. Sixty
percent of all military doctors have served less than two years.
Table 8-I summarizes the size and character of the health
service in the armed forces as of January 1, 1969. It
encompassed 242 hospitals and 450 reporting dispensaries, and
employed over 200,000 people. The patient population slightly
exceeded 10,000,000, only 3% million of whom were active
duty personnel. The other 6% million were civilians; either
dependents of active duty personnel or retirees or their
dependents.
Official accounting for medical services puts the annual
budget at $2 billion. Our studies place the expenditures at a
considerably higher figure
- about
$3.25 billion. Moreover, the
latter estimates accept military earnings as the cost of both
enlisted and officer personnel. If the services of those personnel
were priced correctly, that is, at their value in the civilian
economy, the cost of military medical service would be even
larger. We estimate that the expenditure on medical services
rendered
by
the military medical corps is about $325 per capita
as compared to $254 per capita for the entire U.S. population
in 1967. The quality of the health care rendered by the military
medical corps is generally considered to be very high.
Both the size of the patient population and the personnel
requirements in table 8-1 reflect the build-up for Vietnam.
Those magnitudes will decline with active duty force
reductions.
Table 8-11 presents data on the utilization of military
medical facilities
by
type of beneficiary in 1969, and highlights
a neglected aspect of conscription. Perhaps one-half of the
physicians now conscripted into service are actually serving a
civilian population. Despite the increased need for medical
services for active duty personnel as a result of Vietnam, 47
percent of hospital admissions and 48 percent of outpatient
88
TABLE 8-l.-Department of defense medicalservices
visits
involved dependents and retired personnel. Presumably,
the proportion will be even larger in the post-war environment.
A large centralized health organization has been developed,
not just to serve active duty military personnel, but to serve a
89
TABLE .S-Il.-Medical care provided at fixed medical facilities
in fiscal year 1969
broad clientele in specialties ranging from obstetrics (146,000
babies delivered in 1969) and pediatrics to geriatrics. Indeed,
patient care is only a part of the organization’s activity. It
sponsors a variety of medical education and training programs
as well as an extensive program of medical research. The
desirability of these services is not in question. Good medical
care is an attractive inducement to prospective volunteers, and
it is one of the more important morale factors for career
military personnel. What is in question, however, is whether it is
either necessary or advisable to sustain that care with doctors
who are compelled to serve.
The professional manpower required to provide these
services is drawn from a wide variety of sources but virtually
none of the entrants are true volunteers. All but a handful enter
because of the threat of being drafted. If the draft is eliminated,
dramatic action will be required to insure the continuation of
health care now provided by the military medical system.
We have assumed that, whatever steps are taken to convert
to a fully voluntary military medical service, the quantity and
quality of care supplied to the present patient population will
be maintained. Within that constraint there are two courses of
action open in converting the system to volunteers. One is to
90
decrease the requirement for military physicians by substituting
civilians in their stead. The other is to increase the number of
physicians willing to volunteer by improving earnings and other
conditions of employment.
EXPANDED USE OF CIVILIANS TO PROVIDE
MEDICAL CARE
A shift of some fraction of military patient care to civilian
physicians can be accomplished in either of two ways: (1) by
establishing a medical insurance program for some portion of
the patient population - the most likely candidates being
retirees and their dependents or the dependents of active duty
servicemen, or (2) by engaging civilian physicians to staff some
military medical facilities.
A medical insurance scheme is already in effect for retired
personnel, and for dependents who can demonstrate that care
provided by the military is not available to them. Patients under
such a plan obtain medical services from a civilian physician or
in a civilian hospital and are reimbursed for the costs. While the
substitution of private medical insurance for directly rendered
health care is an appealing possibility, it has a number of
disadvantages. Shifting patients to the civilian sector would, at
least in the near term, further raise costs there. Physicians
released from the military could shift to civilian health care, but
the hospitals, equipment, etc. could not readily be shifted. To
the extent that these military facilities are replaced by a system
of private medical insurance, the armed services would reduce
their ability to expand available medical care to meet a crisis.
Also, substitution of private medical insurance would mean
losing the advantages of a unified health care system for the
highly mobile population of active duty dependents.
The substitution of civilian physicians for military doctors
within the existing organization could be effected on an
individual position basis, but substitution on the scale required
is probably possible only through contracting with organized
groups of doctors to operate military hospitals or other medical
facilities. The present organizational format for most of the
health service of the armed forces can best be described as
hospital-based group practice.’ Hospital-based group practice
‘me remainder consists or la*@ an* Smsll medics, ““its in direct support of
combat units.
91
has proved a most efficient form of medical organization in the
civilian economy. The Permanente medical groups. for example.
provide economical health care for 7 million subscribers in the
facilities of the Kaiser Health Foundation. The Defense
Department might on a similar basis negotiate contracts with
groups of physicians to exe for patients in existing military
hospitals. Such civilian medical groups would have a number of
advantages. They would preserve the hospital-based
organizational format. and the advantage of a unified system.
They could eliminate duplication of facilities in areas where
more than one service maintains health facilities. Where military
facilities are under-used, the group practice might be expanded
to include otherwise ineligible civilians. There would be less
turnover of medical personnel and more female doctors.
Professional staffing would be easier and less expensive because
the physicians would not have to experience many of the
disadvantages associated with medical service in the military.
But there are also some disadvantages. With the size of the
military medical corps reduced, the number of physicians
available for service in a conflict like Vietnam will be smaller.
Also. the peacetime rotation of those remdining may be
increased and their assignments made less attractive. Conversion
of military hospitals to civilian contruct operation can proceed
only on the basis of careful study of each individual installation.
Moreover. care must be taken to preserve desirable assignments
for career medical officers and to provide bases for medical
education and training. In addition. a careful analysis will be
necessary to determine the minimum number of doctors
required on active duty by length of service -“- an analysis based
on realistic contingency plans and on rotation base
requirements for planned force levels.
INCREASING THE NUMBER OF
PHYSICIANS WHO VOLUNTEER
Physicians. like other active duty personnel, make career
decisions on the basis of a wide variety of pecuniary and
non-pecuniary aspects of the careers under consideration. These
include potential earnings. available facilities and equipment.
security. prestige. opportunities for further education and
research. type of patient, patient/physician relationships, etc.
The attractiveness of military medical careers can no doubt be
enhanced by improving some of the non-pecuniary factors.
92
However. the gap between civilian and military medical income
is now so large, and the number of true volunteers is so small,
that such improvements do not touch the heart of the problem.
Something substantial must be done about pecuniary rewards
for military physicians to obtain a voluntary military medical
corps. There are again two major alternatives. One is to provide
stipends to medical students in exchange for a commitment to
serve for a specified period. The other is to raise the pay of
medical officers.’ The extent to which reliance is placed on one
or the other of these two depends upon the size career medical
force it is desirable to maintain. Stipends for medical students
will provide a broad base of young physicians, most of whom
will not elect careers in the military. Increasing the pay for
medical officers on the other hand will significantly effect
retention. Indeed the compensation schedule for physicians
should be designed specifically to provide efficiently the desired
number and length of service distribution of doctors. In this
regard, the military’s retirement system is inefficient within the
context of the medical corps because it permits military
physicians to retire with full benefits (about half salary) after
20 years of service and embark on a civilian career. After twenty
years, these doctors are relatively young and still capable of
serving effectively.
A variety of forms of subsidies to medical students are
feasible. Differences between civilian and military earnings for
doctors suggest that a stipend of $5,000 per year paid to
medical students over seven years (four years of medical school,
one year of internship, and two years of residency) would
produce a significant flow of volunteers willing to commit
themselves to three years of active duty. Variations on this basic
arrangement could include larger stipends for shorter periods or
smaller stipends for shorter service commitments. Such stipends
could be tied into already existing plans for bringing medical
students into the military.
Data to use as a basis for reliable estimates of the effect of
compensation on the number of physicians who would enter
the military or the number who would remain there are not
available. For that reason, a provisional approach to medical
pay seems advisable. Data on civilian earnings for medical
doctors. are available, and have been used to develop the
compensation profiles shown in table S-111. Columns 3 and 4 of
table S-111 give the annual salary and continuation pay for
medical officers as of July 1, 1969. At present medical officers
TABLE 8-W.-Proposed compensation for medical officers
Physician
Medical
Active Officer Annual continua- Physician officer
service rank
salary ' tion pay2
pay
total salary
$11,034.38
11,455.58
11,455.58
11,793.98
12.319.58
12.99998
12,999.98
13,801.18
13,801.18
14.115%
14,952.98
15,888.98
15,888.98
18.859.12
18.859.12
17.084.18
18,779.78
19,719.38
19,719.38
19.719.38
19.719.38
21.170.18
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
$2,82i
2,950
3,120
3,358
3,358
3,549
3,549
3,855
4,041
4,278
4,278
5,701
5,701
8,185
$ 1,800 $12,834
1.800 13.258
3,800 15,058
5,400 17,194
7,200 19,520
9,000 22,000
10.800 23.800
12.800 28.201
12,800 29,023
12,800 29,888
12,800 30,873
12,800
31,845
12,600 31,845
12.800 32,808
12,800 32.808
12.800 33,339
12,800 35,421
12,800 38,595
12,800 38,595
12.800 38,020
12,800 38.020
12,800
39,955
with 2-6 years of active duty also receive an additional $150 a
month as special physician pay. Column 5 sets forth a new
schedule
of physician pay as follows:
94
Third year of duty $300 a month
Fourth year of duty $450 a month
Fifth year of duty $600 a month
Sixth year of duty
$750 il month
Seventh year of duty $900 a month
Eighth year of duty $ I.050 a month
The last column of table S-111 gives the sum of these three
components of compensation. The total salaries shown in
column 6 compare reasonably well with those of physicians in
group practice, except in the early years where they are lower
to take account of the student stipends discussed above. If
student support is not undertaken, or if individuals wish to join
the military who have not participated in the fellowship
program, the total salary in the early years would have to be
adjusted upward.
We believe that the salary schedule derived in table S-111 is
a major step towards a fully voluntary medical corps, and
recommend that it be put into effect at the same time as the
recommended pay increase for the rest of the force, July I,
1970.
TRANSITION TO A VOLUNTARY MEDICAL CORPS
The transition to a voluntary medical corps will be greatly
facilitated by planned reductions in force levels. As a result of
draft pressure, many medical students have already committed
themselves to service under the various programs now in effect.
With those already committed and with prompt action on
stipends for graduate students and increased pay for military
physicians, it should be possible to eliminate the conscription of
doctors concurrently with the ending of the draft for other
military personnel.
Because of uncertainties over the extent to which
substitution of civilians will be possible, our estimates of the
budget increase required to move to a voluntary medical service
are imprecise. Given the recommended pay increase, the
fellowship program, and the cost of civilian staffed hospitals, we
estimate that an additional $150 million to ‘$200 million of
expenditures will be required.3
CHAPTER 9
RESERVES
INTRODUCTION
The Commission recognized from its first meeting the need
for special attention to the problem of the reserve forces.
Surveys indicate that perhaps 75 percent of the enlisted
personnel fulfilling their initial six-year military service
obligation in the reservcs are there only because of the draft. II
conscription is eliminated, how are these forces to be manned’?
Research directed to that question indicates that planned
resewes can be maintained on :tn all-volunteer basis at
reasonable levels of compensation. Analysis of the reserve
problem, however, suffers seriously from a lack of data. Even
though special care was taken to provide against errors of
estimation, the assessments of what is required to maintain an
all-volunteer reserve force are much more tenuous than those
for the active duty force.
U.S. reserve forces have: two primary functions: first, to
supplement the active duty forces as needed; second, to help
91
maintain domestic peace and assist in time of civil disaster. The
latter is largely the responsibility of the National Guard.
Currently. about one million officers and men in the
Ready Reserve receive pay for participating in reserve
training ~ two-thirds of them are in the Army Reserve (USAR)
and Army National Guard. More than 80 percent of the men in
the paid reserve are orguked and trained as units which are
designed to fit into the structure of the active forces. Should
these men be called to active duty, it is intended that they
perform in their respective units. The remaining 7-O percent,
about I65.000 men, un be called as individuals to augment
active forces. In addition to paid reservists. there are I .3 million
unpaid reservists in the Rudy Reserve pool who may be called
up as individuals.
DISCUSSION
In an emergency the President is authorized to cull to
active duty as many as one million Ready Reservists (IO USC
673). Reserves in the Standby and Retired categories can be
called only with the approval of Congress. Table ‘1-l shows how
reserve manpower (less mobilized strength still on active duty)
was allocated into recall categories on June 30, 1969. Table 9-11
summarizes the major units which that strength provided in FY
1969.
RESERVE FORCE REQUIREMENTS
The impact of planned reductions in active duty forces on
reserve force manning requirements is still very uncertain. Four
projected active duty forces have been analyzed. spanning the
range that is generally considered reasonable, from 2.0 million
to 3.0 million men. A similar procedure has been followed in
analyzing the reserves. We have associated a reserve force, by
service, with each of the four active alternatives. The projected
strengths shown in columns 3 and 4 of table 9-111 are based on
the relationship between active and reserve forces prior to
Vietnam.
TABLE
9-I.--Defense department resar~e forces’
June 30,1969
[thousands]
Paid drill Ready Reserve Officers Enlisted Total
30.4
32.2
19.0
2.7
10.3
10.1
104.7
19.3
124.0
96.3
103.7
323.6
649.6
356.5
229.1
113.7
46.4
73.1
34.9
855.7
37.7
693.4
1.169.0
322.2
205.0
2,609X
369.0
261.3
132.7
49.1
63.4
44.9
960.4
57.0
1 ,017.4
1,267.3
425.9
526.6
3.259.4
TABLE
9-Il.-Major reserve units
June 30,1969
Army Reserve Naval Reserve
Air Force Reserve
13 training divisions 35 destroyers and
14 wings (45 squadrons)
3 brigades destroyer escorts
6 military airlift
2 maneuver area 26 boats and craft
6 tactical airlift
commands
36 air squadrons
Army Guard
Marine Reserve Air Guard
6 divisions 1 division 21 wings (92 squadrons)
16 brigades 1 air wing
12 fighter
3 reconnaissance
2 air refueling
7 militafv airlift
There is reason to doubt, however, that there was a real
requirement for the pre-Vietnam levels of paid-drill strength.
The public record is clear that the Army was reluctant to accept
the minimum strength levels mandated by Congress. The Air
99
TABLE 9-ill.-Alfenrafive active and reser”e strength /eVe/S
[thousands]
Reserves
- Ur
Imodified Modified
enlist< ed strength
enlisted strength *
(3)
(4)
(5)
(6)
Mixed
Volunteer Mixed
Volunteer
force
force 2 force force 2
628.3 639.5 554.9 566.5
707.5 712.4
624.8 632.3
786.0 785.5
694.1 696.3
838.8 829.8
740.9 734.9
Active duty
(1)
Total
(2)
force Enlisted
level
strength
2,000 1,697.l
2,250 1,902.7
2,500 2.107.6
3,000 2,581 .l
Force was similarly pressured into higher levels than it had
requested, although the Air Force found useful work for much
of the excess strength, largely in part-time support of the active
force’s mission. The tenuous nature of the pre-Vietnam reserve
requirements is also evident from independent research
undertaken by the Commission staff, which confirms that
reorganization
of the reserve forces could eliminate
approximately 113,000 men in paid drill status (“spaces”)
without significantly affecting reserve effectiveness.
Because of these apparent overstrengths, we have prepared
a second set of alternative reserve force levels to be associated
with the four alternative active levels. This second set modifies
the first by removing from the current level I 10,000 Army and
2,800 Air Force paid-drill spaces; (16,300 officer and 96,500
enlisted spaces). Proportional modifications are made in each
representative force level and are presented as “modified” levels
in table 9-111.
These force levels are set forth here to emphasize that
shortfalls from present levels in the reserves are not a serious
threat to national security. We believe that the recommended
pay increase for the active duty component (which is
automatically effective for the reserves) will provide enough
100
reserve enlistments to meet the larger requirements in table
9-111. If that turns out not to be true, or if transitional problems
develop, reserve strength could decline moderately from the
unmodified levels in table 9-111 without posing a serious
national security problem.
RESERVE NON-PRIOR SERVICE ACCESSIONS
The critical variable in determining the feasibility of a
voluntary reserve force is the number of enlistments from
civilian life that will be required annually. That number depends
on: (I) annual reserve losses (which depend on the reserve
Fe-enlistment rate), and (2) annual prior service enlistments
(those who join the reserves after active duty). Columns 3 and 5
of table 9-IV show estimates of the number of civilian
enlistments required annually to maintain each of the forces
shown in columns 2 and 4 on a stable basis.
TABLE WV.-Annual civilian enlistments required for
volunteer resewe alternatives 1
[thousands]
Active Unmodified Civilian Modified Civilian
force enlisted enlistments enlisted
enlistments
level strength 1 required strength required
2,000 639.5 90.0 566.5 76.2
2,250 712.4 97.2 632.3 81.6
2,500 785.5 106.2 698.3 88.6
3,000 629.6 102.6 734.9 84.0
1 Re.e”,,stmentl are e*tlm.ted to be 13 percent Of ,orce strength: prior llervice enllstmenls
“my Wilh BC,,W ,OlSBI. ThB der,YatIo” 0, me*e estimates is dexlibed beIoW.
For comparison, the annual number of civilian enlistments
in the reserves (excluding the “2 x 6” program) averaged
122,000 during the last eight years.
THE SUPPLY OF RESERVE MANPOWER
Like the active forces, the paid drill reserve contains a
mixture of true volunteers and men who serve chiefly or solely
to discharge the military service obligation imposed by law. The
proportion of men who willingly undertake regular drill training
is strikingly different for officers than for enlisted men.
According to a 1969 Defense Department survey of reserve
101
pcrsonncl, X0 pcrccnl d 0lTiwrs drill volut~l;~rily. hot wly 27
pcrccnt or cnlistcd nwn do. I:or lhis rws011. our ;Inxlysis hx
focused on the cnlistcd scgmcnt 01’ a11 ;III-~~I~IIII~~~ rcww
force.
The prospect ot’ securing volunlccrs l’or ~cscrvc scrviw is
surely rclatcd to pay Icvcls. All too ol’tcn it is said that drill pay
is nearly irrelevant to ;I young man deciding whcthcr III tlcvolc
I‘ree time to unit activity. Yet ;~lmost one-third 01‘ mcu will1 less
than six years ol‘ scrvicc dcsuihc drill pay as one or the n~ost
significant fuctors in their dwision.
A typical reservist ;~ttends 4X training ;~sscmhlics lwx year.
Each assembly lasts four hours (:I small pcrccnt;~gc only three)
and assemblies are usually “multiple”: two on S;~turtlay. or l.our
on a weekend. On avcragc. the typical rcscrvist dcvotcs one I’ull
weekend each month to unit training and Irains for two weeks
on active duty each year. llis total investment ol’ time is 3 I2
hours. Counting basic pay alone. he earns 5642 ;I year if he is an
E4 (corporal) with four years ol‘ service (about $580 iC hc has
three years of service).
This is not a large amount compared to total family
earnings: median income for an E4 falls in the %7,000-SX.000
range. But the more meaningful economic comparison is with
part-time employment alternatives. Two-thirds of the E4’s are
married and more than half of them have working wives.
Two-thirds of the E4’s are 21-25 years old; and more than
one-third have children. The typical E4, in other words. closely
resembles the Department of Labor’s portrait of the typical
multiple job holder ~ “a comparatively young married man
with children who feels a financial squeeze.” According to the
Bureau of Labor Statistics, in May 1966, 5% percent of‘ 20-24
year-old working men held multiple jobs. They worked a
median I4 hours on their second job. In a full S2-week year,
they would work 728 extra hours.
For men who are interested in extra income, reserve
activity does not offer the earnings potential of part-time
civilian work because it is too infrequent. For some men it
could become an attractive alternative as a second job. Certainly
a necessary if not sufficient condition for voluntary reserve
participation is a level of drill pay attractive enough to make
military instruction preferable to other part-time activities.
While the pay level in the early years of service has been too low
to attract voluntarily the high quality of recruits which the
102
reserves have enjoyed over the past ten years, our studies show
that a more reasonable qualitative mix can be obtained
voluntarily.
Drill pay is now directly linked to active duty basic pay.
The present pay schedule is given in table 9-U. In one drill
period (usually four hours), a reservist earns an amount equal to
a full day’s pay for his regular service counterpart. His starting
level, if he enlists directly from civilian life, is about $1 .OO per
hour. (The federal minimum wage is $ I .60 per hour.) A man,
who has served four years with the regular forces and has
reached the ES (sergeant) pay grade, can earn $2.75 per hour at
drill training. At the career end of the scale, the rates are quite
attractive. A First Sergeant with over 16 years of service earns
$5.00
per hour.2
Our pay recommendations will increase these hourly rates
significantly in the lower grades. In his first year of service, a
recruit will earn $2.00~$2.50 per hour, approaching the pay that
a sergeant now receives. Drill pay will be increased above the
amount needed to maintain its present relation to civilian wages
as shown in table 9-V.
TABLE 9-V.-Drill-pay increase
by length of service
Years of service
Percent
O-l
69.6
l-2
64.4
2-3 23.7
3-4
19.5
4-5 8.3
5-6 7.9
6-7 4.9
7-8 7.2
6-10 5.0
In addition to basic pay, certain special and incentive
compensation, such as flying pay and parachute pay, is paid to
those on inactive duty at the daily active rate. While on active
duty, the reservist receives the same pay as the regular.
Occupational differentials, such as proficiency pay and the
variable reenlistment bonus, are not paid to reservists on either
active or inactive duty.
TABLE 9-W-Pay rates per training assembly (dollars)
[ettective July 1, 19691
010
09
08~~~ 48.44 49.69 51.07 51.07 51.07 54.88 54.68 57.47 57.47 59.85 62.47 64.85 67.46 67.46
07 ~~~ 40.24 42.99 42.99 42.99 44.90 44.90 47.50 47.50 49.89 54.80 58.66 58.66 58.66 58.66
$j 06 29.81 32.77 34.91 34.91 34.91 34.91 34.91 34.91 36.11 41.80 43.94 44.90 47.50 51.53
05 23.84 28.02 29.94 29.94 29.94 29.94 30.87 32.51 34.69 35.04 39.43 40.61 42.04
04 ~~~ ~~~ 20.12 24.47 26.13 26.13 26.59 27.78 29.68 31.34 31.42 34.20 35.16
03 ~~~~~ 18.70 20.89 22.31 24.71 25.88 26.83 28.27 29.66 30.40
02 ~~~~~~~ ~~~~~~ ~~~ 14.98 17.80 21.38 22.09 22.55
01 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 12.88 14.25 17.80
03' ~~~~~~~~ ~~~~~~~ 24.71 25.08 26.83 28.27 29.68 30.87
02' ~~~~~~~~ ~~~~ 22.09 22.55 23.27 24.47 25.42 26.13
01 -
.~~~~~~~~~~~~.~
17.80 19.00 19.71 20.42 21.13 22.09
w4 ~~~~~ ~~~~~~~~ 19.04 20.42 20.42 20.89 21.84 22.80 23.74 25.42 26.55 27.55 28.27 29.20 30.17 32.51
Footnotes are found at the en* Of fix table.
TABLE 9-W-Pay ratespertraining assembly (dollarsJ.-Continued
[effective July 1, 1969)
Pay
grade
w3
Yearsin pay grade
Under Over Over Over Over Over Over Over Over Over Over Over Over Over
2
2 3 4 6 8 10
12 14 16 18 20 22
26
17.30 18.78 18.78 19.00 19.24 20.65 21.84
22.55 23.27 23.97 24.71 25.66 26.59 27.55
w2 .~
.~~~~
15.15 16.39
16.39 16.86
17.80
18.78 19.49 20.18 20.80 21.61 22.31 23.02 23.97
Wl
12.63 14.49 14.49 15.68 16.39
17.10
17.80
18.53 19.24 19.95 20.65 21.38
E9 ~~~~~~ ~.~
..~~.~~~~~
21.63 22.12
22.64 23.13 23.64 24.11 25.39 27.85
;;
VI E8 ~~~~~~~~~~
~~~~~~~~~~~ 18.15 18.65 19.15 19.65 20.15 20.63 21.14 22.39
24.88
E7 ~~~~~~~~~~
~~~~~~~~~~~
11.40 13.66
14.17 14.68
15.17
15.66 16.15 16.67 17.41 17.91 18.41 18.65 19.90 22.39
E6
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
9.82 11.93
12.43 12.93
13.44
13.92 14.43 15.17 15.66 16.15 16.41
E5 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 8.49 10.46
10.95 11.44 12.19 12.69 13.18 13.66 13.92
E4
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.~ 7.13 8.95 8.44 10.19 10.69
E3
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
5.16 7.20
7.71 8.20
E2 ~~~~~~~~~~.~~~~~~~~ 4.25 5.96
El ~~~~~~~ .~~~~~.~.~~~~~ 4.10 5.46
El <4 mos. 3.83
Reservists are also entitled to pensions. Full retirement
credit is given for years served on active duty; partial credit is
given for years on inactive service. Retired pay is contingent
upon completion of twenty creditable years of service and
begins at age 60, at the pay scale then in effect.
Proposals are advanced from time to time to permit
payment of retired pay at age 50. If this were done and benefits
were not reduced, the cost of the retirement benefit would
double. Since retirement pay has little attraction for young men
whose primary job is in the civilian sector, this added
expenditure would do little to solve the recruitment problems
of the reserves.
Currently, about 850,000 enlisted men are in paid-drill
reserve status. If men temporarily called to active duty are
included, the paid-drill total averaged 836,000 over the eight
years prior to June, 1969. To maintain this level the reserves
have required an average annual inflow of 262,000 men. Of
these, 153,000 ~ nearly 60 percent - were men who entered
directly from civil life? The remaining 109,000 were personnel
with prior service.
Three sources of manpower are available to an
all-volunteer paid drill reserve:
I. Reenlistments - new commitments by those already
in the reserves. Re-enlistments affect losses and
thereby the level of accessions required to maintain a
given force;
2. Prior service enlistments - enlistments by those who
have been on active duty; and
3. Civilian enlistments ~ first enlistments by civilians.
RE-ENLISTMENTS
Reserve re-enlistments are a primary factor in determining
the number of new accessions required each year. Reenlistment
rates may be expressed as a proportion of average strength.
Measured in this way, reenlistment rates during the FY
1962-69 period are shown in table 9-VII.
These data imply that if the re-enlistment propensities of
the FY 1962-65 period could be re-established, a 20 percent
improvement (from 1.2 percent to 8.6 percent) in
TABLE 9-VII.-Paid-drill sfrengfh, re-enlistmenls. and
re-enlistment rates
[FY 7962-69 [thousands]
FY Strength R-enlistments Rate (percent)
1962 651.6 54.3
6.4
1963 620.3 59.5
7.3
1964
799.7 66.3 11.0
1965
818.7 61.1 9.9
1966 633.5 ‘80.9
9.7
1967
663.2 ‘66.4 7.9
1966
656.4 ‘51.5 6.0
1969 656.7 ‘43.3
5.1
1962-65~ 3,290.3 263.2
6.6
1966-69~ 3.409.8 244.1
7.2
,.~
f lnCl”deS BStimated 1.9 for Marine Cores.
The conventional and more useful way of analyzing
re-enlistment rates is to examine the proportions of separating
men who continue in service at a series of “decision points”
along the career path. Because actual rates are not wailable. we
used statements of continuation intentions provided by the
1969 attitude survey to approximate them. Table 9-VIII
displays re-enlistment intentions classified by length of service
and by obligated and voluntary drill categories. As one would
expect, interest in drill participation is higher in the voluntary
category; and it is markedly higher after the sixth year of
service.
What would have been the affect on reenlistments if the
1969 reserves had been composed entirely of volunteers? Using
reenlistment intentions as proxies for reenlistment rates, we
have estimated that “conversion” to a volunteer force would
have added nearly 33,000 reenlistments, an increase of
three-fourths over the number who actually did re-enlist in FY
1969. The reenlistment rate, expressed as a percentage of
‘average strength, would have improved from 5.1 to 8.8 percent.
(About half of this estimated gain occurred in the under-6 year
portion of the force, where the conventional re-enlistment
rate -
percent of men separating - rose from 6 percent, in
the mixed force, to 16 percent in the all-volunteer force.)
This comparison suggests that a shift to voluntarism would
raise the 7.2 percent reenlistment rate of recent years to 12.7
percent of average strength. The best reenlistment experience
in the eight years examined was FY 1964, when 88,000
re-enlistments equalled 11 percent of a mixed
volunteer/obligated force. Given the striking differences in
reenlistment attitudes between volunteers and non-volunteers,
the estimate that a voluntary force will attain reenlistments at
that level seems quite conservative.
One might assume an additional increase resulting from
reestablishment of the pre-1965 environment. If this were the
case, the reenlistment rate would become 15.2 percent of
average strength. We did not make that assumption; because the
earlier force included a larger proportion of volunteers and the
shift to voluntarism was, thus, already partly taken into
account.
We then estimated the effect which our proposed pay
increases would have on reenlistment behavior. Survey
responses indicate that modest increases in reenlistment will
occur. Higher pay will induce proportionately more
reenlistmenrs among men who now have the lowest inclination
to continue in reserve service. For instance, our studies show
that among those persons required to drill with from four to
six-years of service, a pay increase of 10 percent would be likely
to increase the reenlistment rate from 3.6 to 4.3 percent, an
increase of 20 percent. Reenlistment rates for those who drill
voluntarily would rise from 15.2 to 16.4 percent, only an 8
108
percent improvement. Volunteers with six-to- ten years of
service now tend to reenlist at very high rates - 50.7 percent
according to survey statements. A 10 percent increase in their
pay would raise their re-enlistment rate to 52.3 percent, a 3
percent improvement.
We propose to increase enlisted drill pay 6 percent after
the sixth year of service, when most decisions to continue in the
reserves are made. This increase will have both immediate and
longer-term effects on re-enlistments. The immediate result will
be to provide a moderate rise in reenlistments of those in the
first six years of service. Such men now usually leave the
reserves, but they are more responsive to pay changes than their
older colleagues. As volunteer enlistees gradually replace
draft-motivated men over the six years following conversion to
an all-volunteer force, reenlistment rates will improve at
accelerating rates until a higher stable rate is reached. Our
calculations indicate that, in an “all-volunteer” 1969 reserve,
re-enlistments as a percent of strength would have risen from
8.8 percent (after conversion) to 9.1 percent (after the pay
rise); and half of this gain would be realized in the under-six
year component of the force.
The recommended pay increase should improve the
position of reserve drill duty vis-a-vis other part-time
employment opportunities. If relative pay is maintained at the
recommended level in an all-volunteer situation, we estimate
that the combined effect of moving to a volunteer system and
increasing pay will increase the re-enlistment rate from the
current 7.2 percent to 13 percent, an improvement of 80
percent.
PRIOR SERVICE ENLISTMENTS
The man who separates from active service is a highly
prized candidate for service in a reserve unit. He has had two or
more years of training and experience which qualify him not
only for immediate assignment to fill a unit vacancy, but often
for a leadership role as well. Under present rules, geography
prevents full exploitation of this enlistment potential. Unless a
unit with a vacancy matching his grade and skill qualification is
convenient to his home and regular occupation, a veteran is
unable to participate. Because unit assignment specifies
location, many prior-service enlistments have been lost.
109
In the eight years spanning FY 1962-69, 4.8 million men
left active service. The reserve components recruited fewer than
900,000 of them into paid drill status. That total includes
substantial numbers who were obligated to join, some through
training “pay-back” agreements entered into during their active
service, but more through involuntary assignment (in the Army
Reserve) to achieve programmed strength levels. The number of
enlistments would have been still smaller had not the Navy
assigned a large fraction of reservists to paid-drill, individual
mobilization billets rather than to actual crews. Nearly 80
percent of paid-drill Naval reservists attend regular training
sessions during the year and report to a crew assignment for
two-week summer training. The Navy’s experience demonstrates
that it is not necessary to forfeit reserve enlistments because of
the self-imposed limitations of unit structure.
Prior-service recruitment experience between FY 1962 and
1969 deteriorated sharply except in the Navy, where the “2x6”
program provided a degree of stability. The drop was sharpest in
the Army components, especially the USAR, whose recruitment
rate fell from nearly 23 percent in the first four years to 6
percent in the last four. This decline is attributable chiefly to
wartime and the accompanying sharp rise in the number of
inductees separated: 70 percent of 1960-67 inductions were
released in the 1966-69 period. Another factor depressing
USAR recruitment was a ruling by the Defense Department in
June 1967 that involuntary assignments into paid-drill units
were to be used only if programmed strength could not
otherwise be attained.
Since the 1962-65 period approximates a non-war
recruiting situation, we have chosen that period as the basis for
estimates of enlistments in a post- Vietnam environment. As a
matter of policy, the reserves accepted prior-service men only
on a voluntary basis during that period, except the USAR. Even
sb, survey responses in 1964 show that fractions of the men in
the other components also regarded their service as involuntary.
These responses may be only the results of retrospection, but
they suggest that estimates of potential recruits ought to be
discounted for involuntary assignment in all components. The
adjusted rate is the number of enlistments multiplied by the
fraction who volunteered, the product then divided by the
number of separations from the parent service. Table 9-1X
presents the unadjusted and voluntary (or adjusted) rates which
II0
we applied to projected active separations in order to estimate
reserve gains from that source. The high level of voluntarism in
the National Guard, and to somewhat lesser degree in the Navy,
is striking.
TABLE
94X.-Percenf of active separations
enlisting in
reesewe components
[FY 1962-L%]
Voluntary
proportion
,944
,257
,811
,404
,943
,601
Vol”“tar;
enlistment
rate
8.0
5.9
25.5
4.1
4.4
3.6
Projected losses from the 2.5 million all-volunteer force are
342,300 in the 1977-79 period which would provide 47,800
prior service enlistments for the reserves. Projected losses from
the 2.25 million all-volunteer force of,the 1977-79 period are
302,500. We estimate that the reserves will be able to recruit
about 42,400 of them.
Substantially higher gains can be expected during the early
years of transition to a” all-volunteer force owing to high
separations from the active force. For instance, active
separations from a 197 I all-volunteer force are predicted to be
665,000. We estimate that the reserves could voluntarily enlist
92,000, or nearly double the number expected after the active
force is stabilized at 2.5 million. Table 9-X consolidates active
separations and projected gains into the reserves.
CIVILIAN ENLISTMENTS
In the presence of the draft, reserve service has provided a”
attractive opportunity for young me” to minimize the personal
cost of fulfilling their military obligation. Indeed, it has come to
be preferred by so many that queues of prospective enlistees
have formed which at times are longer than the entire annual
flow of enlistments. The reserves, unable to accept all
111
TABLE %X.-Projected active separations and paid drill gains, all-volunteer
active and reserve tomes, selected years
[thousands]
Component
Fate
(percent)
Average
1971 1972 1973
1977-79
Sep. Gains Sep.
Gains Sep. Gains
Sep. Gains
2.5 million active force
Army National Guard ~~~~~~~~ 6.0
32.5 25.8 23.7 11.9
Army Reserve ~~~..~~~~..~~..~~ 5.9 406 23.9
I
322
19.0
296
17.5
I
146
a.7
2.25 million active force
Army National Guard ..~..~~. 6.0
32.5 25.6 23.7
121
9.7
Arm” Reserve 5.9
406
23.9
322
19.0
296
17.5
I
7.2 ..~,..~~.~~~~~~~~~~~~~
applicants. have exercised a high degree of selectivity. Table
9-X1 compares the educational attainment of reserve and active
duty personnel. In 1969. 94 percent of the paid drill reservists
had completed high school. over one-h;df had attended college,
and I h percent had been granted college degrees. This is a much
higher level of educational attainment than for the active duty
force. Only I.6 percent of paid-drill reservists were Negro, as
compared to IO.5 percent in the active forces. At the same time
fewer than 5 percent of paid drill reservists. but I5 percent of
active duty enlisted men. were under the age of twenty. Table
9-X11 compares reserve and active distribution by age.
TABLE
3-XI.-Educational attainment of enlisted men-FY 1969
[cumulative percent]
Paid drill reserves Active duty
-..
College graduates ~~~ 16.1
2.2
Some college .~ ~~~~~ ~~~~
54.4 21.5
High school graduates 93.9
62.7
TABLE
%X11.-Age of enlistedmen-FY 1969
[cumulative
percent]
Paid drill reserves Active duty
Under 19 .~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.~.~
1.2
5.6
Under 20 ~~~ .~ ~~~~~
4.6 15.2
Under 22 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
19.1
47.8
Under 24 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
40.9 66.9
Under 26 ~~~~~~~~~~ ~~.,
62.2 75.0
Men of this age and educational level are almost certain to
have little real interest in reserve service. The 1969 survey found
that three-fourths of the paid-drill reservists serving their initial
six-year obligation entered military service because of the draft.
Five years earlier the proportion was two-thirds. (Among 17-2 I
year olds in the I969 survey. the proportion was 55 percent.)
Evidence of strong draft motivation among reservists has
been interpreted to mean that a voluntary system will not work.
These draft motivation data. however. significantly overstate
the magnitude of the problem. As table O-XIII shows, draft
motivation is~strongly related to education and age: the younger
and less educated the reservist, the lower the draft motivation.
113
TABLE 9-XIII.-Percenf draft motivated by education attained
and by age, fiscal years 1964 and 1969
Educational attainment
1964 1969
College graduate ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~..~~..~~.. ~~~~ 90
91
2-4 years’ college ~~~.~~~...~..~~.~~~~~~~ 77
a3
Under 2 years’ college ......~.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 60
73
High school graduate ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~..~. 43
70
Less than high school graduate ~~~~~~~~ 24
64
Age
21 ~~. ..~~~.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.~.~..~... 63
65
20 ~~~~~~~ ..~~~..~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 70
76
19 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~...~.. .~ ..~~...~~.~~~~~~~~~~~ 55
78
16 ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.~~~.....,,. .~~~.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 41
65
Under la .~. ~~~~.~~...~~~~~~.~~~...~.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ 26
54
If recruitment is focused on a younger, less well-educated
group; the flow of volunteers will be substantially larger than is
implied by the draft motivation of the present force.
In estimating the number of civilian men who can be
recruited for reserve service, we have noted the large waiting
lists for reserve vacancies. These lists were built up because the
ability of the services to accept reserve enlistments has been
limited by their budgets and by the capability of the active
forces to provide initial training. At the same time, the services’
needs for new enlistments are governed by losses which follow a
complex cyclical pattern ,,
with crises such as Berlin influencing
losses in later years. The size of the queues has fluctuated as
capacity and needs varied, and it has not been possible to
estimate satisfactorily the additional number of volunteers who
might have been recruited if enlistments had been unlimited.
Table 9-XIV shows the size of waiting lists annually since 1965
(the first year for which data are available) and the number of
enlistments which occurred in the corresponding fiscal year.
While our estimates do not use data on the queue
explicitly, we have used the existence of the queues to justify
basing our estimates on recruitment in a high, pre-war
year - 1964.
As shown above, educational attainments and mental
qualifications have been inflated in the reserves under the
pressure of the draft. The reserves do not require such an
114
TABLE 9-XIV.-Numbers of men awaiting reserve enlistment
on January 1st and numbers enlisted, FY 1965-69
[thousands]
1965 1966 1967 1966 1969 1970
Waiting ~~~ 236.9 153.2 272.2 125.2
61.9 146.2
Enlisted (REP) 117.9 204.7 96.3
61.9 112.7 xx
educationally rich
force. Peacetime recruits should come
predominantly from among high school graduates and not from
those with some college experience. According to the 1964
survey: 43 percent of the high school graduates in their first
term of reserve service were draft-motivated w&tees; 55
percent of those 17-21 in the first term were draft motivated;
67 percent of those 17-24 were draft motivated; and 70 percent
of the last-named group, excluding the “2 x 6” program, were
draft-motivated. Even though that group contained far more
college men than is desirable for good retention, we have used a
draft motivation factor of 70 percent in projecting enlistments.
In 1964, 175,000 men enlisted from civil life. If 30 percent
were true volunteers, the true volunteers represented 0.7
percent of the 17-2 I year old pool. For our projections we have
assumed that at current levels of relative military/civilian pay.
civilian reserve enlistments each year would be 0.7 percent of
the 17-2 1 year pool. Our estimates take no account of the fact
that entry-level drill pay rose substantially more than earnings
of civilian production
workers
in the five years following 1964,
and therefore err on the conservative side.
We have no data from which to estimate the results of pay
increases on reserve enlistments. Our analyses of the problem of
recruiting into the active forces indicate that a pay increase of
one percent will produce a 1.25 percent increase in enlistment
rates; our estimates of reserve reenlistments suggest that a one
percent pay increase will generate only 0.8 percent
improvement in re-enlistments. Table 9-XV portrays projected
enlistments under each of these assumptions and at an
intermediate value.
SUMMARY
Table 9-XVI shows required reserve force strengths and
enlistments for stable forces corresponding to the 2.5 and 2.25
million man active forces. Table 9-XVI also shows three
TABLE !+XVI.-Reserve strengths and required and projected
civilian enlistments.’ FY 1977
Active Volunteer Required Modified
force res?rve enlistments reserve
2,250
712 97 632
2,500
766 106 696
Projected enlistments
(1) 99
(2) 107
(3) 117
Required
enlistments
62
69
projections of voluntary enlistments for the reserve forces. The
projected enlistments appear to be adequate for the reserve
forces associated with the 2.25 million force and 2.5 million
man active forces. Given the uncertainty which surrounds
projections of reserve enlistments and losses, however, further
116
steps beyond the recommended pay increase may be necessary.
Any further steps should await the results of experience with
higher pav during the next few years.
In that transition period, recruiting potential for the
reserves will be substantially enhanced by the large flow of
servicemen being separated now. Prior service enlistments, as we
saw in table 9-X, are expected to be significantly higher in the
197 I-73 period than they will later be for the stabilized force.
As a result, the requirement for civilian enlistments will be well
within recruiting capabilities in the early years.
This can be seen in FY 1972, for example, when extremely
high losses are expected. The currently planned reserve enlisted
strength for FY 1971 is 865,000 in the paid-drill category. That
strength is higher than the largest force level considered in our
analysis, but our study indicates that even that level could be
maintained in FY 1972 with volunteers. The re-enlistment rate
is expected to reach 9.2 percent by that year, so
that
an
estimated 79,600 men would re-enlist. Prior-service gains would
number 8 1,800. Losses are estimated at 243.000. To maintain
level strength
would therefore require 8 1,600 civilian
enlistments (losses less re-enlistments and prior service gains).
Using the most conservative evaluation of the effects of the
proposed pay increase, we have estimated that 90,300 civilians
can be persuaded to enlist.
117
CHAPTER 10
THE STANDBY DRAFT
Heeding its directive, the Commission has considered
“what standby machinery for the draft will be required in the
event of a national emergency.” The Commission recommends
that legislation be enacted to provide. once an all-volunteer
force is in effect:
I. A register of all males who might be conscripted
when essential for national security.
2. A system for selection of inductees.
3. Specific procedures for the notification. examination
and induction of those to be conscripted.
4. An organization to maintain the register and
administer the procedures for induction.
5. That a standby draft system can be invoked only by
resolution of Congress at the request of the President.
Because there have been several recent studies of the
operation of the Selective Service System. we have uot
119
undertaken
a re-examination of that subject. Instead, we have
formulated our recommendations for standby draft machinery
in fairly general terms. which would be consistent with a wide
range of specific systems.
Clearly the task of creating and maintaining a state of
military preparedness capable of dealing with threats to the
nation’s security is a vital one. The nation’s military readiness is
both actual and potential: active duty personnel are prepared to
act instantaneously; able-bodied but untrained and unorganized
civilian males are potential servicemen. This spectrum of
manpower can be divided into three groups in descending order
of their state of readiness: (1) active duty personnel, (2)
reserves. and (3) civilians. In planning standby draft machinery,
it is important to recognize that conscription is relevant only to
the civilian population.
The rationale for providing a standby draft is the possible
urgent need for the nation to act quickly. It is clear, however,
that a standby draft will not supply effective military forces in
being. All it can provide is a basis for acquiring eligible
manpower who must be trained, organized and equipped.
Effective forces can be available only
to
the extent that men are
organized, trained and equipped prior to an emergency. Under
current military policy, should a crisis arise, it is the function of
the Reserves to provide the first stage in the expansion of
effective forces. They are organized and at least partly trained
and equipped; hence they can be operationally ready in a
shorter time than new forces. The function of a standby draft is
to provide manpower resources for the second stage of
expansion in effective forces.
Much thought lies behind the recommendation that
Congressional approval be required to invoke conscription. An
important issue of national policy is obviously involved. The
alternative is to endow the Office of the President with the
independent power to call for activation of the standby
machinery. This has been rejected for several reasons.
Conscription should be used only when the size of forces
required for the security of the nation cannot be supplied by
the existing system. If Congressional approval is made a
prerequisite to the use of conscription, the necessity for
legislative action will guarantee public discussion of the
propriety of whatever action is under consideration. If
discussion yields a reasonable consensus, the nation’s resolve
120
will be clearly demonstrated and made less vulnerable to
subsequent erosion. If a consensus sufficient to induce Congress
to activate the draft cannot be mustered, the President would
see the depth of national division
before,
rather than after,
committing U.S. military power.
A standby system which authorizes the President to invoke
the draft at his discretion would capture the worst of two
worlds. On the one hand, it would make it possible for the
President to become involved in military actions with a
minimum of public debate and popular support. On the other
hand, once the nation was involved, especially in a prolonged
limited conflict, the inequities of the draft would provide a
convenient rallying point for opposition to the policy being
pursued.
It is important to emphasize that Congress has not been
reluctant to enact a draft when the President has requested it.
In the first World War, the United States declared war on April
I, 1917, the draft law was requested by President Wilson on
April 7, and it was signed into law on May 18. Prior to World
War II a draft bill was introduced into Congress on June 20,
1940, endorsed by the President on August 2, passed on
September 14, and signed into law September 16. When the
Korean War broke out on June 24, 1950, debate on extension
of the selective service law had been underway for some
months. Congress promptly discontinued debate and extended
the law for one year on July 9.
Because of the loss of personal freedom and the inequities
inherent in conscription, the draft should be resorted to only in
extreme situations. If the Office of the President has the power
to use the draft, there will be pressures to do so when
circumstances do not warrant it. The viability of an
all-volunteer force ultimately depends upon the willingness of
Congress, the President, the Department of Defense and the
military services to maintain (1) competitive levels of military
compensation, (2) reasonable qualification standards, and
(3) attractive conditions of military service. Under foreseeable
circumstances, such as serious budget constraints, there is a
danger that inaction by one or another of these parties might
force the President to resort to conscription when it is not
*Cllly necessary. If Congressional approval is made a
prerequisite to use of the draft, the danger of using it
unnecesarily or by default will be much reduced.
121
One of the fundamental principles embodied in the
Constitution is that taxes are to be levied only by Congress.
Since conscription is a form of taxation, the power to conscript
is the power to tax. Therefore, it is in keeping with the intent of
the Constitution to require Congressional approval for the
activation of the standby draft.
Finally, requiring Congressional approval for activation of
a standby draft will have little or no effect on the time required
for the nation to bring effective military power to bear when
needed. To repeat: conscription does not provide the nation
with military forces in being. Effective flexibility in response to
crisis can be achieved only to the extent that forces are already
partly or wholly organized, trained and equipped. The draft is a
vehicle for supplying men for gradual expansion, not for
meeting sudden challenges. This has been true, for example, in
Vietnam. Under our standby proposal, the delay introduced in
expanding the forces with conscripts cannot exceed the time it
takes for Congress to act. In practice the time lost will be even
less: preparations for organizing, training and equipping recruits
can proceed simultaneously with Congressional action.
MAXIMUM SIZE OF AN ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCE.
No estimate has been attempted of the maximum size of a
force that could be provided on a voluntary basis. When it is
posed in this general form, the question of maximum size is not
a meanmgful one. The number of individuals who will serve
voluntarily depends on a variety of factors, more or less subject
to control, which change over time. One factor is the specific
set of circumstances which dictate the expansion of forces.
When the threat to national security is clearly serious, as it was
after Pearl Harbor, volunteers will be plentiful. For a limited
conflict in a distant and alien land, there will be less enthusiasm.
Willingness to volunteer also depends on the character and
terms of military service, on casualty rates, and on the public
esteem such service enjoys. Most importantly, the flow of
volunteers depends upon the level of military compensation.
Pay is important because it leads to more relevant
questions regarding the size of the voluntary force which can be
sustained. Other things being equal, if it is indeed true that
higher military compensation will result in more enlistments,
the question of the maximum size of a volunteer force becomes
one of how high the level of military compensation should be.
Ultimately, each of us faces the question: how heavily are we
willing to tax ourselves to pay for a volunteer force? The
question of the maximum size of a volunteer military force is at
bottom political and not economic. Conscription cannot
produce more manpower than already exists. The constraint is
political, and it is imposed by the reluctance of voters generally
to incur higher taxes even though they want forces large enough
to guarantee their security.
Whatever the ultimate limitations on the size of a
voluntary force, some relatively large forces have been
assembled on such a basis ~ for example, the Union forces in
the Civil War. By the middle of 1862, the North, without
conscription, had raised a force of approximately 670,000 men,
the vast majority of whom had made three year commitments.
This was 15 percent of the estimated male population, age 18 to
39, of the Union States. During World War I, Great Britain
rekd on volunteers until 1916. By that time, England had
raised an active duty force of nearly 2.7 million men, or 35
percent of her age 18 to 40 male population cohort.
Such examples are by no means conclusive, but they do
suggest that conscription is not necessarily required for conflicts
comparable in scale to those the United States has fought since
World War 11. The maximum active duty force levels reached
during the Korean and Vietnamese Wars were 3.7 million and
3.6 million respectively. The Korean War force represented 15
percent of the male population age 18 to 39 in 1952, and the
Vietnam War force represented 12.4 percent of the male
population age 18 to 39 in 1968. In prosecuting those wars with
conscripts, the nation imposed a heavy tax on a small segment
of the population. In all, 5.8 million men saw service during the
Korean War and 6.0 million during the Vietnam War. In neither
case was a serious attempt made to expand the forces with
volunteers, and in the Vietnam War little use was made of the
Reserves.
Historically, whenever conscription has been used, military
pay has fallen further behind comparable civilian earnings and,
as a result, enlistments have inevitably been discouraged. The
more conscription is used, the less incentive there is to maintain
military pay (especially for those in the lower ranks) at levels
sufficient to attract volunteers. This inverse correlation between
conscription and military pay (and therefore volunteerism) is
123
illustrated by the data in table IO-1 which compares military
pay and allowances to manufacturing earnings at different dates
in our history.
In the future, serious consideration should be given to
steps which would facilitate the expansion of forces through
voluntary means before invoking conscription. In particular
whenever expansion of forces is required to meet a limited
emergency, Congress and the President should give serious
consideration to enacting significant permanent or temporary
increases in military compensation.
TABLE l&l.-Comparison of annual military enlisted earnings with
average annual earnings in manufacturing
Manufac-
Percent
wring Of forces
earnings ? Ratio
drafted
$ 410 1.041 2
394
1.127 0
980 .aaa 59
2,469 ,643 61
3.721
,694 27
124
CHAPTER 11
BUDGETARY IMPLICATIONS
A major share of our research has been devoted to
estimating the budgrt increases that will be required to sustain
an all-volunteer force. The results of that effort are summarized
in tables I I-I and I l-11.
Table 1 I-I presents our estimates of the additional
expenditures that will be required to put our recommendations
into effect in FY 197 I
Each of these sources of increased budget expenditures is
discussed elsewhere in this report.
Table 1 I-II summarizes the average budget increases
required to sustain all-volunteer forces with the same effective
strengths as the 2.0, 2.25, 2.5, and 3.0 million man mixed
forces for FY 1977 through FY 1979. We have chosen the
period 1977 through 1979 as fairly representing the differences
in budget requirements for the mixed and all-volunteer forces,
because at that time accession requirements will have stabilized,
and most of the savings resulting from an all-volunteer force will
have taken effect. All of the comparisons are made in constant
125
TABLE 11-L-Additional
budget expenditures for all-volunteer force
FY 1971
[billions]
TABLE 1
l-Il.-Additional budget expenditures for
all-volunteer
force
FY 1977-79 average
[billions]
1970 dollars; that is, there is no allowance for inflation. The
pay profiles used to compute total pay and allowances are those
set forth in chapter 5. For all of the mixed forces, we have used
the estimated pay for FY 1970, which includes an
across-the-board increase of 8 percent. For the 2.0, 2.25, and
126
127
CHAPTER 12
OBJECTIONS TO AN
ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCE
Critics argue that elimination of the draft will adversely
affect our society or our armed forces. Their main objections
are: (I) an all-volunteer force will become isolated from society
and threaten civilian control; (2) isolation and alienation will
erode civilian respect for the military and hence dilute its
quality; (3) an all-volunteer force will be all-black or dominated
by servicemen from low-income backgrounds; (4) an
all-volunteer force will lead to a decline in patriotism or in
popular concern about foreign policy; (5) an all-volunteer force
will encourage military adventurism.
There are several compelling reasons why an all-volunteer
force will not have the dire consequences some predict.
First, an all-volunteer armed force will not affect the
institutional framework within which the Department of
Defense and the military services now operate. The system of
manpower recruitment is only it small part of that framework.
An all-volunteer force does not impinge on the constitutional
roles of the President, who will remain Commander-inChief; or
129
the civilian service secretaries, who will remain responsible to
him; or Congress, which will continue as an independent
legislative and budgetary overseer. The change from a mixed
volunteer/conscript force to an all-volunteer force maintains
intact the legal structures that define the role and status of the
military services.
Second, this structure rests on deeply rooted and widely
held values. Americans firmly believe in a clearly defined and
limited military role, a belief derived from the Anglo-American
heritage of individual freedom and democratic political
processes. Defense of personal rights and liberties against all
threats, foreign and domestic, has been a constant theme in
English and American history. The English established
parliamentary control over the military through the Glorious
Revolution in 1688. The authors of the United States
Constitution recognized that military forces were necessary, but
they carefully circumscribed their role. They provided that the
President be the Commander-inChief of the forces and gave the
Congress the power to raise and support armies. Civilian control
of the military has concerned every generation of Americans
since I776 and this concern remains high today.
In 1940, when peacetime conscription was first proposed
in the United States, Senator Vandenburg reminded the Senate
of these long-held attitudes and traditions:
“I am opposed to tearing up one hundred and fifty years of
American history and tradition, in which none but volunteers
have
entered the peacetime Armies and Navies of the United
States, unless there is valid reason to believe that this reliance
in 1940 has become a broken reed for the first time in a
century and a half.
“There must have been sound reasons all down the years why
our predecessors in the Congress always consistently and
relentlessly shunned this thing which we are now asked to do.
These reasons must have been related in some indispensable
fashion to the fundamental theory that peacetime military
conscription is repugnant to the spirit of democracy and the
soul of Republican institutions, and that it leads in dark
directions. That certainly is my view.”
More recently, President Eisenhower reminded the nation
of these considerations in his Farewell Address:
“In the councils of government, we must guard against the
acquisition of unwarranted influence, whether sought or
130
unsought, by the military-industrial complex. The potcnlial
for the disastrous rise of misplaced power exists and will
persist.
“We must never lel the weight of this combination endanger
our liberties or democratic processes. We should take nothing
for granted. Only an alert and knowledgeable citizenry can
compel the proper meshing of the huge industrial and military
machinery of defense with our peaceful methods and goals, so
that security and liberty may prosper together.”
In short, however the armed forces are recruited, a watchful
population will continue to be the strongest force limiting the
influence of the military in American society.
Third, there is much evidence that our society has more to
gain than to fear from an all-volunteer force. Throughout its
history, the United States has relied on volunteer military
forces, resorting to conscription only in time of clear danger.
Prior to 1948 conscription was abandoned after each major war
and voluntary recruitment reinstated. Only in the past twenty
years has the United States used the draft to raise a standing
military force. During the long periods of entirely voluntary
recruitment the United States never experienced a threat to
civilian control from the military. These voluntary military
forces were able to accomplish successfully the military tasks
required of them. The rush of volunteers at the outbreak of
every war demonstrates that a voluntary military did not
produce a decline in patriotism. Nor is there evidence in our
history that voluntary forces encouraged military adventurism.
Our national experience strongly indicates that a volunteer
force is likely to promote civilian control of the military,
improve the quality of the armed forces, foster continued
patriotism and help avoid military adventurism.
Lastly, the manpower policies of an all-volunteer force will
largely maintain the existing qualitative composition of the
armed forces. This conclusion is based on an analysis of the
main alternatives available to us for recruiting military
manpower. We have made projections of two future
forces ~ one a mixed volunteer-conscript force, the other an
all-volunteer armed force. In comparing the two alternative
forces, we use four categories: the career force, true enlistees in
their first tour of duty, draft motivated enlistees in their first
tour, and draftees. The career force contains men voluntarily
serving beyond any period of obligated service. True enlistees
131
117.4ili 0 1” 1”
are men who would have joined even if there were no draft.
Draft-motivated enlistees are men who say they would probably
not have joined if there were no draft. Draftees are, of course,
men inducted under Selective Service procedures. Table 12-I
shows the number of enlisted men in each of the categories for
the two alternative 2.5 million man future forces. The table
shows that 83 percent of the mixed force will be serving
voluntarily.
TABLE
12-I.-Composition of mixed and volunteer enlisted forces,
1980 [millions of men]
Volunteer force Mixed force
First-term force
Draftees
..~~.~~~.~~~~~~~ ~~~ None
,193 (9%)
Draft-induced volunteers .~~~.. None .162 (6%)
True volunteers ~~~~~~~~~~~~.~..~.~~~. 1.079 (52%)
,925 (43%)
Career force-volunteers ~~~~~~~~..~~~~ 1.010 (46%)
,848 (40%)
Total ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~.~ ..~~ 2.089 (100%)
2.146 (100%)
Since career men and true volunteers in the mixed force
will remain in a volunteer force, the potential differences in the
two forces are mostly limited to the kind of men who are draft
induced volunteers or draftees in the present mixed force.
Draft motivated volunteers are men who object less to
military service than the men who are drafted. A potential
draftee is presented with a forced choice. He can be drafted into
the Army for two years or he can enlist in the service of his
choice and get a better chance of serving in the branch and
occupation he prefers. Enlistment generally requires additional
time in service ~ one year extra in the Army, two extra years in
the Navy and Air Force. Draftees are not willing to serve this
extra time. But draft motivated volunteers are willing to trade
extra time in uniform for preferred service. These draft
motivated volunteers are the type who will find service in an
aH-volunteer force attractive. Improved compensation and
better conditions of service will appeal to the men who would
otherwise volunteer to avoid the draft. The major quantitative
difference between the projected all-volunteer force and the
projected mixed volunteer-conscript force is, therefore, the
presence of 193,000 draftees in the latter, nine percent of the
enlisted force.
Further, the qualitative standards for entry into the two
132
alternative forces will be the same. Identical mental, physical
and moral standards will act to reduce differences in the types
of men who man the two forces. Men who will not qualify to
enter the mixed force will also not qualify for the all-volunteer
force. For example, some 30 percent of America’s young men
do not presently qualify for military service. A disproportionate
share of these men come from a low income environment.
These men will continue to be ineligible for military service
whether or not they are attracted to military life.
Raising first-term military pay will increase the
attractiveness of the military more to young men with higher
earnings potential than to young men with lower earnings
potential. For those who have very poor civilian alternatives
even the present low level of first-term pay is relatively
attractive. In either the mixed force or the all-volunteer force,
men who have very poor civilian alternatives and who meet the
military’s standards will be able to enlist and reenlist. But the
low first-term pay of the present mixed force is a real obstacle
to recruiting men who have better civilian alternatives.
Increasing first-term pay for the all-volunteer force removes this
obstacle and should increase the flow of qualified enlistees. In
spite of low first-term pay an estimated 140,000 high-school
graduates entered the military as true volunteers during 1968.
Higher first-term pay certainly would have attracted some of
the remaining 1.2.million male high-school graduates who either
entered the labor force or continued their education.
The men attracted to an all-volunteer force will not
necessarily make military service their career, In fact, about 65
percent of tile men who enter the all-volunteer force will leave
after a single tour of duty. We estimate that turnover in the
all-volunteer force will be three-quarters of the turnover in a
comparable mixed force. As table 12-I shows, 52 percent of the
men in the projected voluntary force will be first-termers ~
only
slightly less than the estimated 60 percent in the
comparable mixed force.
The all-volunteer force will resemble a mixed volunteer
and conscript force in other ways. In the important area of
officer recruitment, the majority of new officers in the
all-volunteer force will come from ROTC, direct, appointments
and officer candidate school. Each year the military will
continue to draw new leaders into the service from the same
sources as it does today. Most of these men will enter at the
133
bottom and advance to higher levels just as officer personnel do
today.
Because we do not expect major changes in the
composition of the armed forces, we do not expect major
changes in the relationship oetween the armed forces and the
rest of society.
Beyond these general considerations, we felt obliged to
study several specific questions to insure that our conclusions
were valid. Assuming the change to an all-volunteer force might
affect the relations between the armed forces and society,
would it result in undesirable separation? How might the change
affect the racial composition of the forces? What might be the
consequences of a reduced flow of veterans from the forces into
society? How might the end of the draft and reliance on
all-volunteer forces affect the foreign policy decision-making
process? Much of the opposition to an all-volunteer force arises
because such questions have not been carefully explored.
Concerns about the all-volunteer force are often expressed
in emotionally charged terms - “mercenaries” - and rely on
leaps of the imagination to close the gaps where evidence is
lacking. It is easy to conjure up the threat of a more powerful
military establishment which would gain unwarranted influence
within the government, until one hears other voices claiming the
opposite - namely, that isolation of the military will lead to
reduced influence and a less effective force. Through these (and
other) objections runs the assertion that the military and the
rest of society will be “alienated.”
ISOLATION AND CIVILIAN CONTROL
The long-established institutional framework, firm public
attitudes, and the similarity of the future forces with or without
conscription will help prevent separation between the armed
forces and society if the United States adopts an all-volunteer
force. Still, critics feel that the high turnover of manpower
generated by the Selective Service System is a healthy
phenomenon. The flow of men into and out of the armed forces
is thought to generate a link between the services and civilian
society that will be weakened or lost with an all-volunteer force.
It is claimed that the constant inflow of civilian draftees with
limited commitment
to
the military guards against the growth
of a separate military ethos. It is further claimed that the
134
constant outflow of veterans to society makes society more
informed, more patriotic, and more alert to threats to national
life.
Concern about isolation of the military is heightened by
the knowledge that the men in an all-volunteer force would be
self-selected rather than chosen by their draft boards. The
change, some say. will result in an Army composed of
undesirable psychological types, men inclined to use force and
violence to solve problems. A mercenary army might develop.
The men in the military might come to serve the military’s
interests against society, leading eventually to loss of society’s
control over the armed forces. Isolation and alienation could
also operate on civilian society. As the military grew apart from
the rest of society, interest in military matters would diminish
and anti-military attitudes would develop. This would make it
difficult to attract high quality men into the armed forces and
the military’s stature would fall further. A cycle of
anti-militarism and falling prestige would ensue. Both the
quality of military leadership and the effectiveness of the
military as a fighting force would deteriorate. The experience of
other nations is sometimes cited to support fears of such
undesirable consequences.
We have examined the issues raised by those who fear
potential alienation of the armed forces. Some are mutually
contradictory. For example. an all-volunteer force cannot both
strengthen and weaken the influence of the armed forces. We do
not believe that an all-volunteer force such as we recommend
will become isolated or alienated from society.
Those who fear greater alienation from voluntary
recruiting exaggerate the difference between volunteer and
conscripted forces. We have already pointed out that the men in
both forces will be largely the same types. Moreover, the
turnover of the volunteer force will be three-fourths as large as
if conscription is retained. At a force level of 2.5 million men
the volunteer force must attract 325,000 men, the conscripted
force 440.000 men. Further, the men who join the volunteer
force will not all become long service professionals. An
estimated 2 15,000 men will leave after serving a single tour. As
a result. about half the men in the volunteer force will be in
their first tour of duty. The large infusion of new men will help
insure that neither force becomes isolated from society.
I35
The charge that the United States’ armed forces will
become
“mercenaries” is easiest to answer. The term implies a
single motive - monetary reward ~ which precludes patriotism
and all other motives for service. It is usually applied to those
who serve a foreign power. We simply cannot take the charge
seriously. Why should an all-volunteer force be a mercenary
force when our local police, F.B.I. agents, and federal marshals,
all entirely voluntary, are not? Changes in compensation and
conditions of service for the all-volunteer force will enhance the
attractiveness of the armed forces for citizens who will serve for
a variety of reasons. Many factors affect the choice between
military and civilian opportunities, and pay is weighed along
with the chance for interesting work, living conditions, travel,
opportunities for promotion and others.
To suggest that men who enlist to serve their country do
so only for pay is to demean the hundreds of thousands who
voluntarily serve today. More than half of all the men in today’s
forces are true volunteers. This includes one-third of the men
with less than four years service. Given today’s first-term pay
levels, these men must be motivated by other considerations,
including a high sense of dedication to their country. Whatever
motivates these first-term men will not disappear simply
because the draft is no longer used to compel other men to
serve and because conditions of service improve. Nor should we
expect that the recommended pay increases will diminish the
demonstrated dedication of the career force. On the contrary,
patriotism is now weakened by the fact that society initially
underpays men who volunteer and generally treats military
service as an activity which men will undertake only if
compelled to do so.
The charge that the all-volunteer force will be manned by
“hired killers” obsessed with violence is as empty as the talk of
“mercenaries.” Such men ~’ assuming they exist in significant
numbers - are free to join the present mixed force. If anything,
discipline of the violence-prone would be enhanced in a fully
professional volunteer force.
As for the feared possibility of military intervention in
political matters, this occurs when civilian political leadership is
weak and indecisive or when its legitimacy is called into
question. Those nations which have experienced military
interference in political affairs suffer ills entirely unrelated to
136
the
presence or absence of conscripts in
the ranks. Furthermore,
such interventions
usually arise from the officer corps. In the
two major nations which have relied on volunteer forces
throughout most of their modern history - the United States
and the United Kingdom ~ it is difficult to find anything
remotely resembling military intervention.
The modern history of Europe and Latin America reveals
no evidence that all-volunteer forces are more likely to
overthrow civilian leadership. But, major direct military
interventions in political affairs are not the only concern of
those who oppose an all-volunteer force as a threat to civilian
control of the military. They also fear that the military will
acquire excessive political and social influence. These fears
appear groundless. An all-volunteer force will not have any
more influence on the President, Congress or the rest of society
than the military now possesses. In fact, to the extent size alone
matters, the impact of an all-volunteer force will be less since it
will be somewhat smaller than a mixed force of equal
effectiveness. An all-volunteer force will have a larger budget,
but the additional funds will be used for compensation and will
not provide more control over real resources.
Elimination of the draft will also reduce somewhat the
military’s influence over the use of manpower resources in the
civilian sector. The Selective Service System frankly
acknowledges that it uses the draft to direct potential draftees
into activities it regards as vital to the nation:
The deferment of men from military service to pursue civilian
activities in the national interest has always been a function of
Selective Service. The Prospect of deferment has had the effect
of
influencing men to pursue such activities.
The
spectrum of skills vital to the nation’s capacity to survive
his steadily broadened. Its limits cannot be foreseen. It
embraces many civilian activities
as well as service in uniform.
Particularly since the beginning of the “space age” the breadth
of the concept of what cwxtitutes “service” in defense has
been difficult to fix. But it has been equally apparent that the
fullest development and wisest utilization by citizens of their
capabilities is vital to the nation.
In making decisions about manpower allocation, the Selective
Service System operates independent of any direct
Congressional review. This “channeling” process gives
137
deferments for defense related work and not for otherwise
similar non-defense work. The return to an all-volunteer force
would end this practice, and to that extent limit the military’s
influence on the setting of social priorities in America.
On balance the elimination of conscription may slightly
reduce the influence of the military, but the effect is so small as
to be negligible.
Behind fears that the military’s political power would be
enlarged lies a basic concern that an all-volunteer force would
develop its own rigid ethos. Even if the military did not have
increased political power, some fear it would use the power it
possessed in undesirable ways. Again, this fear assumes II greatly
exaggerated difference between an all-volunteer and a mixed
force.
The officer corps exercises the dominant influence on
military values. Elimination of the draft will not significantly
alter its composition. Officers will continue to be recruited
from all over the nation and from a variety of socio-economic
backgrounds. Further, the change to an all-volunteer force will
have no effect on top leadership, since these men have always
been professionals. There is little evidence that the views of
enlisted men have a significant impact on their thinking and
even less evidence that this impact depends upon how enlisted
men are recruited. If there is a separate military ethos, it will
persist in a mixed as well as an all-volunteer force.
Moreover, it is by no means clear that a problem exists at
all. There is now significant interaction between the military
and the rest of society. The military is not isolated from the
mass media which permeate all walks of life. Also, the forces
contain a wide variety of specialists, not only in air, sea and
ground combat, but also in all branches of engineering and
science, in computer applications, medicine and dentistry, law,
aviation, personnel management, ship building, and others.
These men are often in daily contact with their fellow
professionals in the civilian sector. Much specialist and officer
training takes place in the civilian sector. The Defense
Department employs more than one million civilians, and many
officers serve tours of duty which require daily contact with the
business community, academic institutions, and other civilian
organizations.
If the present degree of military and civilian interaction is
inadequate, conscription does not solve the problem. The
138
solution lies in taking further steps to reduce the separation
between the military and the rest of society. Many of the
benefits provided in-kind to military personnel increase that
separation. A serviceman can live on a base, shop in the
commissary and post exchange, send his children to a school
filled with children whose parents are also in the military, and
have his family’s medical needs attended to in a military
hospital. If more military compensation were paid in cash and
less of it in-kind, the military might be less isolated from the
rest of ‘society. Also, more of the training and education of
military personnel could be civilianized; and, as suggested
elsewhere in this report, medical services could be civilianized.
An aggressive expansion in the use of lateral entry, especially in
the officer corps, would provide leaders less identified with any
prevailing military ethos. These are some steps which might be
taken if the nation desires a closer identification between
military and civilian values. However, they may ,have an adverse
effect on morale in the military. By working and living together,
servicemen develop a rapport which is very important in
combat. One cost of having more civil-military integration may
be a less effective defense establishment.
ISOLATION AND MILITARY QUALITY
While some worry that an all-volunteer force will increase
the power of the military, others believe it will lead to the
deterioration of the military. They see the end of conscription
as causing public neglect, significant reductions in the defense
budget, a ge’neral declilie in the prestige of military service, and
a reduced quality of military personnel. In fact, the effect of
the all-volunteer force should be the reverse of this gloomy
picture. As it stands today the draft is a major source of
antagonism toward the military, which erodes public support of
the armed services. Because the draft is unnecessary, an
all-volunteer force offers an obvious opportunity to curb the
growth of anti-militaristic sentiment.
Of course, civil-military relations will never be
uncontroversial. They have not been so in the past, whether
manpower has been raised by conscription or voluntarism. The
military have a distinct and separate set of responsibilities of
fundamental importance to the survival of American society.
Military leaders seek assurance that they will be able to
accomplish successfully the tasks they may be called upon to
139
do. Uncertainty about potential threats rind our ability to cope
with them leads to differing judgments about the size of forces
required. These differences bring about conflict hetwesn the
demands of the military and the demands of other groups in our
society and will do so regardless of whether there is a draft.
The resolution of this conflict wilt vary depending on the
public’s evaluation of national priorities. During the 1930’s
defense expenditures averaged one percent of Gross National
Product, hut from 1955 to I964 they averaged nine percent of
Gross National Product. The strength of our armed forces is
hased on fundamental public attitudes toward national defense.
No doubt the shift to an all-volunteer force will have some
effect on those attitudes. Those who no longer face the threat
of conscription and those who oppose the draft on moral
grounds are likely to feel less hostile toward the milit;lry. while
those whose taxes are increased may he displeased. On balance,
it is difficult to see which of these factors will predominate.
More importantly. it seems clear that neither factor is
likely to have very much effect. Since World War II our
peacetimr armed forces have been consistently supported at
levels unparalleled in our history. This can hardly he explained
by the fact that we have also had conscription during these
years. The public lms supported the maintenance of large forces
htxausr it has felt that they were t‘ssential to notionat security.
The change fro&a mixed force of volunteers and conscripts to
an all-volunteer force wilt not dmmatioally change that feeling.
In recent years military service has been scorned and
condemned by some Americans. No doubt. the Vietnam War is
partly responsible. hut the draft has also contributed to the
military’s unpopularity. Young men are inevitably skeptical
about a career in an organization which has to use compulsion
to ohtoin recruits. Moreover, the low pay implies that society
plxes little value on ;I soldier. The termination of the draft
should immediately enhance the prestige of enlisted service. The
knowledge that those in the armed forces have freely chosen to
serve their country cannot hut improve their image in their
own eyes as well X
in the ryes of society. Our
recommendations regarding military compensation have been
discussed earlier. They should also go a long way toward
improving the image of ;I military career and they are aimed at
maintaining the quality of military personnel. Many of our
recomm~~~d;ltions for increasing the efficiency of military
140
personnel management will also enhance the image of military
life. Making the terms of obligated service for enlisted men the
same as those for officers, vesting retirement benefits,
encouraging lateral entry and similar changes will operate to
reduce the differences between military and civilian careers.
Military careers will become more professional and avoid the
stigma of being an unpleasant task that some men must be
forced to do temporarily.
The return to an all-volunteer armed force should improve
the “quality” of military life. Conscription enables the military
to ignore individual dignity and desire, secure in the knowledge
that the draft will replace those who do not like the military
system. The entire military “atmosphere” ~ the approach to
training, discipline, and treatment of individuals - must be
reexamined. In the modern army at most one-third of the men
serve in infantry or ground combat units, and the others serve in
technical, administrative and logistical billets. The appeal and
utility of military occupational training can be improved by
greater recognition that some individuals do not need the kind
of training traditionally given all recruits as potential
infantrymen. Assignment policies which minimize family
separation and which reduce the frequency of duty changes and
moves will also make military life more attractive.
Elimination of conscription will also affect the American
officer corps even though its recruits have always been
volunteers. The draft induces many men to volunteer for service
as officers to avoid being inducted as enlisted men. Thus the
prestige of military service has been hurt by the draft even in
the officer corps. Officers as well as enlisted men will benefit
from the changes the Commission is recommending. Pay will be
increased, particularly for junior officers. Change in conditions
of service and in the quality of military life will make military
careers more attractive to potential officers.
AN ARMY OF THE BLACK?
Members of both the white and Negro communities have
expressed concern that the all-volunteer force might fill its
enlisted ranks with the poor and the black. This concern is
linked to the recognition that to move to a voluntary force
requires a substantial increase in first-term military pay. Higher
pay, it is said, will increase the attractiveness of military service
primarily among lower income groups, where the proportion of
141
Negroes is high. A predominantly black enlisted force might
develop. This will result, according to some, in the black and
the poor bearing a disproportionate share of the burden of
defense: Some whites are concerned with the dangers of having
in the community a large number of blacks who have had
military training. They fear that these men will participate in
domestic disorders and riots.
There is no evidence that the black community would be
happy with an increase in the number of blacks in the military.
Increasing the attractiveness of the military will draw able
young males into the services because other job opportunities
are denied them. In most black communities there is a need for
able young black males to enter civilian careers, work on
community projects, and inspire the young. There is strong
evidence to suggest that the black community, more than the
white, looks at the “male drain” as extremely costly.
Many of these questions and concerns cannot be answered
rationally. Racial attitudes and fears are emotionally based.
Solid facts and the sound judgments are seldom cures for
prejudice. For example, those who fear “domestic disorders” as
a result of blacks serving in the military raise such unanswerable
questions. To bar blacks from the military because of these
fears will not solve the root causes behind domestic disorders.
Black participation in the military will neither quiet nor
aggravate domestic disorders.
The racial aspects of the relationship between the armed
forces and society have been given special consideration by the
Commission. We have concluded that the racial composition of
the armed forces cannot be fundamentally changed by ending
the draft. Even if higher pay appealed only to the “poor,” twice
as many whites as blacks would be attracted. The proportion of
blacks below the poverty line in 1967 was 3X percent while
only I I percent of whites were in the Same category. But, in
absolute numbers, more than twice as many whites (17.6
killion) as blacks (8.3 million) were below the poverty line.
The relevant comparison is between the racial mix of the
all-volunteer force and the racial mix of an alternative force of
conscripts and volunteers. We conclude that the similar
manpower policies of the two forces will result in similar racial
composition in the two forces. The mental, physical, and moral
standards for enlistment will ensure that neither force recruits
an undue proportion from minority groups or the poor. The
142
best estimate of the proportion of blacks in the all-volunteer
force is 14.9 percent, compared with 14.1 percent in a mixed
force of conscripts and volunteers. In the Army, the proportion
of blacks in the volunteer force is 18.8 percent; in the mixed
force it is 16.6 percent. At a 2.5 million man force level, only
five to ten thousand more blacks will serve in the enlisted
component of a volunteer force than in a mixed force.
Our estimates are based on a careful review of all aspects
of the racial composition of the armed forces. As a first step,
participation by whites and blacks in the military during the
1960’s was examined. Second, the detailed projections of the
alternative future forces were analyzed to determine the racial
mix of the 2.5 million man force in 1980. The number of blacks
in either force depends on the number of young black males in
the population, their qualifications for military service, the rate
at which the qualified enter the military, and the rate at which
they reenlist. Our analysis of these factors is based on data
provided by the Department of Defense and the Census Bureau.
Participation of Blacks in Present Forces
Because of racial differences in civilian earnings, even the
current levels of military pay are more attractive to blacks than
to whites. In 1966, the average annual income of a 24-year old
white high school graduate was $6013, for a black high school
graduate the same age average annual income was $4344. In the
military, the earnings of the two men would be nearly the same.
In spite of this relative attractiveness, the proportion of blacks
in the armed, forces has been slightly less than the proportion in
the U.S. male population.
During the late 1960’s, Negroes constituted from 9.0 to
9.5 percent of the total armed force. In June 1969, two percent
of the officers were Negro as were 10.5 percent of the total
enlisted force as shown in table 12-H. Both in total and in the
enlisted component alone, the proportion of Negroes was
somewhat less than their proportion (12 percent) in the young
male population. Negro participation in the Army in Southeast
Asia (I I .4 percent) is slightly less than their percentage in the
total Army (I 1.7 percent).
The forces of the 1960’s were, of course mixed forces of
volunteers and conscripts. However, the racial composition of
these forces is only partially the result of conscription, since
143
TABLE 12-Il.-Negro
participation
in the Armed Forces,
June 30.1969
[percent]
-
Officer
Enlisted Total
In SE Asia
Army ~~~~~.~.~~~~.~.~~~~ 3.2 12.6 11.7 11.4
Navy ~~~~~~~~~~~~
0.4 5.3
4.0
4.5
Marine Corpse 1.0 11.9
11 .o 10.3
Air Force...~ 1.6 10.6 9.2 10.5
-
DOD
total~~~~. .~~
2.0 10.5 iFI ii2
even under the draft a majority of the military are there on a
fully voluntary basis. The distinction between the first term
force and the career force is helpful in understanding the racial
composition of the armed forces. The first term force includes
draftees, draft motivated volunteers and true volunteers, men
who say they would have volunteered at current pay levels even
if there were no draft. The career force includes all men who
have voluntarily reenlisted.
The racial mix among true volunteers in the first term of
service and in the career force gives some insight into the racial
composition of the all-volunteer force. Table 12-111 shows that
blacks constituted only 12.7 percent of nearly 1.7 million
enlisted men serving voluntarily in 1969 Among true
volunteers, blacks are now serving in the armed forces almost
exactly in proportion to their numbers in the U.S. population.
About one-third of the men in the first term of service are true
volunteers. Of these men, 11.6 percent are black. The
proportion of. blacks in the career force is 13.1 percent - only
slightly higher than the percent in the U.S. population. The
same holds for women in the military who, of course, serve free
of the compulsion of the draft. In all cases, the proportion of
TABLE 12-Ill.-Blacks, as a percent of enlisted frue
volunteers
in the 1969 Armed Forces
Male Female
-
First term Career
Total
Total
Arrnym~~~ ~.~~~~~~~ 16.4 19.2 17.7
15.4
Navy...~~~~~~~~~.~~.~.~ 6.0 7.0 6.5 6.2
Marine Corps~~~~-~~~.. 11.6
11.9
11.6
15.1
Air Force......~~~~~~~~~~~ 11.4 12.0 11.6 11.1
-
DOD total ....~~~~
11.6
13.1,
lG?
11.0
144
blacks is highest in the Army and lowest in the Navy. At
present. blacks constitute nearly 20 percent of the Army cxeer
enlisted force.
These proportions depend on the r;tcial mix among men
entering the two force components. The proportion of blacks in
the first term true volunteer force depends on the proportion of
blacks among true volunteers entering the militxy. Thr
proportion of blacks in the career force depends on the
proportion of re-enlistws who are black. The data in table
IXV shows blacks as a percent of the men flowing into the
ci,nx~ force. (The percentage given in the table should not be
confused with re-enlistment rotrs. Re-twlistmrnt rates are higher
for Negroes than for whites. but these drpcnd on the definition
of eligibility for re-enlistment. Since eligibility rates are lowrr
for Negroes than for whites. a comparison using rs-enlistment
rates overstates the proportion of Negroes entering the carrw
force.) The percentage of blacks among those w-enlisting at the
end of their first term of service has fallen shxply in recent
years. This is largely the result of a sharp decline in the
percentage of blacks among first term re-enlistws in the Army.
The decline in the percentage of blacks re-enlisting will
eventually lead to a decline in the percent of blacks in the Army
career force.
TABLE 1%IV.-Blacks as a percent of first-term reenlistments’
1965 1966
1967
1966 1969
Arrn~~~~~~
22.3 20.7
19.2
14.3 11.6
Navy~.~~ ~~~.~~.~..
6.6 6.4
7.1
6.5 6.6
Marine Corps ~..... 12.5 11.6 13.4 12.0 12.6
Air Forw~~~~..~. 15.1 10.9 15.1 13.0 14.0
DOD total 16.3 14.7 14.6 1G 11.4
I oats lo, ,965 to ,968 is calendar year. oats for 1969 is fiscal year.
In summary. in today’s force blacks do not serve
disproptionately to their numbers in the population. This is true
for the total force and for the true volunteer component alone.
Black participation is highest in the Army. where about one
man in five in the career force is Negro.
Participation of Blncks in Future Forces
Estimating the participation of blacks in the all-volunteer
force or the future mixed volunteer and conscript force requires
14s
examination of (I) the projected pool of young white and
black men available for military service, (2) the ability of these
men to meet the mental and physical standards of the military
service, (3) the first term mihtary participation rates among
qualified men of both races and (4) the re-enlistment behavior
of men in the military. A range of estimates of the proportion
of blacks in the armed forces has been developed by varying
assumptions about qualifications rates, enlistment rates and
reenlistment rates.
Young men in the I7 to 20 age group are the primary
source of initial enlistments. During the 1970’s this pool will
grow by more than a million men. But, since the white pool will
grow at a slower rate than the black pool, the proportion of
blacks available for military service will increase, as shown in
table 12-V. This trend makes it likely that the proportion of
blacks in either the all-volunteer force or the mixed force will
increase during the 1970’s from today’s 10.6 percent. These
proportions of blacks in the military age population provide a
standard for evaluating minority group participation in the
alternative future forces.
TABLE l&V.--Trends
in the 17-20 male population [in thousands]
Black White Total
Percent
nonwhite
It is an unfortunate fact that not all these young men will
be qualified for military service. The qualifications for service
will be retained at today’s level in both the all-volunteer force
and the alternative mixed force. To be acceptable for military
service, young men must meet certain minimum physical,
moral, and mental standards. For example, men who score in
the lowest IO percent on the Armed Forces Qualification Test
are exempted from military service. The results of examinations
of draftees provide an found acceptable for military service in
young men for military service. (See table 12.VI). Clearly, the
TABLE 12-VI.-Preinduction
examination accepfance rafes
[percenf]
1964 1965 1966 1967 1968
White ~...~~ ~~..
52.8
60.3 64.8 60.8 59.7
Black ._.... ~~..~~~~~~..~~..
21.7 29.2 42.5 49.9 45.0
proportion of young black men found acceptable for military
service in preinduction examinations is lower than the
proportion of young whites found acceptable. But just as
clearly, the acceptance rate for young blacks is rising rapidly.
Acceptance rates for enlistees are higher than for draftees,
running better than 90 percent overall. Combining the results
for draftees with the higher acceptance rates for similar
examinations for enlistees in all services gives an overall
acceptability rate of about 73 percent for whites and 53 percent
for blacks based on the recent past. Estimates of the qualified
black population have been made based on recent experience
(53 percent acceptability), and for improved black acceptance
rates (63 percent acceptability) and are shown in table l2-VII.
The acceptability of young whites has been held constant at 73
percent. Though the proportion of young blacks in the
population is growing, their numbers remain relatively small.
This limits the number of blacks who will serve in the armed
forces.
TABLE
12-VII.-Male population 17-20 qualified for military service
Qualified black population
based on
53-percent
63-percent
acceptability acceptability
1970 .~~.~~~~ ~~..~~ 528,490 628,740
1975 . .._.. ~~.~~~~~~.~~ 614,270
770,170
1980 ~..~~~~~~.. 684,410 817,110
1985 ..~..~~~~~~.~~..~~ 633,350
752,850
Qualified
white population
73-percent
acceptability
4,712,880
5.247,240
5,371,340
4,663,240
The next step in estimating the racial composition of
future forces is to determine the numbers of men of both races
who can be expected to participate in the first term force. The
all-volunteer force will attract men through higher pay and
improved conditions of service. The mixed force would include
draftees, draft induced volunteers and true volunteers. Recent
experience has been used to estimate the participation of true
volunteers in the armed forces and to show how the
participation rate is affected by military pay increases. Table
12-VI11 gives true volunteers in the first term of service during
1969 as a percent of the qualified male population, 17 to 20.
For example, some 51,200 blacks in the Army in their first
term of duty would have enlisted even if there had been no
draft. In 1969 the qualified black population was about
5 12,000, so 10 percent of the qualified men were serving as true
volunteers.
TABLE 1%VIII.-True volunteer participation rates at current
few/s Of pay
White
Black
(percent) (percent)
Army ~~~~~~~~~~~ 5.65
10.00
Navy ~~~~..~..~~~~~~~~~.~..~. 3.60 2.16
Marine Corps .~~~.~~~~~ 2.47
2.96
Air Force ~~~~~.~~...~~~~~ 3.46
4.01
DOD total .~~~~~ 15.38
19.15
The rates in table 12-VIII, and similar participation rates
for draft induced volunteers have been used to estimate
volunteer participation in the mixed volunteer and consript
forces. The proportion of blacks among draftees in recent years
has been higher than their proportions in the qualified
population. During the last five years, Negroes constituted only
9.2 percent of the qualified population but were 14.3 percent
of the men actually inducted. Estimates of the proportion of
blacks among draftees are based on recent experience and,
alternatively, on the assumption that blacks are drafted exactly
in proportion to their numbers in the qualified population.
Voluntary participation rates depend on the relationship
between the military compensation and civilian earnings. If
military pay is increased relative to civilian earnings,
participation rates should increase. The pay increases
recommended in chapter 5 will result in about a 40 percent
increase in first term military pay. But the effect of the increase
on black participation rates will be smaller than on white
participation rates. Because a larger proportion of the qualified
148
black population is willing to serve at today’s relative pay level.
the 40 percent increase will attract a smaller percentage of
additional black entrants. For example, studies of Air Force
re-enlistments indicate that a IO percent increase in relative pay
will increase white re-enlistments by 24 percent but black
re-enlistments by only I8 percent. Two assumptions were used
in estimating the effect of the recommended first term pay
increase on participation rates. In one case. the percentage
increase in the black participation rate was assumed to be
three-quarters of the percentage increase in the white
participation rate. In the other case, equal percentage increases
were assumed.
Experience during the 1960’s has also been used to
estimate the racial composition of the career force. For
example, blacks constituted 12.7 percent of the true volunteers
entering the Air Force between I963 and 1966. When men who
entered the Air Force in this cohort made first term
reenlistment decisions, 14.4 percent of the re-enlistees were
black. The ratio of these percentages. 1.134. is applied to the
estimated first term black proportion to estimate the
proportion of blacks in the career force. Thus. if 1 I, 1 percent
of the men in the first term service in the Air Force were black,
the percent of blacks in the career force is estimated to be 12.6.
The
same
procedure was used for all services.
These assumptions and estimates yield a variety of
estimates of the proportion of blacks in the two alternative 2.5
million man future forces. For the voluntary force. these
estimates range from 12.8 percent to 16.0 percent. For the
mixed force of conscripts and volunteers the lowest estimate is
12.1 percent and the highest is 15.1 percent. Tables 12-1X and
12-X give the best estimate of the proportion of blacks in the
TABLE
12-IX.-Esfimafed
racial composition of the enlisted male
al/-volunteer force in 1980
Percent
Black Total Negro
155,650 627,100 16.6
42,550 516,600 8.2
29,650
164,600
16.0
62,700 558,900
14.6
310.750 2.089.400 1G
149
TABLE
1%X.-Estimated reciel composition of the enlisted male
mixed torte in 1980
White
Black
723,400
144,300
483,750 42,850
154,250
31,950
481.200
84.200
Percent
Total Negro
867,700 16.6
526,600 8.1
186,200
17.1
565,400 14.9
-
DOD total 1,842,600 303,300 2.145.900 ct
two forces. For both forces, these estimates assume that the
proportion of black males qualified for military service rises to
63 percent. For the mixed force, blacks are assumed to be
drafted in proportion to their presence in the qualified
population. For the all-volunteer force, the effect of the first
term military pay increase is assumed to be smaller for blacks
than for whites. Given these assumptions, the proportion of
blacks in the two forces is nearly equal. The highest estimate for
the proportion of blacks in the all-volunteer force 16.0 percent,
occurs when the effect of the pay increase is assumed to be the
same for both races. For the mixed force, the highest estimate is
15.1 percent, when blacks are assumed to be drafted in a higher
proportion than their numbers in the qualified population, as
during the late 1960’s.
Even if higher estimates were realized, we would not
consider asking the government - including the military - to
cut back on hiring blacks, or to set quotas. Government service
has traditionally been a major source of employment for blacks.
This is as true for blacks with the highest skills and degrees as
well as for other levels of training and income. The participation
of blacks in municipal, state and national government reflects
the confidence blacks have in the government as a “hirer of last
resort.” Discrimination and segregation in other sectors of
society traditionally have persisted long after government policy
changed to include blacks. Citizens who are concerned with
racial imbalance in this or that sector must work to open
opportunities for blacks in all occupations. Then, and only
then, will the question of “proportionate representation” be
fair.
VETERANS IN SOCIETY
Many Americans are concerned that creation of an
all-volunteer force will adversely affect the size and composition
of the veteran population. They reason that a system of military
recruitment which uses conscription takes many .young men
from society, exposes them to an important experience, and
then rather quickly returns them to civilian life.
Veterans are today a substantial part of American society.
In 1968 veterans were 13 percent of the total population, 23
percent of the adult population, and 47 percent of the adult
male population. These more than 27 million veterans averaged
44 years in age, and 27 months of active duty. Both their
numbers and their ages make the influence of veterans on
American life highly significant.
A volunteer system will take fewer recruits, retain them
longer, and return fewer veterans to civilian society. If military
experience is beneficial, there would be some loss in the
qualities that veterans bring to society - qualities that are
attributed to military experience.
Military life is thought to have a discernible and beneficial
impact on an individual’s capabilities, attitudes, and behavior
patterns as they are carried over into the veteran’s civilian life.
The differences between veterans and non-veterans are
described in a variety of ways. Veterans are said to display
more
patriotism and to be readier to serve our nation. Some argue
that veterans are better informed and more concerned about a
wide variety of foreign and domestic affairs and, thus, are more
alert to threats to the nation. Veterans are alleged to behave
differently - to have more self-discipline and to pay greater
attention to neatness and hygiene. Veterans are said to do
better economically than non-veterans, to participate more in
community social and political activities, and, in general, to
make better and more productive citizens.
We have studied the effect of an all-volunteer force on the
size of the veteran population. In addition, we have examined
the effect of military service on men’s attitudes toward national
security and other contemporary issues to determine whether
veterans are different from non-veterans and whether the
differences are beneficial.
At any force level, the turnover of military personnel and
the consequent annual flow of new veterans will be smaller
151
under an all-volunteer system than under the mixed,
conscript-volunteer system. Using an estimate of 15 percent as
the enlisted turnover for the volunteer force and 20 percent for
the mixed force, about 130,000 fewer veterans would be added
annually to the veteran population with the all-volunteer force.
For the next 20 years World War 11, Korean War and
Vietnam veterans will dominate the veteran population and
therefore the short-run impact of ending the draft will be small.
Eventually, lower turnover will mean a smaller veteran
population. For example, by adding projected new veteran
accessions to the existing veteran population and adjusting for
mortality, the present system of conscription will generate a
veteran population of 26.3 million by the year 2000. For the
same effective force, an all-volunteer force adopted in 1971
would generate 3.2 million fewer veterans over the next 30
years. Veterans as a percentage of the total population would
decrease from 13 percent today to about 8 percent in the year
2000 under a mixed conscript-volunteer system and to about 7
percent for an all-volunteer force.
Whatever the exact quantitative effect of a return to an
all-volunteer force, If military service instills patriotism and
greater awareness of national interests, ending the draft would
eventually affect public attitudes about foreign policy and
national security matters. Alternatively, if military service does
not instill different attitudes then the change in method of
recruiting will have no effect. To study the influence of military
service on public attitudes we used national opinion surveys on
a wide variety of domestic, foreign policy and security issues
that also had information on the veteran status of respondents.
Military experience proved to be a minor factor
in
explaining
opinion differences. Other characteristics ~ notably occupation,
income, region, education, political party, age, race and other
sociological attributes ~ are far better predictors of attitudes
than veteran status. Indeed, there is a significant difference
between attitudes of veterans and non-veterans ~ holding other
characteristics constant - on only one matter of contemporary
debate -~ namely, attitudes toward veterans’ benefits.
Similarly, the effect of military training on earnings is
much more questionable than frequently supposed. Since 1960
over three-quarters of the active military personnel served in
jobs that had white-collar or blue-collar civilian counterparts.
Yet, only an estimated one-quarter of the men who left the
152
service accepted jobs which they judged to be related to their
military service. The figure for the Army. which experiences the
highest turnover rate, is 15 percent, the lowest among the
services.
As with attitudes, earnings depend on such factors as age,
ability, education and race. Gross comparisons of veterans’ and
non-veterans’ incomes are likely to be misleading because men
who enter the service are more intelligent, healthier, and have
more schooling than those who do not. A meaningful
comparison would allow for these factors. Recent studies which
have attempted to do this conclude that differences in the
earnings between veterans and non-veterans disappear when
factors other than military service are considered.
In summary, the belief that two or three years of military
service increases earnings or alters opinions is not supported by
the evidence. Other experience factors, such as region,
education, age, and the more fundamental family and
community history, are more significant in shaping a person’s
earning power and the way he thinks of himself and of his
environment. Most of these factors are determined long before
military service and are unaffected by it. Whatever qualities
veterans bring to their communities - informed judgment or
ignorance, patriotism or indifference, self-discipline or personal
disarray, community participation or apathy ~ are qualities that
these individuals would probably have displayed without prior
military experience.
EFFECTS ON FOREIGN POLICY DECISION MAKING
We have heard conflicting concerns about the effect on
foreign policy of a return to voluntary recruiting. One view
foresees a less militaristic foreign policy as a consequence of the
all-volunteer force; the other, more military adventurism.
Those who hold the first opinion believe that an
all-volunteer force necessarily will be smaller and less flexible
than a force raised by conscription. Therefore the return to
voluntary recruiting signals a weakening of the United States’
capability to meet its military commitments overseas. The
opposing belief is that the greater training and readiness of a
volunteer force will offer a tempting military solution to
problems which might be better resolved peacefully. Further,
those who hold this opinion think that an all-volunteer force
would have fewer and weaker links to civilian society,
153
imperiling democratic control of foreign policy decisions. We
have considered both of these concerns in the light of our
recommendations. Neither provides a valid basis for rejecting
the all-volunteer force.
Since World War II, the United States has benefited from
an extensive system of defense alliances. Similarly, the security
and freedom of our allies depend on United States’ military
power. Both the resolve and capability of the United States to
continue using its power in the defense of freedom help shape
the expectations and actions of friendly governments. Our
recommendations are designed to insure that an all-volunteer
armed force would be fully consistent with the strategic
concepts underlying national security policy.
This Commission has not tried to project the armed forces
required to carry out the nation’s foreign policy after the
transition to an all-volunteer force. The determination of these
peacetime force requirements is the responsibility of the
Department of Defense and the National Security Council. The
Commission has relied on a range of estimates of active duty
requirements and developed estimates of the all-volunteer force
required to yield the same effective force strength as these
equivalent mixed forces of conscripts and volunteers.
In addition to active duty forces, there will be 700,000 to
800,000 trained men in Reserve or National Guard units
(assuming a 2.5 million man active duty force). These units
furnish a force capable of rapid mobilization, which no draft
law can match. Deployment lead times vary from less than a
week for some naval units to 6 to I4 weeks for Army units.
Under an all-volunteer system, these units will continue to be an
important second line of defense. If a crisis situation requires
more men than are available in the active and reserve forces,
untrained manpower from the civilian pool can be recruited
voluntarily or by conscription.
As set forth elsewhere in this report, the Commission
recommends that permanent peacetime forces be put on a
voluntary basis and that a stand-by draft system be maintained
in readiness. We cannot foresee the shape of future threats to
the security of the United States, and prudence requires that
provision be made for mobilizing civilian manpower by
conscription if necessary.
The Commission’s recommendations, in summary, provide
1) active duty forces comparable in strength to those currently
154
projected, 2) reserve forces for quick reinforcement of the
active forces and 3) a stand-by draft system as a final measure
if large-scale mobilization of untrained men is needed. We
believe that these provisions constitute an effective and flexible
military manpower policy, and will enhance national security
during and after the transition to an all-volunteer force.
We have examined how the return to volunteer forces
might affect the decision to use U.S. military power. We
conclude that the recommended all-volunteer force will actually
increase democratic participation in decisions concerning the,
use of military force. We reject the fear of increased military
aggressiveness or reduced civilian concern following the return
to an all-volunteer force.
A decision to use the all-volunteer force will be made
according to the same criteria as the decision to use a mixed
force of conscripts and volunteers because the size and readiness
of the two forces will be quite similar. These military factors are
key determinants in any decision to commit forces. Beyond
initial commitment, the policy choice between expanding our
forces by conscription or by voluntary enlistment is the same
for both the all-volunteer force and a mixed force of conscripts
and volunteers. The important difference between the two
forces lies in the necessity for political debate before returning
to conscription. Voluntary enlistments in both alternative
forces can be increased by enhancing the attractiveness of
military service. If either force is expanded by making military
service more attractive, civilian participation obviously will be
increased in the process. Increased pay and added fringe
benefits will be borne by the general taxpayers, a far more
inclusive group than potential draftees and their families. If tax
increases are needed or military spending claims priority over
other public spending, a broad public debate is likely. Recent
history suggests that increased taxes generate far more public
discussion than increased draft calls.
With the all-volunteer force, the President can seek
authorization to activate the stand-by draft, but Congress must
give its consent. With the mixed system, draft calls can be
increased by the President. The difference between the two
alternatives is crucial. The former will generate public discussion
of the use of the draft to fight a war, the latter can be done
without such public discussion. If the need for conscription is
1.55
not clear, such discussion will clarify the issue, and the draft
will be used only if public support is widespread.
The claim is made that the ranks of the public attentive to
foreign policy are swelled significantly by those citizens
touched by the draft. It is a doubtful notion. The
corollary -- that public interest in foreign affairs will decrease
significantly if voluntarism is adopted - is also doubtful.
Volunteers have as many concerned relatives and friends as men
who are drafted. Higher educational levels, the diffusion of
modern mass communications, and the newsworthiness of
compelling national security events assure that foreign affairs
will hold the attention of a substantial and growing public.
regardless of the method used for procuring military manpower.
When a minority is selected to fight a long and unpopular
war,
the draft is inevitably a focal point for dissent.
Voluntarism would be expected to decrease dissent stemming
from the issue of conscription. However, popular dissent usually
arises from many issues and reaches the Government along
many channels. Ending conscription will close off one of the
channels, but it will not end dissent.
Because conscription is a tax in kind, part of the cost of
armed forces is hidden when there is a draft. The explicit costs
of using military forces are underestimated, with the result that
decisions to use the armed forces are made which perhaps
would not be made if the true costs were known. The
all-volunteer force, by making economic and political costs
explicit, should lead to more rational and democratic decisions
about the use of military force.
Finally, there is the allegation that political leaders will be
more inclined to military adventures if the armed forces are
composed entirely of volunteers. This argument is based on
three important inferences: (1) an all-volunteer force will be
more aggressive than a mixed force; (2) the nation’s civilian and
military leaders will risk the lives of volunteers with less concern
than those of conscripts
and (3) a doubtful foreign
commitment could be undertaken and sustained with less
popular dissent than if conscripts were used.
Decisions by a government to use force or to threaten the
use of force during crises are extremely difficult. Presidents
have arrived at such decisions only after consulting a broad
range of informed and responsible interests. The high cost of
military resources, the moral burden of risking human lives,
I56
political costs at home and overseas, and the overshadowing risk
of nuclear confrontation - these and other factors enter into
such decisions. It is absurd to argue that issues of such
importance would be ignored and the decision for war made on
the basis of whether our first-term forces were entirely
voluntary or mixed.
As discussed earlier in this report, an all-volunteer military
is not expected to differ significantly from the present mixed
force in its size, composition, and relations with civilian society.
Its subordination to the nation’s political leaders will change
not at all. The belief that volunteers will be more aggressive, will
have greater autonomy from the civilian leadership and will
exploit international tensions to their own advantage springs,
not from any rational evidence, but from an irrational fear of
relying on the neglected mechanism of freedom to preserve and
protect our nation.
157
CHAPTER13
CONSCRIPTION IN AMERICA
Throughout our nation’s history, state and federal
governments have compelled service to meet emergencies.
Nevertheless, a permanent and comprehensive peacetime draft,
such as we have known since 1948, is a
recent
departure.
During the colonial period, hundreds of conscription laws
dealt witli specific requirements for service, provided
exemptions and penalties, and laid down procedures. Induction
into the local militia generally entailed the obligations that are
imposed on a reservist today. A militiaman was ‘required to
attend drills and was available for call-up to repel Indian attacks
or invaders. The maximum term of active service was usually
three months, and in some instances the militia could not be
used beyond the borders of its colony. Despite the existence of
such draft laws, colonial militias were primarily made up of
volunteers.
The colonies were opposed to the idea of a common
defense establishment. Memories were still fresh of oppressive
acts by standing armies under Cromwell, Charles II, and James
II of England. The colonists’ fear that a large standing army
might result in loss of religious and political freedom denied
General Washington access to a centralized and compulsory
system of procuring men and supplies. Hence, the War of
Independence was fought almost entirely by volunteers who
were attracted by bounties either to the state militia or the
Continental Army. To the limited extent that state militias
resorted to the draft, its effect was mitigated by the exemptions
available to men who were married, who paid a commutation
fee, or who offered a substitute. The militia draft was more a
means of taxation than of compulsory procurement of
manpower.
Setting a pattern of rapid post-war demobilization which
has recurred throughout our history until World War II, the
Continental Congress reduced the standing army almost literally
to a corporal’s guard - some 80 men ~ soon after the War of
Independence. Such weakness left the Confederation unable to
suppress Shays’ Rebellion and protect against the continued
threat of foreign invasion and Indian attacks. To remedy the
defects of the Confederation, the Constitutional Convention
was called in 1787.
The new Constitution was ultimately a compromise
between two fears: (I) that the federal government would
remain too weak to maintain order or prevent invasion, and
(2) that the federal government might misuse its newly granted
power to curb the rights and relative independence of the
former colonies. In the field of military affairs, the compromise
took the form of balancing the independence of state militias
against the need for both a standing army and some centralized
control over the state militias. The Constitution gave the federal
government the powers to tax, to raise and maintain an army
and navy, and to declare war. The states retained the right to
raise the militia, to appoint its officers, and to supervise its
training in accordance with federal directives. The Constitution
explicitly provided that the militia could be placed under
federal control only to
“execute the Laws of the Union,
Suppress Insurrections and repel Invasions.” And the Second
Amendment identified the state militia as a bulwark of
freedom.
In 1790 Congress rejected Secretary of War Knox’s
proposal for a combination of universal militia service and a
federal draft. The question of conscription next arose during
the War of 18 12. After war was declared, President Madison and
Congress approved creation of a 166,000-man army composed
primarily of militiamen. However, three New England states
were opposed to the war and refused to conscript militia forces.
In addition, the regular army had difticultly recruiting. As a
result, the armed forces never reached the desired size and
sustained an almost unbroken series of defeats, culminating in
the burning of the nation’s capital in 18 14.
To reverse this tide of events, the President requested that
Congress conscript 40,000 men. The proposal was fiercely
debated. Finally, both the Senate and the House passed bills
that would have instituted a modified draft. Before the houses
of Congress could resolve their differences, however, the war
had ended.
The threat of conscription had created a real danger that
New England would secede from the Union. Interestingly, the
draft contemplated by both the Senate and the House was more
a
recruiting vehicle than a comprehensive system of
conscription. Both the House and Senate bills divided the
population either by state or nationwide into groups, each
representing a cross-section of socio-economic classes. Each
group would be compelled either to provide money or
“volunteers.” The volunteer would.be induced to serve by a
bounty raised among that group, or, if necessary, would be
selected from among its members. Thus both the House and the
Senate bills explicitly recognized that everyone should be taxed
according to his ability to pay in order to compensate the men
who actually did serve.
Once again, the end of the War. of 1812 saw a rapid
decrease in the size of the standing army. After 1815, a small
army was maintained ,until 1846 and the outbreak of the
Mexican War. Although it lasted more than two years, neither
conscripts nor the state militia were used to fight this war.
The Civil War, the greatest conflict ever waged on this
continent, was largely fought by volunteers on both sides. When
war was declared, the Union Army had fewer than 16,000
officers and men. Within the first two years, more than one
million men answered the call to arms. Nevertheless, President
Lincoln proposed a national draft in early 1863 to ensure that
the necessary troops would be forthcoming. When it was
enacted in March, the draft immediately aroused widespread
resistance, which reached a bloody climax in the New York
161
draft riots. The street fighting left more than 1,000 dead.
Like the draft proposed during the War of 18 12, the Civil
War draft was not a “pure” system of conscription. A draftee
could provide a substitute or initially purchase an exemption
for $300. Although conscription accounted for about 250,000
of the 3,667.OOO men who served in the Union Army, only
some 46.000 were actually drafted into personal service. Of the
balance of those subject to the draft, almost 87,000 purchased
an exemption and more than 116,000 provided substitutes.
True draftees accounted for only 2.3 prrccnt of the military
manpower raised by the North.
In theory, the South had universal conscription. Recause
of a wide range of exemptions, however, only 170,000 men
were conscripts out of the I.2 million who served in the
Confederate Army.
In the South and the North alike, therefore, the draft was
not a true system of conscription or a comprehensive system of
military manpower recruitment. Even so, the unpopularity of
the draft was apparent not only in the riots it touched off but
also in the widespread and disruptive draft resistance which
caused the suspension of habeas corpus in many areas.
Surprisingly, the constitutionality of the 1863 Conscription Act
was never tested in the federal courts. One fairly obvious reason
was the suspension of
huheus
corpus, which eliminated the
primary means of raising the constitutionality issue.
Still, there was an important state case - Knwdler V. Lane
‘~ in which
a divided Pennsylvania court upheld the
constitutionality of the 1863 Conscription Act. The court held
that the draft represented a valid recognition of, on the one
hand, the Government’s need to be able to wage a war and, on
the other, the individual citizen’s obligation to serve his
country.
Knee&r v. Lane was the first case upholding the
constitutionality of a wartime federal draft. The constitutional
question was not reconsidered until World War I. (In the
meantime, the United States used only volunteers to fight the
brief war against Spain in 1898.) In 1917, a comprehensive
draft law was passed immediately after the declaration of war
and precluded primary reliance on volunteers. Men were drafted
into federalized National Guard units and the constitutional
distinction between the army and the militia virtually
disappeared.
162
All enlistments were forbidden in 1918 so as not to upset
“the orderly process of selection” established by the preceding
year’s Act. Basically it evaluated the contribution of each
registrant to the war effort and made the least “valuable” the
most eligible. The effect of this procedure was certainly
inequitable. It meant that,
as in the Civil War, the poor
inevitably bore a disproportionate share of the burden of
service. For example, Negroes represented 13 percent of those
inducted although they accounted for only 9.6 percerit of total
registrants. Another unique aspect of the draft was its effect on
military pay. In the past, military pay had risen during a war
and had always exceeded comparable manufacturing earnings.
In World War I, almost total reliance on the draft relieved
Congress of the necessity for providing pay increases or
enlistment bonuses, even though the cost of living rose during
the war. For the first time, a soldier’s pay was less than that of
his civilian counterpart.
Opposition to the 1917 Act was less violent than the
response to the Civil War draft even though this was the first
measure that conscripted men for foreign service. Evasion
replaced open resistance, and more than 250,000 draftees failed
to appear for induction.
In contrast
to the Civil War experience, the
constitutionality of the 1917 Selective Draft Law was
immediately challenged in the federal courts. A number of cases
were consolidated by the Supreme Court and decided
unanimously in the Sekctiw Dru/‘t Law Cases. The significance
of this case has been magnified over time because the Supreme
Court has never again formally reconsidered the draft’s
constitutionality.
The Court upheld the law, citing as the only precedents
Knee&r v. Lune and several Confederate cases. The Court
noted that the Constitution granted Congress the power to
“raise and support armies
“; “to declare wars”; and “to make all
laws which shall be necessary and proper for
CarrYiW
into
execution the foregoing powers.” The Court argued that these
powers would be rendered ineffectual if any limit were imposed
upon their use. On that theory Congress had the power to
conscript men for war or any other legitimate purpose.
The Selec/ive Draft Law CUWS hold that the effective
exercise of the war power may require a wartime draft. After
World War I the draft expired and the nation again seemed
163
117.111, 70 IZ
content with a small standing army. Meanwhile, however, the
National Guard was brought into closer association with the
Regular Army through an amendment to the 1916 National
Defense Act. By that amendment, enacted in 1933, units which
met federal standards were paid by the Federal Government and
redesignated as units of the National Guard of the United
States. Thus, distinctions carefully drawn in the Constitution
were first blurred by Civil War conscription, then nearly
eradicated in World War I, and finally made to disappear
completely in 1933. Only those units not up to federal
standards would retain the status of a separate state militia.
In 1940, with war in progress in Europe, Congress passed a
draft law on September 14, 1940. The constitutionality of this
new law was at once challenged. Relying almost entirely on the
Selecfive Draft Luw Case.s, district courts in four major cases
rejected
the argument that a peacetime draft was
unconstitutional. Essentially, the courts reasoned that it was
unrealistic to construe the Constitution and the Selective Draft
Law Cuses to mean that an actual war must be declared before a
draft could be instituted. They pointed out that military
technology permitted the launching of massive surprise attacks
with devastating effect and concluded that it was essential for
the nation to be able to prepare adequately for war, as well as
to wage it, On the grounds that military necessity required a
broader
construction of Congress’ power under the
Constitution, the district courts decided that the power to raise
armies by conscription was no longer dependent upon the
power to declare war.
Legal challenges and general opposition to the draft
virtually ceased when Pearl Harbor plunged the United States
into war. As in World War I, the draft was the principal source
of military manpower, inducing many men to enlist and
providing directly more than IO million, or 61 percent, of the
16.5 million men who donned uniform.
The draft again enabled the Government to keep military
pay at levels significantly lower than comparable civilian pay.
The World War II Selective Service System established a
structure of deferments and exemptions which has remained
relatively unchanged down to the present day. The World War II
draft was the first genuinely popular system of conscription.
The draft law was allowed to expire on March 3 I, I947 as
part of the rapid demobilization typical of the nation’s behavior
164
in postwar periods. The military soon expressed concern that it
would not be able to obtain the necessary number of volunteers
which might. in part. have reflected a 23 percent decrease in the
A111ly’s recruiting budget. Simultaneously, President Truman
was vigorously promoting universal military training, which
Congress rejected in June, 1948. Instead, Congress passed a
draft act which was extended for short periods until the Korean
War. In January. 1949.
the Army ended the two-year
enlistment. raised standards higher, and refused to accept
volunteers with dependents. Nevertheless, young men continued
to enlist. Only 30,000 men were inducted during the period
from June, 1948, until the outbreak of the Korean War.
During the Korean War itself the draft provided 27 percent
of those in uniform. The Korean War caused Congress to extend
the I948 draft law; and in I95 I it continued the draft authority
for a four-year period. This four-year enactment completed the
evolution of the draft into a permanent part of the military
manpower procurement structure, even though the nation was
not fighting either a major or a declared war.
Until the United States’ commitment in Vietnam rose
sharply in 1965, the draft seemed to be generally accepted as a
necessary means of military manpower procurement. There was
virtually no debate or opposition to the extension of the
Universal Military Service and Training Act in 1955, 1959, and
1963. This was not too surprising. Following the Korean War,
military force levels decreased and the impact of the draft
declined while the number of draft age youth increased.
During the early 1960’s, 95 percent of those between the
ages of I8 and 35 were excluded from the I-A and I-A-O pool.
The Selective Service System found itself faced with the
problem of allocating an excess supply of eligible youth. Its
solution was to create new deferments OT expand the scope of
existing ones. In addition, induction standards were raised and
rejection rates increased during the early 1960’s. Meanwhile,
pay for first-term enlisted men remained below civilian levels.
Even so, young men continued to volunteer and the draft
call-ups remained relatively small. By 1964-65 only
5,000-10,000 men were being inducted each month, and the
average age of induction was almost 23.
The escalation of the Vietnam War in 1965 once again
focused attention on the draft. Monthly calls rose sharply to
20,000-30,000. Deferment criteria were tightened, and the
165
average age of inductees declined to 19. Of the 6 million men
who have served in the Armed Forces during the Vietnam war,
25 percent have been draftees. In the past few years numerous
articles and books have been written about the draft and both a
Congressional panel and a Presidential commission have been
created to study the Selective Service System. The Marshall
Commission, appointed by President Johnson in 1966,
published an extensive analysis of how the draft works and
concluded that the primary age of draft liability should be 19.
The Marshall Commission also urged a random system of
selection similar to the one that has since been adopted.
Both before and during the Korean War, there were cases
in which inductees questioned the draft’s legality. In general,
the federal courts either refused to reconsider the
constitutionality question or explicitly upheld peacetime
conscription as a legitimate and necessary measure to maintain
readiness for war. They usually took judicial notice of the
threatening international situation which has characterized the
cold war period and noted the need for a high degree of military
preparedness.
The Supreme Court has increasingly treated the
constitutional question as settled, Although the issue has not
been directly reconsidered, the Supreme Court has commented
in passing on the draft’s constitutionality. In a 1953 case the
Court said that the draft was a valid exercise of the war power
and must function in times of peril as well as during declared
wars. In 1968 the Supreme Court said in (I.S. v. O’Brien:
“The
Constitutional power of Congress to raise and support
armies and to make all laws necessary and proper to that end is
broad and sweeping The power of Congress to classify and
conscript manpower for military service is beyond question.”
The only citation in support of this firm conclusion was the
Selective Draft Law
Cases which dealt with a
wartime
draft.
The Founding Fathers feared conscription by the central
government would lead to unnecessary abridgment of personal
freedoms. Until the Civil War there was no draft; the system of
compulsory service instituted in 1863 was born of necessity and
was, in any event, far short of being comprehensive. In both
19 17 and 1940 the draft emerged again as a wartime expedient.
In 1948 the Selective Service System was revived to maintain
preparedness for cold war crises. After the Korean War, it
166
remained in existence and was once again an important source
of manpower when the nation became deeply involved in
Vietnam in 1965. Given the nation’s legal and political
traditions, the relatively recent phenomenon of a continuing
peacetime draft should be reevaluated.
CHAPTER 14
RECENT FOREIGN EXPERIENCE
WITH VOLUNTARISM
Great Britain, Canada, and, until 1965, Australia have all
manned their armed forces on a completely voluntary basis in
the recent past. Because the United States shares with these
countries a common cultural heritage, we have examined their
experiences with all-volunteer forces to anticipate problems
which might arise once the draft was ended in the United
States. Of course, due allowance must be made for differences
as well as similarities in evaluating the impact of ending the
draft in other societies.
The British experience is most helpful because they
maintain relatively larger forces than the other two countries.
Also their comparatively recent decision to abandon
conscription sheds light on the transition process as well as the
steady state experience.
Britain’s decision in 1957 to end conscription coincided
with a new defense policy emphasizing nuclear deterrence,
withdrawal from positions east of Suez, and a cutback in force
169
levels to 400,000 from 700,000. By 1960 the transition was
virtually completed, and all inductions ceased.
The elimination of conscription increased the average
length of service per man by approximately 200 percent, from
less than three years under the draft to roughly eight. While this
increase reflects in part use of long initial terms of service (6 or
9 years) it also shows that true volunteers were more likely to
stay in the service than conscripts.
Another important effect of ending conscription was the
decline in the proportion of troops in training from 21 percent
to 14 percent despite an increase in the average length of
training per man. Thus, an all-volunteer force has enabled the
British to maintain a higher proportion of troops in an effective
status.
British officials have said that the fully volunteer force is
more productive than a mixed force because of lower turnover
and the superior performance of more experienced servicemen.
A precise measure of this improved productivity is not possible,
but the British are able to assess any changes in the quality of
their armed forces by such measures as educational attainment
and aptitude scores. These show that the Royal Navy and Air
Force have experienced no decline in quality since conscription
ended, and that the quality of Army recruits has slipped
slightly ~ the proportion of volunteers falling in the lowest 30
percent aptitude category increasing by perhaps 2 percent.
Some British Army officers assert that improved motivation and
morale in the enlisted ranks since the end of conscription far
outweigh the loss of a relatively small number of high quality
draftees.
During the past several years the British have experienced a
decline in enlistments which is beginning to threaten the
achievement of target force levels. There appear to be four
reasons for this shortfall. First, more young men are staying in
school. Second, new government policies expanding the
availability of both apprentice and advanced training have made
civilian employment relatively more attractive to youth. The
latter factor is especially important in Britain because 15-17
year olds enlist primarily to get training. Third, British youths
are less willing to undertake long initial minimum tours of duty
ranging from five to twelve years. Fourth, there has been a
decline in the number of youths aged 16 to 24 in the
population.
170
To increase enlistments, the British Army introduced in
April. 1969 a shorter minimum enlistment of three years. The
initial response has been good and this shorter option has not
significantly reduced the number enlisting for longer terms.
Thus. relatively short-term enlistments, perhaps supplemented
by pay increases, could provide an adequate number of British
recruits in the foreseeable future.
Conscription in Australia ceased after World War II. During
the Korean War a system of Universal Military Training was
introduced requiring every qualified male to complete three
months of training and then serve in the Australian reserves.
The active duty forces never used these conscripts and only
volunteers fought in Korea and Malaya. This system ceased in
1958 and the Australian forces were manned exclusively by
volunteers. But, in October of 1964, the Australian government
decided to raise force levels from 49,000 to 76,000 by
instituting a draft by lottery.
Some have cited the Australian decision to return to a
draft as evidence that an all-volunteer force is not feasible for
the United States. There are several reasons why this argument
by analogy is inappropriate. First, the Australians have not
made a concerted effort to attract additional recruits on a
voluntary basis. Once the decision was made to use conscription
to raise force levels, no serious effort was made to increase
voluntary enlistments either by raising pay or redoubling
recruiting efforts. Second, the Australian economy is heavily
unionized and apprenticeship programs requiring four or more
years deplete the pool of men available for military service.
Third, Australia has enjoyed a rapid growth in its economy (the
unemployment rate is about I percent) which makes civilian
jobs relatively more attractive than military service. Finally,
civilian earnings significantly exceed military pay rates. Civilians
receive over-time and other supplementary compensation in
excess of the common wage rates set by the government for
both the military and the civilian economy.
The Australians could have expanded the size of the
Armed Forces on a voluntary basis by raising pay and
reorganizing recruiting.Given the important differences between
the two countries, one cannot conclude that the Australian
experience shows that the United States would be unable to
attract enough recruits on a voluntary basis if energetic and
171
efficient recruiting were combined with competitive rates of
pay.
The Canadian Armed forces have always been entirely
voluntary except for the period from I940 to early 1945. The
Canadian forces presently number slightly less than 100,000
men, supported by an annual inflow of about 12,000 men. The
quality of the entrants is remarkably high; almost all fall within
the upper half of the population as measured by mental
aptitude. Military pay more nearly approximates civilian
earnings - the monthly pay for privates is $225. Attracting
recruits has posed no problem in Canada, and recruiting officers
suggest that the number of enlistments could be doubled or
tripled with no difficulty.
The Canadian armed force is relatively small; it is roughly
equivalent, on a population basis, to an American force of one
million men. However, budgetary constraints rather than
recruiting difficulties are responsible for the size of Canada’s
forces.
The recent experiences of the British, Australian, and
Canadian Armed Forces suggest that competitive wages will
attract an adequate quantity and quality of volunteers. There is
no evidence in any of these countries that all-volunteer forces
are alienated from the rest of society.
172
CHAPTER 15
ALTERNATIVES TO AN
All-VOLUNTEER FORCE
What are the alternatives both to the present system of
conscription and to an all-volunteer armed force? In this
chapter the Commission weighs various suggestions which have
been raised.
One proposed alternative is National Service. Many
National Service proposals involve purely voluntary service.
Such proposals are actually supplements, rather than
alternatives, to an all-volunteer armed force. Other proposals
would require service on the part of all those eligible. In our
analysis of alternatives to an all-volunteer force, we have
considered only the mandatory proposals. While these
mandatory National Service proposals differ in detail, they
would generally require service of all youth, though not
necessarily in the military. Most would permit individuals to
choose how they would serve from among a limited set of
alternatives.
Advocates of National Service have suggested a variety of
approaches. Some have urged that literally everyone, male and
173
female, be required to serve, even those who are physically or
mentally disabled or morally unfit. Because of the high cost of
formal and on-the-job training, National Service cm a one-year
basis would be prohibitively expensive. National Service for two
years would mean employing almost 8,000,OOO young people,
or 4,000,OOO if females are excluded. If longer terms of service.
were instituted for more attractive types of duty, these numbers
would be even larger. Assuming a very modest annual cost for
each participant of $4,000 to $5,000, the cost of such a
program would be a minimum of $16 billion, and perhaps as
much
as $40 billion - an amount equal to the entire current
manpower budget of the Department of Defense. In short, the
numbers
of men and cost of mandatory National Service are
staggering.
Advocates of other proposals argue that some individuals
should be excused from serving. If that were the case,
deferments and exemptions would proliferate just as they have
under the draft. A new Selective Service System would be
required to administer a non-universal National Service
program.
Regardless of the administrative procedure used, a
National Service program would not be able to prevent glaring
inequities among those who served. Not all National Service
would
be
equally desirable (or repugnant), and those with
higher qualifications would probably find their way into the
more desirable positions. If this inequity were minimized by
introducing a system of differential terms of service, the ranks
of those engaged in National Service and its cost would increase
further.
The appeal of mandatory National Service, in large
measure, arises from the manifest inequities in the present
system of conscription. It promises to eliminate these inequities
by forcing a larger proportion of the populace to serve in some
capacity ~ and hence to pay a tax-in-kind. In practice it not
only perpetuates such an inequitable tax, but extends it to a
larger segment of the population. The cure for inequity is not
its extension.
Above all, mandatory National Service is coercive and
involuntary. Such a system of universal conscription would
require all those eligible to serve within a specified period of
time. If insufficient numbers proved willing to enlist in the
military or volunteer for other onerous types of government
174
service, some would be compelled to serve in these less desirable
capacities. In essence, mandatory National Service requires
forced labor. Although motivated by a genuine interest in the
nation’s welfare, advocates of mandatory National Service are
suggesting a compulsory system which is more consistent with a
totalitarian than a democratic heritage. If the service that youth
would render is important and valuable enough to merit public
support, it can and should be financed through general taxation
like other government programs.
Universal Military Training resembles mandatory National
Service, for it contemplates conscription of all those eligible. It
is undesirable for generally the same reasons as mandatory
National Service. For one thing, it would impose on the military
more untrained personnel than can be productively employed.
A one-year tour of duty - the usual term proposed - is
prohibitively expensive in view of the very short period an
individual would serve after receiving costly training. Assuming
current eligibility standards, a two-year tour would force on the
services more than 2,000,OOO non-career persons at any given
time. Whether or not UMT is unconstitutional, it would
definitely represent a sharp break with the nation’s traditional
respect for individual freedom.
The lottery draft recently adopted is at best an expedient.
It is important to recognize that the tax inequity implicit in the
draft is not eliminated by substituting a lottery for present
methods of selection. In theory, the lottery makes it equally
probable that any individual might be selected from those
eligible to serve. It thus aims at equity in selection. But equity
in selection is not equity in service. Those few who are selected
to serve, whether at random or otherwise, still pay a large
tax-in-kind in order to reduce taxes for the majority. Moreover,
it is by no means clear that the lottery achieves greater equity
even in selection. No doubt one can find many instances of
inequitable treatment of draftees under Selective Service. Even
so, it does not logically follow that the system as a whole is
more unjust than a random system. Many local draft boards and
some of the general rules for deferments and exemptions
actually do more to achieve equity than the system of random
selection. Local boards can and do take into account an
individual’s particular circumstances.
The lottery reduces the number of draft induced
volunteers and thereby necessitates an increase in the number of
175
draftees. Because draftees serve two-year terms and volunteers
three, personnel turnover and the attendant costs are increased.
The lottery offers one advantage over Selective Service.
When it is combined with the proposal to expose potential
draftees to a one-time jeopardy at age 19, it reduces the
uncertainty confronting an individual about whether he will be
required to serve, and thereby mitigates the distortion in career
and personal planning endured under Selective Service.
176
APPENDIX A
BUDGET EXPENDITURES FOR
ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCES
This appendix describes the methods and assumptions
employed to derive estimated budgets for all-volunteer and
mixed forces of equal effective strengths. The mixed forces
examined employ a 19-year-old lottery as the means of selecting
draftees. Limitations of space preclude an exhaustive analysis of
estimation procedures. These detailed analyses will be reported
in a forthcoming volume containing background studies.
SUPPLY OF ENLISTED PERSONNEL
In our analyses of mixed forces we have assumed that only
the Army will have to conscript men, and then only for its
enlisted ranks. Sufficient reservists, officers, and enlisted men
for the other services were presumed to be available on a
“voluntary” basis, even though some of them will be
draft-motivated. These assumptions are consistent with recent
experience.
177
Procedurally, monthly draft calls are determined as a
residual; they are the difference between requirements for
Army recruits and the number of Regular Army enlistments.
Given requirements, draft calls will be negatively related to
enlistments; the higher the enlistments, the smaller the draft
calls. If one looks at the data, however, he will find that draft
calls have been positively related to enlistments. Higher draft
calls have been accompanied by increased enlistments, because
many potential draftees prefer the advantages of enlisting to the
prospect of being an inductee. When requirements rise, the
probability of being drafted rises and induces an increase in
draft-motivated enlistments. Our projections for the mixed
forces incorporate this type of supply response. Army
enlistments rise by 235 men per year in response to an increase
in draft calls of 1,000 individuals. By shortening the period of
draft liability, the I9-year-old lottery now in effect will tend to
reduce the flow of draft-motivated volunteers relative to calls
(independently of the response to varying levels of draft calls).
In our projections the voluntary enlistment rates experienced
under Selective Service have been reduced by 12.5 percent to
provide for the effect of the l9-year-old lottery.
The average annual flow of voluntary enlistments under
the former Selective Service draft for the period FY 1963-65 is
shown at the top of table A-I. During this period, mental group
IV annual accessions (men with mental test scores between the
10th and 30th percentiles) were controlled by the services and
limited to a total of about 15 percent of enlistments and
inductions. Voluntary enlistments and Army inductions of men
in mental groups I-III are expressed as percentages of the 17-20
year-old male population on line 4 of table A-l. These are
enlistment and induction rates.
The “voluntary” enlistments in FY 1963 through I965
included many draft-motivated volunteers who indicated in the
1964 Department of Defense survey that if there had been no
draft they would not have volunteered for active military
service. Moreover, the inductees included some who said they
were also true volunteers, i.e., they would have enlisted in the
absence of a draft. The percentage of true volunteers (line 7 of
table A-I) represents the percentage of first-term enlisted men
who stated in the 1964 survey that they probably or definitely
would have volunteered in the absence of a draft. By
multiplying lines 4 and 7, we arrive at the estimated true
178
I PC-LIZ A-I.-voluntary enlistments and Army inductions by service
z
Regular
Army Army
Department
Marine F0r.X
of
enlistments
inductions Navy corps
Air Defense 1
Number of voluntary enlistments,
annual average FY 1963-65 fOOO1
Mental groips
I-III ~~..~~~:~~ . . . . .
Mental group
IV...-.--..~~--~
All mental groups...~.~----~~ ~~~
Voluntary enlistment rates under
Selective Service draft: FY 1963-&5 2
Mental groups I-III ~~~ ~~.~~.
2
Mental group
IV ~~.~~~ ~.~~
All mental groups ~~~ ~~~.~
Percentage of true volunteers (k)~ .._.......
True voluntary enlistment rates
in the absence of a draft
Mental groups I-III ~~~ ~~~~~~~.
All mental
groups~~~ ~~~~~~~
Number of true enlistments,
annual averages FY 1977-79 3
Mental groups
I-III ~~~~.~ ~~..~
Mental group IV.~~-.~~~..--~~ .._. ~~~~~~
95.3 73.3
76.3 29.1 01.5 262.2
7.3
35.9 6.7
1.0 5.9 23.6
102.6 109.2
65.0 30.9 87.4 305.9
1.56 1.20
1.25
0.46 1.33
4.62
0.12
0.59 0.14
0.03
0.10 0.39
- -
1.66
1.79 - 1.39 -
0.51 1.43
5.01
56.6 12.3 63.4
69.9 56.6
59.8
1.03
-
0.79 0.33 0.75 2.91
1.29 -
0.99
0.42 0.94
3.63
volunteer enlistment rate of men in mental groups 1 through 111
(line 81, assuming that the draft is abolished with no change in
the ratio of’ military to civilian pay.
For our projections we assumed that each service would
accept up to a
maximum
of 20 percent mental group IV
enlistments. The fraction of mental group IV enlistments was
allowed to fall below the 20 percent maximum whenever the
supply of true volunteers exceeded requirements.
The flow of true volunteers,in the absence of a draft and
with no pay changes in the period FY 1977-79, was estimated
by applying the true voluntary enlistment rates to the projected
17 to 20 year-old male population of 8,589,OOO men in this
period; this is presented in the bottom panel of table A-I.
Several statistical studies were made to estimate the
responsiveness of supplies of voluntary enlistments to changes
in the ratio of military to civilian pay. In two time series
studies, quarterly data on Army and Air Force enlistment rates
were related to the ratio of military to civilian pay, draft
pressure, and unemployment. In a third cross-sectional study,
regional differences in enlistment rates were related to
differences in civilian pay and unemployment. In these studies,
the unemployment variable was insignificant, and was thus
ignored in our projections. The elasticity of supply (defined as
the percentage change in voluntary enlistments resulting from a
given percentage change in military pay) i’, hich was estimated in
these studies, ranged from I to 2.2; i.e., a one percent increase-
in military pay can be expected to raise voluntary enlistments
by I to 2.2 percent.
The pay recommendations reported in chapter 5 of this
volume would produce the pay levels for first-term enlisted men
shown in the top panel of table A-II. An elasticity of +I.25
(which is on the low end of the range found in our studies) was
used to estimate the effect of this pay increase on the supply of
voluntary enlistments in the absence of a draft. The true
voluntary enlistment rates with no pay increase E0 and with the
higher recommended pay rates g are shown in the first two
lines of table A-III.
If the draft were ended in FY 1971 with no changes in
military pay (i.e. enlistment rates EO apply), the flow of true
volunteers would sustain the enlisted active duty force strengths
shown in lines 4 and 5 of table A-III. The larger flows of
TABLE A-Il.-Annual compensation of military personnel, by service 1
[in constant 1969 prices]
TABLE A-Ill.-Voluntary enlislmenf rafes and sustainable force sMengrh in the absence of a draft
[in thousands]
Army Navy
Marine Air Department
Corps FOKX of Defense
1.285 0.989
0.416 0.943
3.633
1.919 1.427 ,621 1.356 5.323
1.493 1.443 1.492 1.436 1.465
620.1 553.9 176.9 558.4 1.909.3
649.0
604.4
191.5 571.4 2,016.3
784.8 690.5 234.4 6839 2.393.6
677.9 798.2 268.3 753.5 2.697.9
624.3
691.9
827.1
439.0
487.2
518.6
148.0 471.2 1.682.5
178.6 528.6 1.886.3
184.8 558.9 2.089.4
volunteers that would be attracted by the higher recommended
pay levels could support the larger active duty forces shown in
lines 6 and 7. For comparative purposes, the four equilibrium
all-volunteer forces are presented in the bottom panel of table
A-III. Given the recommended pay increase, the sustainable
all-volunteer forces attain levels by FY 1980 that are above the
target levels for the 2.0, 2.25, and 2.5 million man forces,
Indeed, a 2.0 million man force could be raised with no pay
change provided true volunteers exhibit the projected higher
reenlistment rates of the model. It should be emphasized that
these conclusions pertain to the force in existence in 1980, and
not to the force strengths in the intervening years. In order to
maintain a force of 2.0 million men during the transition years
FY 1973 to 1976, some modest pay increases would be needed.
The number of accessions required to meet any given force
strength objective is a function of losses of active duty
personnel. Men are separated from the Armed Forces for
various reasons such as medical disability, unsuitable
performance, hardship, retirement, and most importantly,
failure to m-enlist after completing an obligated term. The vast
majority of enlisted and officer losses occur at the end of the
first term of service. The loss rates which would be experienced
by an all-volunteer force are expected to be considerably lower
than those in a mixed force. Two-year draftees would be
replaced by three-year regular enlistments. Moreover,
Department of Defense surveys of enlisted men support the
conclusion that draft-motivated volunteers exhibit lower
re-enlistment rates than true volunteers, Finally, the services’
experience with proficiency pay and regular and variable
re-enlistment bonuses has shown that pay increases for the
career enlisted force can raise re-enlistment rates. Reference to
table A-II reveals that the recommended pay increase needed to
move to an all-volunteer force would raise the pay of
second-term enlisted men by roughly 7 percent.
The responsiveness of supplies of first-term reenlistments
to military pay changes (referred to above as the elasticity of
supply) was estimated in three studies. All three studies
reported elasticity estimates which ranged from 2.0 to 4.5; i.e.,
a IO percent increase in the pay of second-term enlisted men
results in reenlistment rates that are 20 to 45 percent above
their previous levels. Again, the elasticity estimates used in our
183
projections were taken from the lower end of the intervals
reported in the three studies (line 2 of table A-IV).
Even if the draft were ended with no pay changes, our
studies indicate that reenlistment rates would rise when all
recruits voluntarily enter the service. The estimated percentage
increase in reenlistments when the mixed inputs of true and
draft-motivated volunteers are replaced by true volunteers is
shown in the third line of table A-IV.
TABLE A-IV.-Estimated first-term reenlistment rates
in mixed and all-volunteer forces
Marine Air
Army Navy corps Force
1. Relative increase in second
term (MI/M,,)
pay ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
1.078 1.040 1.058 1.055
2. Elasticity of supply-B ~~~~~~~~ 2.43 2.14 2.00 2.38
3. Percentage increase due to
all-volunteer recruits
..~
39 25 20 47
Estimated first-term
reenlistment rates
4. Mixed force continued
draft (ro)
~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~..~~~~~~~~~~~~
0.175 0.197 0.140 0.184
5. Transition period (r,)
~~~~~~~~~~~~
,210 .214 ,158 ,209
6. All-volunteer force Ire)
..~
,292 ,288 ,187 .307
The projections of draft calls and required accessions for
the mixed forces, assuming a continued lottery draft and no pay
changes,
were based on loss rates incorporating the
re-enlistment rates of line 4. In the move to an all-volunteer
force, it was recommended that military pay be increased at the
beginning of FY 1971. If the recommended pay raise is
implemented on July 1, 1970, the group which receives the
largest pay increase (first-term enlisted men) includes a
considerable number of draftees and draft-motivated volunteers.
It is unlikely, therefore, that first-term reenlistment rates will
immediately climb to their equilibrium levels. Some
improvement is anticipated, since the pay raise will make
military service more attractive in relation to competing civilian
jobs. Hence, for the transition period, we have used the
re-enlistment rates shown in line 5. The all-volunteer
reenlistment rates (line 6) reflect both the shift to all-volunteer
recruits and the higher pay for enlisted men.
184
The loss rates used in our projections generate the ilnnual
personnel turnover rates for the period FY 1977 through I97Y
shown in table A-V. With a draft and with 47 percent of Army
accessions projected to be draftees, we estimate that the annual
Army enlisted personnel turnover rate will be 27.5 percent. Due
to higher retention rates, an all-volunteer Army will have a
reduced turnover rate for enlisted men of only 17.9 percent per
year. Less striking reductions in turnover are expected to take
place in the other services and for officer personnel.
TABLE
A-V.-Projecfed annual turnover rates of mixed and
all-volunteer forces’
[for effective strength of 2.5 million men]
Comparing sustainable force strengths to target force levels
(table A-III), or comparing required accessions to the flow of
true volunteers, confirms the fact that the Army is likely to
suffer the largest manpower deficits if the draft is ended. The
recruitment problem which confronts an all-volunteer force is
an Army problem. This is not surprising since the Army is the
only service which has consistently relied on draft calls to meet
its manpower requirements.
In estimating the levels of military pay needed to attract
the requisite numbers of recruits, we have concentrated on
Army enlisted manpower deficits. This procedure involves a safe
assumption that if the Army’s manpower demands can be met,
the other services will certainly be able to staff their forces with
qualified men. This procedure also tends to overstate the
requisite increase in military
pay, since it tacitly assumes that
excess supplies of enlistment applicants to the other services
would
not
spill-over into the Army.
185
OFFICER SUPPLY
Under conscription, the number of applicants for most
officer procurement programs has exceeded requirements. It is
anticipated that this situation will prevail even in the absence of
a draft for the highly selective programs such as the. military
academies and ROTC (Reserve Officers Training Corps)
scholarships. Other programs such as the non-scholarship ROTC
and various college-graduate, officer-candidate schools may,
however, experience shortfalls. Because the flow of actual
entrants has been less than the number who would have
volunteered under a draft, data on actual officer accessions do
not provide a satisfactory basis for projecting future supplies.
The supplies of officers to an all-volunteer force depend
critically on three factors: (1) the intensity of the Vietnam War,
(2) the presence or absence of the draft, and (3) the ratio of
military to civilian pay. An econometric model using voluntary
ROTC enrollment data was developed to estimate the
quantitative effects of these three factors. The voluntary
enrollment rate of male freshmen at colleges where ROTC
participation is not compulsory provides us with a supply
variable free of the demand constraints which affect other
officer procurement programs. The Army has not limited
freshman ROTC enrollments, and hence, the enrollment rates
reflect the decisions of youths at these colleges.
The non-scholarship ROTC program has been the major
source of Army officers, and the Army will probably have the
severest officer recruitment problem in an all-volunteer force.
This assumption is plausible since the Army is the only service
which has offered a two-year obligated term (and at one time a
six-month term) for newly commissioned officers. The other
services have adopted three, four and five year obligated terms
even for ROTC officers. The estimated pay increase needed to
attract enough Army officers should be sufficient to attract an
adequate number of officers to the other services.
Army ROTC freshman enrollment rates exhibited a sharp
decline during the last half of the 1960’s so that by 1970, they
were about half of the rate in 1964. This decline closely
correlates with casualty rates in Vietnam. De-escalation should
reverse the trend in FY 1972 and lead to the projected
enrollment rates shown in table A-VI. This anticipated reversal
in the freshman enrollment rate will, however, have a delayed
186
TABLE A-W-Actual and projected proportion ot male freshmen
enrollments in Army ROTC programs in voluntary schools 1
196&90
impact since an increase in the supply of newly commissioned
officers will not occur until four years later.
Elimination of the draft will result in a loss of
draft-motivated volunteers in Army ROTC programs. Column 2
in table A-VI shows the projected trend in enrollment rates if
the draft is continued. The percentage of draft-motivated
first-term Army officers who entered through an ROTC
program was estimated to be 45 percent in the 1964
Department of Defense survey and 56 percent in the 1968
survey. The lower draft- motivation factor, 45 percent, was
employed in projections of Army ROTC officer supplies, on the
assumption that pre-Vietnam conditions would prevail during
the decade of the 1970’s.
The ratio of officer pay to civilian pay of college graduates
was found to be a significant variable explaining differences in
ROTC enrollment rates. The pay schedules recommended by
the Commission will raise the pay of first-term officers by
approximately 25 percent (table A-II). Our studies indicate that
187
this pay raise should increase the supply of Army ROTC
officers by 29 percent. The expected effect of the increased pay
on enrollment rates is shown in table A-VII. When the projected
voluntary enrollment rates of table A-VII with the pay increase,
are applied to the expanding pool of male college freshmen, the
Army meets its officer accession requirements. (The latter
statement assumes that the ROTC scholarship program will be
expanded as recommended from 5,500 scholarships per service
to 10,000 scholarships.)
ADDITIONAL BUDGET EXPENDITURES FOR AN
ALL-VOLUNTEER FORCE
Comparisons of the average budgets required to sustain
mixed forces of 2.0, 2.25, 2.5 and 3.0 million men, and to
sustain all-volunteer forces with the same effective strengths for
FY 1977 through 1979 are. given in tables A-VIII, A-IX, A-X,
and A-XI. We have chosen the period FY 1977 through 1979 as
fairly representing the differences in budget requirements for
the mixed and all-volunteer forces. By then, accession
requirements will have stabilized, and most of the savings
accruing to an all-volunteer force will have taken effect. All of
the comparisons are made in constant 1970 dollars, that is,
there is no allowance for inflation. The pay profiles used to
188
TABLE A-VIII.-Estimated budget expenditures for mixed and
all-volunteer forces FY 1977-1979
[for force of 2.0 million men in billions of 1970 dollars]
All-
Mixed volunteer
force
force Increment
--
$13.20
4.21
17.41
.69
.29
.98
.a3
.25
1.08
.13
.08
.21
19.68
51.49
.09
1.58
-.15
- .Ol
-.16
.12
.Ol
.13
.13
.08
.21
1.76
- .29
1.47
compute total pay and allowance are those set forth in chapter
5. For all of the mixed forces, we have used estimated pay for
FY 1971, which includes an across-the-board increase of 8
percent. For the 2.0, 2.25, and 2.5 million men all-volunteer
forces we have used the pay profile recommended by the
Commission. The 3.0 million man force requires a further pay
increase. In explaining tables A-VIII through A-XI, we have
focussed on the 2.5 million man force only as an example.
Estimates of the military pay and allowances of enlisted
men, officers, and uniformed women (including the imputed
value of income-in-kind) for a mixed force of 2.5 million men in
the period FY 1977 through 1979, are given at the top of table
189
TABLE A-IX.-Estimated budget expenditures for mixed and
all-volunteer forces FY 1977-79
(for force of 2.25 million men in billions of 1970 dollars]
Mixed
force
All-
volunteer
force Increment
$14.46 $1.76
4.64 .lO
19.10
1.86
.84 -.18
.35 - .Ol
1.19 -.19
.93 .14
.27 .03
1.20 .17
.16 .16
.08 .08
.24 .24
21.73 2.08
-24
15. Net bugetary increase ..~ 1.74
A-X.
Because
of lower personnel turnover, an all-volunteer force
can have 56.5 thousand less men than a mixed force of 2.5
million and still provide the same effective strength. In spite of
this reduction in size, which considered alone reduces budget
requirements by $678 million, the military pay and allowances
budget for an all-volunteer force is higher than that for the
equivalent mixed force for two reasons. First, annual pay rates
are higher - especially in the first four years of service.
Second, the greater retention of an all-volunteer force means
the force is more experienced; hence a larger fraction of the
men are receiving higher pay rates. Only 38.0 percent of the
mixed force is projected to have more than four years of service
as compared to 44.6 percent for the all-volunteer force. We
190
TABLE A-X.-Estimated budget expenditures for mixed and
all-volunteer forces FY 1977-1979
[tar
force ot
2.5 million men in billions of 1970 dollars]
Mixed
force
All-
VOlU&X?r
torte Increment
Military pay and allowances:
active-duty forces
1. Enlisted . ~~~ -...... $13.67
2. Officers ..~~ .._..._ .._... . . ~~. 5.02
3. Total compensation . . . . . 16.69
Training and turnover related
travel costs
‘4. Enlisted . . . .._ ~... 1.26
5. Officers .~~ .._.... .._.... . -~~ .._. ~~~ .41
6. Total training and travel costs 1.66
Reserve forces
7. Military pay/allowances ~.~~.. .66
6. Training and travel costs ..~ -.... .22
9. Total reserve forces ~~~ 1.06
Other budget increments
10. Proficiency pay
(first-term enlisted men) ....~~.~~~ -
11. Medical personnel ..~~~~~ ~.~
-
12. Miscellaneous - .~ ._...... . ~.~ .._...
13. Total other items . ~~~~...~ -
14. Total . . . . ~.~ .._..... ~~~ . . .
21.43
15. Less added Federal
income taxes ~~~ .._.. . . . . . . .._...
$15.78 $2.11
5.15 .I3
20.93 2.24
.95 - .30
.39 - .02
1.34 - .32
1.03 .17
.29 .07
1.32 .24
.I4 .I4
.16 .16
.06 .06
.36 .36
23.97 2.54
- .42
16. Net budgetary increase . . . . 2.12
estimate that the pay and allowances budget for an all-volunteer
force during FY 1977 through 1979 will on average be $2.2
billion higher than would be required for an equally effective
mixed force of 2.5 million men.
Although tne move to an all-volunteer force entails a
higher military pay and allowances budget, the training and
transient budgets, which are largely determined by the flow of
new accessions, will fall. Each enlisted recruit receives about
one-half of a year of basic military and technical training. The
size of the training command can be reduced with the move to a
191
TABLE A-XI.-Esfimated budget expenditures for mixed and
a//-vokmfeer forces FY 1977-1979
[for iorce of 3.0 million men in billions of 1970 dollars]
All-
volunteer
force Increment
520.41 54.62
6.04 .47
26.45 5.09
1.16 - .47
.46 -.03
1.62 - .50
1.19 .29
.28 .15
1.47
.44
.21 .21
.20
.20
.08 .08
.49
.49
30.03 5.52
-.97
4.55
voluntary force because fewer accessions are required to sustain
the all-volunteer force. The manpower savings and resulting
reduction in the military pay and allowances budget. have
already been incurporated into the analysis by the reduction of
56.500 men in the all-volunteer force of 2.5 million men. In
addition to manpower costs. substantial budget outlays are also
needed to finance the material and capital costs of the training
command. It was estimated in our study that the material and
variable costs over and above the personnel costs of enlisted
men are about $2,500 per recruit.
192
Approximately 25,000 postions in the 2.5 million man
mixed force must be set aside to accommodate the accession,
training. and separation moves of enlisted men. With its lower
personnel turnover, an all-volunteer force can economize on the
number of positions needed to accomplish these moves, in
addition to generating savings in direct travel costs. The direct
travel costs per recruit that were paid in 1968 are estimated to
be $268. The travel costs per officer accession are even
higher ~ $1 ,150 - because the typical officer is married and
must move dependents as well as household belongings. At a
force level of 2.5 million men, it is estimated that savings in
direct travel costs will average $70 million in FY 1977 through
1979.
The cost of training officers varies widely among different
officer procurement programs. It runs as high as $50,000 for an
officer trained at the military academies, and is approximately
$12,000 for officers commissioned through officer candidate
schools. Flight training is an even more expensive proposition,
and Department of Defense estimates range from around
$50,000 for helicopter pilots to $250,000 for jet fighter pilots.
In our projections, it was assumed that the number of officers
commissioned through the academies and ROTC scholarship
programs would be the same in both the mixed and
all-volunteer forces. The college and non-college graduate
officer candidate schools have historically been the sources
which equilibrated the supply and demand for officers. (Strictly
speaking, the involuntary recall of reserve officers has borne
much of the brunt of changing officer requirements, but this
would also be the case in an all-volunteer force.) The training
cost of $12,000 per officer for the officer candidate programs
was used to estimate the variable training costs for officers
shown in table A-X.
When the training and travel cost savings are subtracted
from the incremental budget expenditures for military pay and
allowances, the additional budget expenditures for the active
duty all-volunteer force (excluding medical doctors and
dentists) is estimated to be $1.92 billion per year in FY 1977
through 1979.
In order to sustain the reserve forces on an all-volunteer
basis, it will be necessary to raise the reserve forces budget by
$240 million. Other budget items (for the medical corps,
additional recruiting expenses, establishment of proficiency pay
193
for first-term enlisted men, etc.) add another $380 million. The
total increment is, therefore, estimated to be $2.54 billion per
year.
The implementation of the recommended basic pay rates
and other items of compensation will result in an increase in
federal income taxes paid by individuals in the active duty and
reserve forces. These added taxes should properly be .deducted
in calculating the incremental budget expense of an
all-volunteer force. For FY 1977 through 1979 they are
estimated to be $420 million.
Thus the net additional budget expense required to
maintain an all-volunteer force equivalent in strength to a 2.5
million man mixed force on a stable, continuing basis is about
$2.12 billion per year. For the 2.0 million man force the
comparable figure is $1.47 billion; for the 2.25 million man
force it is $1.74 billion; and for the 3.0 million man force,
$4.55 billion.
SMALLER FORCES
The military pay increases recommended by the
Commission (which were used to calculate the military pay and
allowances of the all-volunteer forces) would support active
duty forces that are larger than the force strength objectives for
forces of 2.25 and 2.0 million men even during the transition
years FY 1973 through 1976. Our projections imply that if the
recommended pay increases were put into effect, the services
could raise mental qualification standards, thereby reducing the
percentage of mental group IV enlistments below the 20
percent maximum assumed in the study. In fact, the projected
flows of true volunteers imply that nearly all recruits could be
drawn from the top three mental groups. On the other hand,if
the Army continued to accept up to 20 percent mental group
IV enlistments, our projections show that military pay levels
could be reduced while meeting the strength objectives during
the transition, for the 2.25 and 2.0 million man forces. The
estimated Army recruitment deficits together with an elasticity
of supply of 1.25 imply that the minimum increases in
first-term pay needed to maintain the 2.25 and 2.0 million men
forces during the transition years were 24.4 and 11.8 percent
respectively. If these lower pay levels had been adopted for
all-volunteer forces of 2.25 and 2.0 million men (and the
194
Commission does
not
recommend this), the military pay and
allowances budget for enlisted men could have been reduced by
$345 and $714 million below the figures shown in tables A-VIII
and A-IX, respectively.
MAINTAINING FORCE LEVELS AT THREE MILLION
MEN
It was noted earlier that the recommended pay scales
would
not
attract enough recruits to maintain an all-volunteer
force of equivalent strength to a 3.0 million man mixed force.
The data in table A-111 indicate that the overall deficit in
enlisted force strengths would be only 3.8 percent in FY 1975.
The deficits between target and sustainable force levels are,
however, unevenly distributed, being largest, 25.0 percent, for
the Army. To eliminate this deficit, first-term enlisted pay
would have to be approximately 17 percent higher than the
Commission has recommended in this report. The pay of career
enlisted men and officers would also have to be advanced to
prevent inversions in the pay profiles. When these higher rates
of pay are applied to the estimated length of service
distributions of enlisted men and officers, the military pay and
allowances budget for an all-volunteer force is $5.0 billion
higher than for the equivalent mixed force. The summary of
these budget estimates appears in table A-Xl.
RESERVE FORCES BUDGETS
The estimated average annual manpower budgets for each
of the four equally effective all-volunteer and mixed reserve
forces for FY 1977 to 1979 is given in table A-XII. The mixed
force estimates use 1970 compensation profiles, including the
assumed 8.0 percent pay increase. Compensation for the three
smaller all-volunteer reserve forces was computed using the
Commission’s recommended pay levels. Compensation for the
largest reserve force is based on the pay levels required for the
3.0 million man all-volunteer active force.
195
TABLE A-XII.-Reserve manpower expenditures
[millions]
Unmodified FY 1977-79
stable reserve force. _
Draft All-volunteer Difference
2.00 Force
Military pay and allowances $ 714.1
Personnel-related 2
~.~~~~~~ ~. 236.1
Total .~~~...~
952.2
2.25 Force
Military pay and allowances 792.4
Personnel-related = ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~..
241.7
$ 634.2 $120.1
246.0 9.9
1,062.Z 130.0
927.7 135.3
267.9
26.2
Total ~~~.~~ ~.~... 1,034.l 1,195.6
161.5
2.50 Force
Military pay and allowances ~. 664.9 1,025.6
160.7
Personnel-related 2
.~~~.~~~..~.~~ 220.5 292.7 72.2
Total ~~~~.~~~.~~~ ~~~~...~..~ ~~~.. 1,065.4 1.316.3 232.9
3.00 Force
Military pay and allowances
698.7
1,193.5
294.8
Personnel-related 2 .~~...~~~~~~~~~~..
127.9 262.6 154.9
- __ -
Total .~~~...~ ~. 1,026.6 1,476.3
449.7
Modified FY 1977-79
stable reswve force
Draft
All-volunteer Difference
2.00 Force
Military pay and allowances ~. $ 633.0
$ 744.2 5111.2
Personnel-related 2 ~~~~ 167.1 210.0 22.9
Total .~~~..~~..~~...~..~~ ~~~~~ 620.1
954.2 134.1
2.25 Force
Military pay and allowances
701.6 626.3 124.7
Personnel-related 2
~~..~~.. 164.4 224.9 40.5
Total .~~~.~~~...~ 666.0 1,051.z
165.2
2.50 Force
Military pay and allowances
765.3 912.0 146.7
Personnel-related 2 ~~~~~~~~..~~...~~~ 156.6
244.2 87.4
Total ..~.~~~~.~~..~~~..~~~~~~ ~~~~~~ 922.1 1,156.Z
234.1
3.00 Force
Military pay and allowances
792.4 1,060.7 266.3
Personnel-related 2
59.6 231.5 171.7
- ~ ~
Total ~..~~.~~~.~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~..
652.2 1,292.Z 440.0
1 Not onset ‘0, lwome taxes reCOvered.
‘Tra,“,“~ and travel: excludes military personnel CO(ID.
196
APPENDIX B
MILITARY AND
CIVILIAN CDMPENSATIDN
Compensation comparisons, like those in tables 5-11 and
5-111 in chapter 5, always raise two kinds of questions: (1) has
compensation been properly measured for the individuals being
compared and (2) are the particular comparisons drawn, valid
ones? These two questions are discussed below.
MEASUREMENTOFCOMPENSATION
The civilian earnings figures used in this study are those
generated by the Census Bureau’s Current Population Survey
(CPS), and are based on individual earnings reported to census
interviewers. The value of employers’ contributions to fringe
benefits is derived from annual expenditure data for such
benefits submitted by private firms to the U.S. Chamber of
Commerce.
The military cash items of pay incorporated in the regular
and total compensation figures are based on a random sample of
pay records generated by each of the four services. Since these
197
pay records show the actual cash payments to individuals, the
estimates of military cash pay derived from them are probably
superior to those generated by the Census Bureau. The value of
items provided to military personnel in-kind has been derived
from Department of Defense estimates and from other sources.
In most instances, we have incorporated the lowest of the
available estimates.
For instance, food-in-kind provided was valued at $1.32
per day; the Defense Department’s estimate of the cost. That
figure excludes the costs of preparation, service buildings, and
equipment. Similarly, medical services have been valued at
about $92 per person per year. This estimate is based on the
costs of comprehensive medical insurance; costs which are
significantly below those actually incurred (about $400
annually per individual for active military men, their
dependents, and retired personnel). The current value of retired
pay has been estimated by discounting future benefits at 10
percent per year, a discount rate significantly above the 3%
percent used by the Government. The higher discount rate
greatly reduces the value of these benefits.
A conscious effort was made to use minimal estimates of
income-in-kind, recognizing that the value of such items to the
individual is likely on average to be lower than the costs of
providing them. If there is any bias in our measurement of
compensation, it is probably in the direction of underestimating
military compensation for those in the latter stages of their
careers.
With regard to the representative nature of the two
measures of compensation, the average level of military pay for
a given level of education and experience is probably more
representative than is the average level of civilian pay. Even
when age and education are held constant, the variability in pay
among civilians is significantly greater than the variability in
military pay.
VALIDITY OF THE COMPARISONS
The question of the validity of our comparisons breaks
down into three subquestions:
1. Are compensation comparisons by education and age
or years of experience superior to compensation
comparisons by occupation or by position? We have
used the former because education and age or years
of experience are objective characteristics that we can
measure with reasonable accuracy; whereas deciding
what civilian position is comparable to operating a
submarine sonar or to firing a mortar is a subjective
exercise fraught with difficulties.
Also, the “job approach” focuses on the nature
of the position rather than the qualifications of the
individuals holding that position. Admittedly,
education and experience are only two of the many
qualitative characteristics that determine pay. But
these two characteristics are among the most
important ones and their market value is easily
measured. Moreover, we have used them to compare
average compensation for two similar groups, each of
which includes individuals who are both more and
less successful than those receiving the average level
of compensation for the group as a whole. By
choosing two qualities (formal education and
on-the-job training or experience) which produce
significant differences in civilian earnings, we are best
able to relate military pay to civilian alternatives
which influence career decisions.
The final and probably most important reason
for choosing these two qualitative characteristics has
been our recognition that individuals are only partly
influenced by how well they are remunerated for
their performance of a particular task or in a
particular position. In choosing careers or employers,
they are also interested in advancement opportunities
or the speed of movement between jobs and levels of
responsibility. The education-experience classification
highlights one’s earnings opportunities throughout his
entire career. The compensation profiles derived from
this classification show the levels of pay at a point in
time as well as the changes in compensation over
time. As such, they emphasize the major dimensions
that influence the individual’s career decision - the
alternative levels of compensation over time in both
military and civilian careers.
199
2. Is the quality of military personnel higher (or lower)
than that of the civilians with whom their
compensation is being compared? More precisely, do
military selection procedures or self-selectivity result
in an average quality for military personnel exceeding
(or falling below) that of the civilian group to which
they are compared? This is a very hard question to
answer. It is difficult even to define “quality”, much
less determine whether it is higher or lower in the
military
than elsewhere. Fortunately, our
comparisons center on only those aspects of quality
which influence compensation. The fragmentary
evidence on these aspects suggests no significant
differences, if any, in the average level of quality
between the groups being compared. On the one
hand, the military services reject those with the
lowest mental (AFQT) scores and those with physical
handicaps at the initial entry point. On the other
hand, a large number of those with high AFQT scores
have been exempted from military service because
they had either college student or occupational
deferments. Also, upon completion of the initial term
of service, the separations from the military have in
the past tended to the proportionately greater among
those of higher skills and levels of education than
among those with lower skills and levels of education.
It has been argued that selectivity for promotion
makes the quality of military personnel relatively
superior. But, particular selective promotional steps
occur in the later stages of a military career and do
not become too critical until about the
20.years-of-service point.
The various factors mentioned above have
probably prevented the emergence of significant
differences in the average quality of the two groups.
This conclusion is substantiated by the observed
absence of any significant difference in civilian
earnings between veterans and non-veterans of the
same age and with the same educational levels.
Indeed, the civilian earnings of retired service
personnel are, on average, below those of civilians of
200
like age and educational background.
Finally, we have attempted to compensate for
any possible residual difference in quality favoring
the military by comparing military compensation
with the compensation for a group of civilians with
higher levels of education than those of the military
group.
For example, enlisted compensation was
compared with civilian compensation for only white,
male, high-school graduates. The enlisted ranks,
however, contain a significant proportion of
individuals (about 25 percent) who have not
completed high school. Similarly, officer
compensation was compared with the compensation
for white males with 16 or more years of education,
even though about 30 percent of the officer
population are not college graduates.
3. Should the levels of military compensation equal the
levels of compensation of equally qualified civilians?
This issue involves the respective heights of the two
compensation profiles - not their shapes or slopes.
While civilian high school or college graduates
work in a variety of activities and under extremely
divergent conditions, military personnel are likely to
experience greater hazards and hardships in the
service. For this reason, we are unable to claim that
equality between military and civilian compensation
represents true comparability. In fact, we suspect that
higher’ levels of remuneration for military than for
equally qualified civilian personnel will be necessary
to achieve comparability in both monetary and
non-monetary conditions of service. The excess of
military over civilian compensation required will
depend, among other things, on how many true
volunteers the military will require.
201
APPENDIX C
REVIEW OF THE
1966 DEPT. OF DEFENSE DRAFT STUDY
A number of published and unpublished studies have
developed estimates of the additional budget expenses that
would be needed to move to an all-volunteer system. The
estimates which have been most prominently reported in the
press and Congress are those contained in the 1966 Department
of Defense draft study! The I966 DOD study concluded that
an all-volunteer force of 2.65 million men would add $4 billion
to $17 billion per year to the defense budget. If the extreme
estimates are excluded, the mid-range expenditure estimates are
from $5 billion to $8 billion per year. The Department of
Defense estimates are substantially higher than our’ estimate
that an additional $2.12 billion per year will be needed to
sustain an all-volunteer force of 2.5 million men on a stable
basis.
A careful review of the
1966 DOD draft study was
conducted to reconcile the differences in these estimates. The
DOD study concluded that the unemployment rate in the
civilian economy had a significant effect on both the demand
for and supply of military personnel. Two alternative
unemployment rates, 5.5 and 4.0 percent, were used in the
DOD projections. In addition, three alternative estimates of the
elasticity of supply (which describes the responsiveness of the
supply of volunteers to changes in military pay) were examined
for each assumed unemployment rate, thereby producing a total
of six estimated budget increments. As we have noted earlier in
appendix A, the unemployment variable was not statistically
significant in our studies of first-term enlistments. Hence, we
omitted unemployment as an explicit variable, and generated
only a single set of projections.
At the outset, it is instructive to examine the six budget
estimates which are reproduced in table C-l. The rows in table
C-I present the annual increments (or decrements) to the
defense manpower budget required to maintain an all-volunteer
force under different assumptions. Table C-I reveals that
between 92 and 95 percent of the added budget expense is due
TABLE C-L-Estimated increase in payroll costs necessary to obtain
an all-volunteer force of 2.7 million’
[billions]
5.5spercent 4.0-percent
unemployment rate unemployment rate
Low Best High LOW Best High
Enlisted:
Increase in
active-duty pay $3.57 $5.02 $ 6.96 $5.21 $7.64 $14.61
Increase in future re-
tirement benefits .16 .39 1.03 .42 .79 1.94
Savings from
reduced turnoverK -.35 - .41 -54 -.41 -.51 - .72
-- _-
Total ~~~~.~ 3.36 5.00 9.45 5.22 FG 15.63
Officers’ total ~~~ .29 .42 .63 .29 .42 33
--~--__
Grand total ...~~~.~
3.67
5.42 10.26 5.51 6.34 16.66
to the enlisted forces. Our review will be limited to the
estimated added budget expenses for the enlisted force.
The relative increase in pay, (Ml/MO) that is needed to
maintain an all-volunteer force of 2.65 million men depends on
three factors: (1) the supply of true volunteers assuming the
draft is ended with no accompanying change in military pay; (2)
the number of accessions that are needed to meet the prescribed
force strength objectives; and (3) the elasticity of supply. The
budget estimates in the Commission study reported in appendix
A also involved assumptions about these three factors. In what
follows, we point out the major differences in assumptions
between the 1966 DOD draft study and the Commission study
and indicate how these differences account for the widely
divergent budget estimates.
SUPPLY OF TRUE VOLUNTEERS IN THE ABSENCE
OF A DRAFT
The 1966 DOD study dealt with projections for the period
FY 1970 through 197 1, while the Commission study related to
a steady state in the period FY 1977 to 1979. The estimated
annual flows of true volunteers for enlisted ranks taken from
the DOD study are presented in the top panel of table C-II. For
comparative purposes, our estimates of the supply of true
volunteers with no draft and no pay change are shown in the
last column. The male population in the 17-20 year-old range is
projected to be 7,5.5.5,000 for the FY 1970 through 1971
period as compared to 8,589,OOO for the FY 1977 through
1979 period. To adjust for this approximately 14 percent
increase in the pool of potential recruits, the voluntary
enlistments were converted to enlistment rates appearing in the
second panel of table C-11.
The true voluntary enlistment rates were not appreciably
different in the two studies. In fact, the Army enlistment rate
used in the Commission study lies mid-way between the two
Army enlistment rates reported in the 1966 DOD study. This
result is not surprising since both the DOD and Commission
studies estimated the incidence of draft-motivated volunteers by
analyzing the same survey of first-term enlisted men conducted
in the Fall of 1964.
205
TABLE
C-Il.-Supply of true volunteers in the absence of a draft
Commission
1966 DOD draft sludy study
percent unemployment
5.5
4.0
Number of true volunteers
per year
All Services,.~.~~~~~~~~
317 272 312
Army _..... ~~.~ ~~~~
106 91 110
Voluntary enlistment rates’
(percent)
All Services ~~~~~ _........ ~~~~~~.
4.20 3.60 3.63
Army . .._............... 1.40
1.20 1.29
Required accessions
All Services ~~~~~.~ ~~~.~~._ 500 512
342
Army ~~~~~~.. 220 232
148
Recruitment deficits’
All Services~.~ .._... ~~~~~~ . .._. 1.56
1.66 1.10
Army ~.~~~~~~~ ~~~ 2.06 2.55 1.34
Annual turnover rate’
(percent)
All Services ~~~~ _.... ~~~~~~~ . 21.3
21.8
16.4
Army . . . . 25.3
26.4
17.9
REQUIRED ACCESSIONS
In the Commission study, estimates of the accessions
required to maintain enlisted force strength objectives were
based on loss rates in the pre-Vietnam period. The
improvements in retention which result from having only true
volunteers and from higher levels of military pay were
incorporated into the Commission’s projection model. Hence,
the annual turnover rate of Army enlisted men was projected to
decline from 25 percent in the mixed force to 18 percent in the
all-volunteer forces.
206
The assumptions which were used in the 1966 DOD study
could not be found. However, the implications of their
procedures are summarized in the last panel of table C-II, which
shows the implied annual turnover rates. The required Army
accessions in the DOD study imply annual turnover rates of 25
and 26 percent respectively, which are approximately the rates
obtained for mixed forces of draftees and volunteers. We shall
comment later on the importance of this estimate.
ELASTICITY OF SUPPLY
The elasticity of supply, B, is defined as the relative
increase in voluntary enlistments resulting from a given relative
increase in the ratio of military to civilian pay. In the
Commission study, it was estimated that the elasticity of supply
of voluntary enlistments was approximately 1.25, and this value
was used in the projections. The 1966 DOD study assumed a
supply function in which the elasticity declines as larger
fractions of the available population are recruited into the
Armed Forces. Given the relative recruitment deficits appearing
in the fourth panel of table C-II, the elasticities implied by the
first-term pay increases proposed in the 1966 DOD study can be
calculated from the following equation:
log(EI/EBl = B Wx(M,/Mo)l,
where the Army recruitment deficits are used as the pertinent
shortfalls. The relative pay increase and relative Army
recruitment deficit for the six cases identified by the 1966 DOD
study are shown in table C-III. The implied elasticities, B, are
found to vary between 0.7 and 1.25. Thus, the elasticity
estimate used in the Commission study lies at the upper
extreme of the elasticities assumed in the DOD study. Finally,
the level of first-term pay Ml implied by the pay increases is
shown in the second column of table C-III. The first-term pay
of enlisted men, MB which prevailed in 1965 was reported in
the DOD study as follows: The low estimate of first-term pay
for enlisted men required to maintain a voluntary force is
$6,147 in 1965 prices. while the high estimate is $13,045.
207
TABLE
C-Ill.--implied first-term pay and elasticity
of
supply
for the DOD study
Relative Army
increase in
AnIWal recruitment Implied
first-$;; pay first-term pay deficit elasticity
I 0
Ml h/E,,
B
5.5-percent un-
employment
Low ~~~~~~~~~. 1.60 $ 6,147 2.06 1.26
Best ~~~~~~~~~. 2.11
7,206 2.06
.96
High ~~~~~~~. 2.61 9,596 2.08 .71
4.0-percent un-
employment
Low ~~~~~~ 2.14 7,306 2.55 1.23
Best ~~~~.. .~ 2.63
6,961 2.55 .97
High ~~.~ ~~ 3.62 13,045 2.55 .70
SENSITIVITY OF BUDGET ESTIMATES TO
ESTlMATES OF REQUIREMENTS
AND ELASTICITIES
The widely divergent estimates of the additional budget
expenditures for an all-volunteer force ($4 billion to $17 billion
in the 1966 DOD study and about $2 billion in the Commission
study) can be explained by the differences in the respective
estimates of requirements and elasticities. The 1966 DOD study
concluded that pay for first-term enlisted men would have to
rise by 80 to 282 percent to attract a sufficient flow of true
volunteers. (See table C-IV for 1965 pay rates.) The estimated
relative pay increases (M ,/MO) depends critically on the
estimated recruitment shortfall (E ,/Ed and the elasticity of
supply, B.
In order to show how these variables are related we
calculated the pay increases (Ml /&) necessury to achieve an
all-volunteer force for alternative values of (E,/Eo) and 8.
These are shown in the top panel of table C-V. The lower panel
of table C-V shows what the approximate 1966 DOD budget
increments would have been if the DOD study had used the
particular recruitment deficit shown in the column heading and
elasticity estimate shown for the row heading. For example, if
the DOD study had arrived at an estimated elasticity of I .O and
a recruitment deficit of 1.74, their procedures would have
208
generated an approximate budget increase of $3.33 billion. The
data of table C-V enable us to explain why the two studies
arrived at such widely different estimates.
TABLE C-IV.-Mlifary pay
of first-term enlisted men-1965 pay rates
Years Of
service
TtlX
equivalent
income Supplements
Total
military
income
TABLE C-V.-h/alive
increase in military pay (Ml/M,)
and DOD budget ex/xvws’
[for alternative elasticities and recruitment deficits]
Relative recruitment deficit (E./E,)”
Elasticity of
(percent turnover) - “’
SUPPlY
1.57 1.74
1.91 2.09 2.26
B
(16%) (20%)
(22%)
(24%) (26%)
Relative increase in first-term pay (M,/M,)
0.700 1.91 2.21
2.52 2.64
3.21
0.650 1.70 1.91 2.14 2.36 2.61
1.000 1.57
1.74
1.91
2.09 2.26
1.125 1.49
1.64 1.76
1.93
2.06
1.250 1.44 1.56( 1.66 1.60 1.92
1.375 1.36
1.50 1.60 1.71 1 .a1
Approximate budget expense of all-volunteer force (billions)
0.700 $4.29
$5.91 $7.71
510.47
$12.91
0.650 3.11 4.29 5.51 6.90 6.23
1 .ooo 2.37
3.33
4.29
5.31 6.20
1.125 1.92
2.77
3.56 4.40
5.14
1.250 1.64 2.31
2.99
3.67 4.35
1.375 1.30 1.98
2.54
3.16 3.73
The relative recruitment deficits (El/EO) is the ratio of
required accessions, E 1, to the supply of true volunteers in the
absence of a draft with no pay changes b. As indicated above,
there is little disagreement in the two studies on the true
voluntary enlistment rates. However, the projection period for
the Commission study, FY 1977 through 1979, is characterized
by a population pool that is some 14 percent larger than the
population pool for the FY 1970 through 1971 period of the
DOD projections. This fact alone operates to reduce the
recruitment deficit.
The estimated required accessions for the Army, E 1, were,
however, very different. The 1966 estimates imply that if all
rectiits were true volunteers who enlisted for three-year terms,
the Army would experience
an
annual turnover rate of 25 to 26
percent. In the period FY 1957 to 1965 when nearly half of all
Army accessions were two-year draftees, the annual turnover
rate of Army enlisted men was between 20 and 25 percent. It is
now nearly 34 percent because fully two-thirds of all Army
accessions are draftees. In the 1966 DOD study, it was assumed
that the draft would be continued to June 30, 1969. Hence, the
DOD projection period FY 1970 to 197 1 applied to a transition
period in which force strengths remained stable. No statement is
made in the DOD study to indicate when the pay of enlisted
men would be advanced. If it had been raised in 1966, the
greater retention of an all-volunteer force would have occurred
by 1970. On the other hand, if pay were advanced on July 1,
1969, some improvement in retention would still have taken
place especially when pay rates were more than doubled for
first-term enlisted men and increased by at least 50 percent for
second-term enlisted men. We believe that the DOD estimates of
required accessions are unreasonably high. If the 1966 DOD
study had used an annual turnover rate of 20 percent, the added
budget expenditure for an all-volunteer force would have varied
between $2.31 billion (for an elasticity of 1.25) and $5.91
billion (for an elasticity of 0.7). The implications of additional
budget expenditures of $2 billion to $6 billion a year are,
indeed, very different from estimates of $4 billion to $17
billion.
Finally, a considerable part of the added budget
expenditures arises because of pay increases to the career
enlisted force. If first-term pay must be doubled from $3,415 to
$6,830 per year, the pay of the career force must also be raised.
210
These career pay increases should lead to significantly higher
reenlistment rates which, in turn, would reduce personnel
turnover. The Commission study incorporated these effects in
generating estimates of personnel turnover rates. Moreover, the
recommended pay increase in the Commission study led to only
modest increases in the pay of career enlisted men. Although
the 1966 DOD study, provided higher career pay to prevent
inversions in the enlisted pay structure (enlisted men with 1 to
3 years of service earning more than men with 6 to 12 years of
service), they do not mention pay comparisons between enlisted
men and officers. The high budget estimate of $17 billion
implied that a new recruit would receive annual military pay of
$13,045 - considerably more than the pay of newly
commissioned officers.