12
A Theory of Heuristic and
Systematic Information
Processing
Shelly Chaiken and Alison Ledgerwood
ABSTRACT
The heuristic-systematic model proposes two
distinct modes of thinking about information.
Systematic processing involves attempts to thor-
oughly understand any available information
through careful attention, deep thinking, and
intensive reasoning, whereas heuristic processing
involves focusing on salient and easily compre-
hended cues that activate well-learned judgmental
shortcuts. Heuristic processing is a more efficient
and relatively automatic mode of processing,
but more often than not confers less judgmental
confidence. Systematic processing confers more
confidence but is relatively effortful and time-
consuming. Thus, individuals tend to engage in
heuristic processing unless they are both motivated
and able to think carefully about information, in
which case the two modes of processing can have
additive, attenuating, or interactive effects.
Furthermore, both modes of processing can be
relatively open-minded, driven by accuracy con-
cerns, or relatively biased, driven by defense or
impression concerns. This chapter situates the heu-
ristic-systematic model within its intellectual and
personal history, and highlights key empirical find-
ings that support the model’s central tenets.
INTRODUCTION
Attitudes have been a primary focus of
theory and research in social psychology
since the 1920s. Nine decades of research
have produced a sizeable and complex body
of literature that speak to questions of how
people’s attitudes are formed, maintained,
and changed, and provide an ever-growing
foundation upon which new questions arise
and new answers unfold. In 1980, a founda-
tion of process-oriented models that explained
attitude change based on how people under-
stand and evaluate persuasive argumentation
set the stage for one question in particular:
Was careful argument scrutiny the only
kind of process by which attitude change
could occur? Or might we sometimes
change our minds in more efficient, but less
effortful, ways?
The heuristic-systematic model of persua-
sion (Chaiken, 1980, 1987; Chaiken et al.,
1989, 1996; Chen and Chaiken, 1999)
Uncorrected proofs. Chapter to appear in P. A. M. van Lange, A. W. Kruglanski, & E. T. Higgins (Eds.), Handbook of
theories of social psychology. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
247
answers this question by proposing two
distinct modes of information processing.
The first mode, systematic processing,
involves attempts to thoroughly understand
any and all available information through
careful attention, deep thinking, and inten-
sive reasoning (e.g., thinking carefully about
the arguments presented, the person arguing,
and the causes of the person’s behavior). This
information is combined and used to guide
subsequent attitudes, judgments, and behav-
iors. For instance, a systematic approach to
thinking about a proposed economic policy
might involve reading as many magazine and
newspaper reports as possible to learn and
develop an opinion about the “best” course
of action for the economy. The heuristic-
systematic model suggests that such system-
atic thinking entails a relatively high degree
of mental effort, and thus requires that a
person (1) can devote a certain amount of
attention to thinking about the issue, and
(2) wants to devote this attention. Thus,
systematic processing is unlikely to occur
unless a person is both able and motivated
to do so.
Heuristic processing is much less demand-
ing in terms of the mental work required and
much less dependent on having the ability
(e.g., enough knowledge and enough time) to
think carefully about information. In fact,
heuristic processing can be viewed as rela-
tively automatic because it can occur even
when people are not motivated and able to
deliberately think about a topic. Heuristic
processing involves focusing on easily
noticed and easily understood cues, such as a
communicator’s credentials (e.g., expert
versus nonexpert), the group membership of
the communicator (e.g., Democrat or
Republican), the number of arguments pre-
sented (many or few), or audience reactions
(positive or negative). These cues are linked
to well-learned, everyday decision rules
known as heuristics. Like other knowledge
structures (e.g., stereotypes), heuristics can
vary in their availability and accessibility, as
well as in their perceived reliability (i.e., the
extent to which a particular person perceives
a heuristic to be a valid guide for judgment in
a given situation; see Chen and Chaiken,
1999; Darke et al., 1998). Moreover, they can
be used self-consciously or non-self-
consciously: People may consciously decide
to invoke a heuristic in order to inform a
subsequent judgment, but heuristics can also
influence judgments without intention or
self-awareness.
Examples of heuristics include “experts
know best,” “my own group can be trusted,
“argument length equals argument strength,
and “consensus implies correctness.” These
simple, intuitive rules allow people to form
judgments, attitudes, and intentions quickly
and efficiently, simply on the basis of the
easily noticed cues, and with little critical
thinking. A heuristic approach to a proposed
economic plan might involve simply adopt-
ing the opinion of a noted economist. In
other words, heuristic thinking is what we do
when we do not have much ability or time to
think about something and want to make a
reasonable decision as quickly as possible.
The theory further proposed that two prin-
ciples act in conjunction to determine the
mode and extent of information processing
that occurs in any given context (Chaiken,
1980, 1987; Chaiken et al., 1989). The mod-
el’s least effort principle reflects the assump-
tion that individuals try to arrive at attitudinal
decisions as efficiently as possible (see also
Allport, 1954). Thus, all else equal, people
should tend to prefer a less effortful mode of
processing (i.e., heuristic processing) to one
that requires more time and cognitive
resources (i.e., systematic processing).
Meanwhile, however, the sufficiency
principle asserts that individuals are some-
times motivated to exert additional cognitive
effort in order to reach a certain level of
judgmental confidence. They must therefore
balance their preference for maximizing cog-
nitive efficiency with the desire to satisfy
their motivational concerns, such as the goal
to reach an accurate conclusion (Chaiken
et al., 1989; see also Simon, 1976). The
heuristic-systematic model suggests that this
balance point is determined by a sufficiency
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
248
threshold, defined as the degree of confi-
dence to which an individual aspires in a
given judgmental situation (Chaiken et al.,
1989; Eagly and Chaiken, 1993). The suffi-
ciency threshold can be conceptualized as a
point located on a continuum of judgmental
confidence. The extent of information
processing is determined by the size of the
discrepancy that exists between an individu-
al’s actual level of confidence in their judg-
ment and the sufficiency threshold (i.e., their
desired confidence). Thus, effortful informa-
tion processing should only occur when
actual confidence falls below the sufficiency
threshold, and should continue (when capac-
ity allows) until this confidence gap is closed.
Extent of information processing will there-
fore depend both on a particular person’s
actual level of judgmental confidence in a
given persuasion setting, as well as their
desired level of confidence in that setting
(see Figure 12.1).
Together, the least effort and sufficiency
principles suggest that – assuming adequate
cognitive capacity – individuals will engage
in systematic processing insofar as the less
Figure 12.1 A person with a small gap between actual and desired confidence might
be able to reach their desired level of confidence (the sufficiency threshold) using only
heuristic processing (Panel A). If the confidence gap is larger, either due to a low level of
actual confidence (Panel B) or a high level of desired confidence (Panel C), it is less likely
that people can reach their desired level of judgmental confidence using only heuristic
processing. When people cannot attain their desired level of confidence using only
heuristic processing, they will engage in systematic processing in an effort to finish
closing the confidence gap, assuming they have the ability to do so
A.
B.
C.
Actual
confidence
Actual
confidence
Actual
confidence
Desired
confidence
Desired
confidence
Desired
confidence
Confidence
gap
Confidence
gap
Confidence
gap
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
249
effortful heuristic mode does not yield suffi-
cient judgmental confidence (either because
heuristic processing cannot occur, as in situ-
ations that do not offer easily processed
heuristic cues, or because it is insufficient to
close the confidence gap). Systematic
processing will therefore be increased by
factors that either decrease actual confidence,
increase desired confidence, or both.
THE MULTIPLE-MOTIVE
HEURISTIC-SYSTEMATIC MODEL
Although the heuristic-systematic model was
initially developed to apply to individuals
motivated by accuracy concerns to seek valid
judgments, later work expanded the model to
incorporate two other broad motivations that
can lead to selective information processing,
geared toward arriving at a particular attitudi-
nal position (Chaiken et al., 1989, 1996;
Chen and Chaiken, 1999). The first of these,
defense motivation, was intended to reflect
the impact of such self-focused variables as
ego-involvement and personal commitment
(see, e.g., Kiesler, 1971; Sherif and Cantril,
1947). According to the multiple-motive
model of heuristic-systematic processing,
these factors arouse a desire to confirm and
defend the validity of preferred attitudinal
positions (like one’s pre-existing opinion),
while challenging the validity of nonpre-
ferred positions. Impression motivation, on
the other hand, reflects the impact of other-
focused variables such as impression-relevant
involvement, communication goals, and affil-
iative concerns (e.g., Higgins and McCann,
1984; Johnson and Eagly, 1989; Smith et al.,
1956), which arouse a desire to express atti-
tudes that are socially acceptable.
Like accuracy motivation, defense and
impression motivations can engender heuris-
tic and/or systematic processing. However,
unlike accuracy motivation, these directional
motives tend to lead people to process
information selectively, rather than open-
mindedly. The biases engendered by these
directional motives largely occur outside of
awareness; people usually operate under the
illusion that they are thinking in an open-
minded fashion. In the case of defense-
motivated processing, for instance, individuals
may selectively choose heuristics that help
to confirm a preferred position. A defense-
motivated person might therefore invoke the
heuristic “experts know best” if the position
of an expert source reinforces her cherished
values and social identity, but might choose a
different heuristic (e.g., “outgroup sources
can’t be trusted”) if the position threatens
her social identity. Likewise, impression-
motivated heuristic processing entails selec-
tive application of heuristics that ensure a
smooth interaction with specific others. For
example, when interacting with a person or
group whose views on an issue are unknown
or vague, a perceiver might invoke the heu-
ristic “moderate judgment minimizes disa-
greement.” On the other hand, when others’
views are known, a “go along to get along”
heuristic might better serve the same goal.
With sufficient cognitive capacity and
higher levels of motivation, defense-
or impression-motivated people will also
process systematically, but they will again do
so selectively. Thus, a defense-motivated
perceiver will attend to, elaborate on, and
recall information that serves to bolster his
preferred, self-protective position, while an
impression-motivated perceiver will system-
atically process information in such a way as
to convey a desired impression to (real or
imagined) others.
The multiple-motive model thus proposed
three general categories of motives that give
rise to three distinct processing goals, any of
which can engender heuristic and/or system-
atic processing. Expanding the theory in this
way broadened its applicability to a much
wider range of persuasion and social
influence situations. In essence, the multiple-
motive heuristic-systematic model allowed a
rapidly increasing laundry list of persuasion-
relevant variables to be understood in
terms of their effects on a few key factors –
processing goal, cognitive capacity, actual
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
250
confidence, and desired confidence – which
could in turn suggest a reliable prediction
about the extent of attitude change that
should occur in a given setting. The strength
of this basic dual-process model to organize
and generate predictions in the persuasion
literature led to its application across a wide
range of settings (Chen and Chaiken, 1999;
Ledgerwood et al., in press; Mackie, 1987;
Stroebe and Diehl, 1988; see Eagly and
Chaiken, 1993; Ledgerwood et al., 2006, for
reviews). More broadly, it was one of several
theories that helped to precipitate a flowering
of dual-process models across multiple areas
of social psychology, as researchers began to
see similar basic principles at work in a
number of different domains including stere-
otyping, impression formation, and decision
making (see Chaiken and Trope, 1999).
PERSONAL HISTORY OF THE
THEORY: AN AUTHOR BY
LITERATURE INTERACTION
In 1972, the first author entered graduate
school at the University of Massachusetts
Amherst armed with a math major, a psy-
chology minor, and a vague interest in social
influence. I began working with Alice Eagly,
who was at the time examining the impor-
tance of message comprehensibility within
the context of Bill McGuire’s information
processing paradigm. In fact, my masters
research project involved testing an idea
about comprehensibility that McGuire had
tucked away in the depths of a handbook
chapter; namely, that the importance of com-
prehensibility in determining the effective-
ness of persuasive appeals would depend on
the modality of the communication (Chaiken
and Eagly, 1976). Looking back, I can trace
part of the development of the heuristic-
systematic model to this project. The idea
was that message comprehensibility should
matter more when the message is in written
form rather than audio or video, partly
because there is more flexibility to carefully
scrutinize a message when reading it than
when hearing it spoken. Later, we returned to
this idea to examine whether a different type
of persuasion variable – source cues – might
become increasingly influential as one moved
from written to audio and visual modalities
(Chaiken and Eagly, 1983). This research
suggested that different persuasion variables
might be more or less influential depending
on how a message was presented.
Here then was one seed for the heuristic-
systematic model: different types of persua-
sion variables had more or less impact
depending on a recipient’s ability to carefully
scrutinize a message. Other seeds were in
the recent and current literature at that
time: articles on correspondent inference
theory, Kelley’s covariation theory, and self-
perception theory populated the reading lists
for my coursework, and I was intrigued both
by attribution models and by the simplicity
of self-perception (Bem, 1972; Jones and
Davis, 1965; Kelley, 1972, 1973). With Alice,
I helped develop an attribution model of
source characteristics based on Kelley’s
(1973) cube model, particularly his notions
of discounting and augmentation. Yet com-
pared to self-perception theory, analyzing the
covariances of even a somewhat superficial
persuasion variable like source characteris-
tics seemed effortful and deliberative. Could
people really be so careful, so thoughtful, all
the time?
The simple if–then’s of self-perception
theory appealed to me – why engage in some
arduous analysis of your own thoughts and
behaviors when you could simply reason: if
I’m yelling, I must be angry? Years before,
when Kennedy and Nixon had been running
for president, I remember listening to my
parents consider the intricacies of the various
political issues at stake. Meanwhile I (with a
young child’s preference for the simple that
I still haven’t seemed to grow out of com-
pletely) knew that Kennedy was the man to
vote for; after all, he looked better. And it
wasn’t just me; in graduate school, I read
about data showing that although those who
heard the first Kennedy–Nixon debate on the
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
251
radio believed Nixon had won, those who
watched it on television were convinced that
Kennedy had in fact prevailed. If the average
person was really what McGuire (1969) had
dubbed “the lazy organism,” might a simple
if–then suffice for most of us, much of
the time?
Then, in 1975, I came across Shelley
Taylor’s recently published dissertation,
which shed some additional light on self-
perception processes. Female participants
were shown pictures of three different
men who varied in attractiveness. Some
participants were given false physiological
feedback suggesting that they showed a
strong preference for one of the men pic-
tured. Participants were then led to believe
that they would have the opportunity to meet
one of these men in a few weeks (high con-
sequences condition), or were not led to
expect a future meeting (no consequences).
They then rated each of the three men on
attractiveness. The results suggested that par-
ticipants in the no consequences condition
engaged in self-perception: they based their
ratings of attractiveness on the physiological
feedback provided. Most interestingly to me,
however, participants in the high conse-
quences condition were not affected by the
feedback manipulation. Instead, there was
some evidence to suggest they were thinking
more carefully and critically about the three
candidates: they spent more time looking at
the pictures, and content analyses suggested
that they made more critical comments.
I remember thinking to myself that surely
this could apply to persuasion. High and low
consequences provided a variable that could
perhaps predict when a lazy organism would
opt for a simple “if-then” versus a more
complicated analysis of available informa-
tion. I built my main dissertation experiment
around this idea, testing whether high versus
low consequences would moderate the per-
suasive impact of source cues (the most
frequently studied noncontent variable at the
time) and content (extent of strong persua-
sive argumentation). I reasoned that source
cues such as likeability can be processed
quite easily and efficiently by a lazy organ-
ism unmotivated by future consequences.
When future consequences were present,
however, participants should be motivated to
process information more carefully, and
extent of strong argumentation should play a
greater role in persuasion.
And (amazingly, to me at the time), the
study worked. I started calling the more
deliberative mode of thinking systematic, but
didn’t really know what to call the other one
until Icek Ajzen, another important mentor
for me in graduate school, suggested the
name “heuristic.As I continued the line of
research, the notion of consequences became
abstracted into motivation to process infor-
mation. Like many other theories at that
time, the default motivation was implicitly
assumed to be accuracy; I began to explicitly
label the motivation “accuracy motivation”
only later in order to emphasize that both
modes of thinking served the same motive
(rather than one being rational and the other
irrational). Drawing on my earlier modality
research, I also added capacity as a second
variable that seemed necessary for delibera-
tive processing to occur.
Over the years, I tried to expand the model
to other kinds of cues, and to test its assump-
tions in various ways. Perhaps inevitably,
given that my intellectual genes were steeped
in classic functional theories of attitudes
(Alice Eagly had worked with Herb Kelman),
it occurred to me that accuracy was not the
only motive in town, and I began to try to
group the major attitudinal functions I had
learned about in graduate school into a few
broad categories of motives. Over time, we
developed and tested predictions deriving
from a multiple-motive heuristic-systematic
model that included not just accuracy
motivation, but also impression and defense
motives (see Chaiken et al., 1996; Chen and
Chaiken, 1999, for reviews).
Very gradually, then, the theory
expanded – first under the influence of func-
tional theories, and then following new devel-
opments in social cognition. I had always
thought of heuristics as simple decision rules
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
252
that were likely represented in memory, and
such a conceptualization lent itself to new
theorizing about availability and accessibility
in social cognition. By now I was at New
York University, where hallway conversa-
tions with Tory Higgins and John Bargh
inevitably turned toward basic principles of
social cognition. I began to think that heuris-
tics ought to vary in their availability, acces-
sibility, and reliability, and that this would
have important consequences for when a
given heuristic would be applied. Furthermore,
heuristics seemed to me to be relatively auto-
matic, in at least some senses of the term (see
Bargh, 1994). I always thought of them as a
kind of shortcut; thus, at the very least they
were automatic in the sense of being effi-
cient. It also seemed likely that they often
(but not always) operated outside of aware-
ness. Over time, the results of accumulating
studies provided support for this social-cog-
nitive side of the model as well (see Chen
and Chaiken, 1999, for a review).
Conceptualizing heuristics as a form of
automatic social cognition highlights one
way in which the basic processes underlying
the heuristic-systematic model extend beyond
the persuasion context to other domains. It
became apparent early on that a dual-process
perspective was not restricted to a persuasion
context; that it would be fruitful to look
across different domains to understand the
common mechanisms at work in all of them.
And indeed, the heuristic-systematic model
was just one of a growing family of dual-
process models that began to populate social
psychology in the 1980s and 1990s, as
researchers across different domains con-
verged on a similar set of mechanisms to
explain information processing in a variety
of settings (see Chaiken and Trope, 1999).
INTELLECTUAL HISTORY
OF THE THEORY
Like many of the models in this family, the
heuristic-systematic model suggests that
individuals can think about information not
only via a bottom-up, data-driven process
but also via a more top-down process
that depends on the pre-existing knowledge
structures they bring to a particular context.
Although this represented a radical reorienta-
tion in the field of persuasion at the time,
the notion that we can rely on learned asso-
ciations to structure understanding emerged
as early as 1930 in Kohler’s discussion of
sensation and perception, in which he
suggested that our perceptions are shaped as
much by a top-down application of knowl-
edge derived from past experiences as by
bottom-up, sensory experience (see also
Moskowitz et al., 1999; Yates, 1985). For
instance, upon sensing a pattern of colors and
lines with our eyes, we can draw on our
past experiences and associations with this
pattern to label it a “chair” and infer its
form and function. Subsequently, Bruner’s
“new look” emphasized the notion that our
perceptions are substantially shaped by
expectation and motivation (Bruner, 1957).
Research on mental schemas developed this
idea to suggest that we can quickly organize
and “fill in the blanks” about our world
using generalized mental structures built
from our past experiences (e.g., Anderson
and Pichert, 1978; Brewer and Treyens,
1981; see Fiske and Linville, 1980; Taylor
and Crocker, 1981; and Fiske and Taylor,
2008, for reviews). Together, these literatures
highlight a relatively quick, efficient,
top-down method of understanding the world
that capitalizes on past experience to struc-
ture current understanding, and suggests that
these mental shortcuts may be applied to a
range of different domains (see also Tversky
and Kahneman, 1974).
Within this historical context, the heuris-
tic-systematic model proposed that individu-
als might sometimes rely on quick, efficient,
cognitive shortcuts to make judgments about
the validity of information they encounter.
Thus, rather than carefully scrutinizing any
and all available information, people might
instead draw on simple if–then associations
learned through repeated experience to
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
253
inform their attitude judgments. For instance,
given that experts tend to be correct, indi-
viduals might develop a learned association
between experts and correctness that allows
them to easily and efficiently infer that a
subsequently encountered expert is likely to
be right (“if expert, then correct”).
As noted earlier, because the model
assumed that heuristics are like other knowl-
edge structures, it invited connections to
social-cognitive research on the principles
governing the activation and use of stored
knowledge (Chaiken et al., 1989, Chen and
Chaiken, 1999). In other words, heuristics
should be subject to the same principles of
availability, accessibility, and applicability
that underlie the use of stored knowledge in
other domains (e.g., Higgins, 1989; Higgins
et al., 1982). Considerable research supports
this claim (see Chen and Chaiken, 1999, for
a review). For instance, in order to be used to
inform attitudes in a given setting, a heuristic
must be (1) accessible (e.g., because it has
been situationally primed), and (2) applica-
ble (e.g., because an individual believes it to
be a reliable, or usable, guide for judgment;
Chaiken et al., 1992).
Heuristic processing thus represented a
very different mode of thinking from the
more systematic, comprehensive mode that
had occupied the center stage of persuasion
theory and research for some time.
Furthermore, the heuristic-systematic model
suggested that these modes of processing
involved a tradeoff between optimal
judgments (maximized by systematic
processing) and efficient judgments (maxi-
mized by heuristic processing). The model’s
original formulation proposed that heuristic
or systematic processing would predominate
depending on the relative importance of
accuracy or economic concerns for a given
person in a given context (Chaiken, 1980).
Subsequently, this notion was refined
to emphasize a continuum of judgmental
confidence, along which two critical points
can be located: a person’s actual confidence,
and their desired confidence or sufficiency
threshold (Eagly and Chaiken, 1993). As lazy
organisms (McGuire, 1969), people first
attempt to close this gap in confidence via
heuristic processing. Only when this easier
strategy fails to confer sufficient judgmental
confidence will people exert the cognitive
effort required by systematic processing,
assuming they are able to do so.
Considerable research supports this
central claim that individuals will process
information heuristically unless they are both
motivated and able to engage in more effort-
ful systematic processing. Heuristic cues
alone tend to guide judgments when ability is
low (such as when participants possess little
knowledge about the topic, when they
are under time pressure, or when situational
constraints diminish cognitive capacity) and
when motivation is low (such as under condi-
tions of low task importance or personal
relevance; Giner-Sorolla et al., 2002; Petty
et al., 1976; Ratneshwar and Chaiken, 1991;
Wood et al., 1985). As ability and motivation
increase, systematic processing plays an
increasing role in influencing attitudes (e.g.,
Chaiken, 1980; Martin et al., 2007; Petty and
Cacioppo, 1984; see Eagly and Chaiken,
1993, for a review). Importantly, the process-
ing modes are by no means mutually
exclusive: given adequate levels of ability
and motivation, heuristic and systematic
processing often co-occur (Chaiken, 1980,
1987; Eagly and Chaiken, 1993). We return
to this assumption of concurrent processing
later in the section.
Bridging beyond the persuasion
context
Although the heuristic-systematic model was
initially developed within the context of the
paradigmatic persuasion experiment, in
which a source conveys a message to a target
with some effect, it quickly became clear
that the fundamental processes at work
within this context were mirrored in other
domains. At its heart, the persuasion para-
digm involves individuals making judgments
in light of information, as they do in many
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
254
other domains. Because it focuses on the
basic processes underlying persuasion effects,
the heuristic-systematic model provided a
natural bridge from persuasion to many
other, conceptually similar, areas. Across
various domains, individuals can make
judgments based on quick shortcuts or
more effortful, extensive processing, and
motivation and ability play a key role in
guiding the extent to which effortful process-
ing occurs.
Indeed, as noted earlier, the heuristic-
systematic model was among several early
dual-process models in social psychology.
Together, these paved the way for a rapid
proliferation of information-processing
theories in a variety of domains that distin-
guished between a relatively automatic, fast,
reflexive mode of thinking based on well-
learned associations, and a more controlled,
analytic, effortful mode based on systematic
reasoning (e.g., Brewer, 1988; Devine, 1989;
Fazio and Towles-Schwen, 1999; Fiske et al.,
1999; Gawronski and Bodenhausen, 2006;
Gilbert, 1989; see Chaiken and Trope, 1999;
Smith and DeCoster, 2000, for reviews). In
their 1999 volume, Chaiken and Trope
featured a variety of dual-process models
from diverse fields that converged in their
basic distinction between these two types
of processes, illustrating that these perspec-
tives are really a family of theories with a
common core.
Empirical findings
The first experiment designed to test the
heuristic-systematic model examined whether
involvement would moderate the extent
to which a heuristic cue (communicator
likeability) versus message content (extent of
supportive argumentation) influenced
people’s attitudes (Chaiken, 1980: Study 1).
Undergraduate participants read a transcript
of an interview with a university administra-
tor who in the course of the interview either
praised undergraduates (likeable source
condition) or disparaged them (unlikeable
source condition). Later, the administrator
stated his opinion on an issue (e.g., changing
from a semester to a trimester system) and
provided either a weak message (containing
only two arguments) or a strong message
(containing six different arguments) in
support of his opinion.
To test whether participants’ level of
motivation would determine the extent to
which they relied on the heuristic cue or
engaged in more effortful processing of
message content, the experiment also manip-
ulated participants’ involvement by leading
them to expect that they would discuss either
the same issue or a different issue at a subse-
quent experimental session. Participants who
expected to discuss the same issue should
be more motivated to reach an accurate con-
clusion about whether the administrator’s
position was valid, compared to those who
expected to discuss a different issue, and
should therefore engage in more systematic
processing. Consistent with the study’s
hypotheses, high involvement participants
showed greater attitude change in response to
a strong (versus weak) message, but were
unaffected by communicator likeability. In
contrast, low involvement participants
showed greater attitude change in response to
the likeable (versus unlikeable) communica-
tor, but were unaffected by message content.
Furthermore, substantiating the notion that
attitude change was mediated via systematic
processing in the high involvement condi-
tion, these participants showed greater recall
of arguments and reported more issue-
relevant thoughts, compared with those low
in involvement. Thus, which factors pro-
duced persuasion – and how they produced
persuasion – depended critically on partici-
pants’ level of motivation.
Importantly, by delineating a dual process
underlying people’s thinking about persua-
sive appeals, the heuristic-systematic model
was able to shed light on the role played
by motivational variables, as well as source
cues and message content, in influencing
attitudes. For instance, previous research had
reported conflicting findings regarding the
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
255
impact of involvement on persuasion (e.g.,
Pallak et al., 1972; Sherif and Hovland,
1961). Our results (Chaiken, 1980) suggested
that involvement could either increase or
decrease attitude change in response to a
persuasive message, depending on the valence
of available heuristic cues and the strength of
the message content. Similarly, Axsom et al.
(1987) showed that whereas involvement
increased the impact of argument quality on
persuasion, it decreased the impact of the
heuristic cue of audience response (i.e.,
whether an overheard message audience
sounded enthusiastic or unenthusiastic). The
heuristic-systematic model thus provided a
theoretical framework within which to organ-
ize a large number of persuasion-related
factors in a literature that had often produced
contradictory results.
The concurrent processing
assumption
It was in large part the prevalence of such
contradictory results that motivated the devel-
opment of the heuristic-systematic model.
Looking back, the historical assumptions
discussed earlier, combined with the current
climate in the persuasion literature, created a
unique context within which the logic of
a dual-process perspective was perhaps
more likely to be discovered. And, in fact,
two dual-process models of persuasion inde-
pendently emerged from this context: the
heuristic-systematic model and the elabora-
tion-likelihood model (ELM; Petty and
Wegener, 1999). Both provided an organiz-
ing framework for understanding the impact
of various persuasion variables by suggesting
two routes to persuasion: the heuristic or
“peripheral” route, and the systematic or
“central” route. However, they differed in
some important ways. For instance, whereas
the ELM assumed that the peripheral and
central routes to persuasion were mutually
exclusive, the heuristic-systematic model
suggested that they could co-occur and even
interact.
Thus, although many of the initial dual-
process studies of persuasion suggested that
heuristic cues do not impact attitudes when
people are motivated and able to process
systematically (e.g., Axsom et al., 1987;
Chaiken, 1980; Petty et al., 1981; Wood
et al., 1985), the heuristic-systematic model
suggested that this pattern was only one
possible outcome of the two modes of infor-
mation processing. Specifically, these results
seemed to represent cases in which system-
atic processing attenuated the judgmental
impact of heuristic processing because it
took into account information that contra-
dicted the valence of the available heuristic
cues. If systematic processing instead yielded
information that was congruent with heuris-
tic processing, the heuristic-systematic model
suggested an additivity hypothesis whereby
heuristic processing could exert a direct
effect on judgment over and above the impact
of systematic processing. Supporting this
hypothesis, Maheswaran and Chaiken (1991;
see also Maheswaran et al., 1992) found
that when heuristic cues and message
content were congruent, attitude change was
mediated by both heuristic and systematic
processing.
Importantly, however, the heuristic-
systematic model proposed that the two
processes could not only co-occur, but could
also interact to exert interdependent effects
on judgment. Specifically, heuristic process-
ing could bias systematic processing by
influencing people’s expectations about the
validity of arguments presented in a persua-
sive appeal (Chaiken et al., 1989). To test this
notion, Chaiken and Maheswaran (1994)
presented participants with a novel attitude
object (a new telephone answering machine
called the “XT–100”) and assigned them to
one cell of a 2 (accuracy motivation: low
versus high) by 2 (heuristic cue: valid versus
invalid) by 2 (argument quality: strong versus
ambiguous versus weak) design. This study
manipulated accuracy motivation by varying
the importance and personal relevance of
participants’ decisions regarding this new
product. Whereas participants in the high
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
256
importance condition learned that they were
part of a small list of respondents, that their
input would be heavily weighted, and that
the product would be distributed in their
geographical area, participants in the low
importance condition learned that they were
part of a large group of respondents, that
individual opinions were unimportant, and
that the product would be distributed in a
different geographical area.
Participants next received a positive
message about the product that contained a
heuristic cue conveying either high or low
validity. Specifically, they learned that the
product description in the message was taken
from Consumer Reports, a credible source,
or from a promotional Kmart pamphlet, a
noncredible source. The product description
contained either strong arguments, weak
arguments, or an ambiguous mixture of the
two. Participants then reported their attitudes
toward the XT–100 and listed their thoughts
about the product description.
As in previous studies (e.g., Chaiken,
1980), the relatively unmotivated participants
in the low importance condition expressed
attitudes that reflected the source credibility
cues, but not the quality of the arguments
presented in the product description. Thus,
participants were more favorable toward the
XT–100 when they had read a positive mes-
sage from a credible (versus noncredible)
source, regardless of actual message content.
Moreover, this effect of source cue on
attitudes was direct, rather than mediated by
cognitive elaboration, consistent with the
notion that participants were directly infer-
ring the validity of the message from the
source’s credibility (i.e., processing heuris-
tically by using a well-learned association
between credibility and correctness).
Meanwhile, the results for participants in
the high importance condition who read an
unambiguous message also replicated past
research: highly motivated participants who
read a strong (versus weak) persuasive mes-
sage expressed more positive attitudes toward
the XT–100, and this effect was mediated by
participants’ cognitive elaborations about the
product. Additional analyses revealed that
when source cue and message content were
contradictory in their implications for
message validity (i.e., a credible source
paired with weak arguments, or a noncredible
source and strong arguments), systematic
processing alone determined attitudes. This
is consistent with the attenuation hypothesis
suggesting that systematic processing can
override the effects of heuristic processing.
However, when source credibility and
message content were congruent (i.e., a
credible source and strong arguments, or a
noncredible source and weak arguments),
there was both a direct effect of the heuristic
source cue on attitudes and an effect of
message content mediated by systematic
processing. Thus, when the information
provided by heuristic and systematic process-
ing were congruent, the results supported the
additivity hypothesis suggesting that both
modes of processing can independently influ-
ence attitudes.
Finally, highly motivated participants who
read an ambiguous message were influenced
both by the source cue and by systematic
processing of the high (versus low) quality
arguments. Supporting the bias hypothesis,
these participants’ cognitive elaborations
about the attitude object were influenced by
the validity information provided by the
source cue, such that the high credibility
source biased systematic processing in a
positive direction, whereas the low credibil-
ity source biased systematic processing in a
negative direction. In addition, attitudes in
this condition were also directly influenced
by the heuristic cue.
In other research examining the bias
hypothesis, Darke et al. (1998) studied the
impact of consensus information presented
in the absence of persuasive argumentation
on college students’ support for comprehen-
sive exams. Accuracy motivation was manip-
ulated via personal relevance. Participants in
the high relevance condition were led to
believe that the exam policy would have
direct personal consequences (i.e., it would
take effect the following academic year, and
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
257
would thus apply to current students),
whereas those in the low relevance condition
were led to believe that there would be no
personal consequences (i.e., the policy would
take effect in ten years, and therefore have
no impact on current students). Participants
then learned that 80 percent of students either
supported or opposed instituting comprehen-
sive exams, based on either a small poll
(a sample size of ten students) or a large poll
(a sample size of 1,000 students). Consistent
with the bias hypothesis, participants in the
high personal relevance condition generated
thoughts that were biased in the direction of
the available consensus cue, and these
thoughts then influenced their attitudes. In
contrast, the consensus information exerted a
direct, heuristic influence on participants’
attitudes in the low personal relevance
condition. Interestingly, highly motivated
participants also discriminated between the
more and less reliable heuristic cues: partici-
pants in the high relevance condition were
more persuaded by the consensus informa-
tion when the poll was based on a large
versus small sample of students, whereas
participants in the low relevance condition
were persuaded by consensus information
regardless of the poll’s size.
Together, then, these studies highlight the
complex interplay between heuristic and
systematic processing (see also Chen et al.,
1996; Erb et al., 1998; Ziegler et al., 2005).
Importantly, they demonstrate that the two
modes of processing can influence attitudes
both independently and interactively,
suggesting that they may best be conceptual-
ized as two interdependent and potentially
co-occurring ways of thinking (see Eagly
and Chaiken, 1993: Chapter 7, for further
discussion).
Multiple motives
Another unique feature of the heuristic-
systematic model is that it jointly considers
the influence of multiple modes of process-
ing on the one hand and multiple motives on
the other. The tripartite analysis of motives in
the heuristic-systematic model has its histori-
cal roots in the literature on attitude function,
although it should be noted that similar
classes of motives that center on understand-
ing, protecting the self, and affiliating with
others are echoed across multiple domains
(e.g., Allport, 1954; Baumeister and Leary,
1995; Deutsch and Gerard, 1955; Fiske,
2002; Heider, 1958; Lerner and Tetlock,
1999; Tesser and Campbell, 1983). The
notion that individuals are often motivated to
form and hold attitudes that square with
relevant facts built on Katz’s (1960) “knowl-
edge” function and Smith et al.s (1956)
“object appraisal” function of attitudes,
which emphasized the role often played
by attitudes in organizing experience and
guiding action with respect to an individual’s
ongoing concerns. The heuristic-systematic
model was thus initially designed to apply to
persuasion contexts in which the message
recipient is concerned with assessing the
validity of a persuasive appeal (Chaiken,
1980, 1987; Chaiken et al., 1996). We subse-
quently extended the model beyond
validity-seeking persuasion contexts, adding
impression and defense motives to encapsu-
late two other broad classes of attitude
functions in the literature (Chaiken et al.,
1989). The concept of impression motivation
was designed to capture other-oriented,
affiliative functions such as Smith et al.s
(1956) social adjustment function, which
emphasized the role that attitudes can play in
helping people establish and maintain
relationships with other individuals or groups
(see also McGuire, 1969). Meanwhile,
defense motivation encapsulated self-
oriented defensive functions such as Katz’s
(1960) ego-defensive function and Smith
et al.s (1956) externalization function, which
suggested that some attitudes serve to protect
individuals’ self-image against internal or
external threats.
Considerable evidence supports the notion
that impression motivation can guide heuris-
tic and systematic processing (see Chaiken
et al., 1996, for a review). For example, Chen
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
258
et al. (1996: Study 2) led participants to
anticipate a discussion about a social issue
with a partner who ostensibly held either a
favorable or an unfavorable opinion on the
issue. Before this discussion, participants
read a series of fictitious scenarios designed
to prime either the accuracy goal of deter-
mining a valid opinion, or the impression
goal of getting along with other people. After
this task, participants familiarized them-
selves with the discussion issue by reading
an evaluatively balanced essay concerning
the issue (in this case, whether election
returns should be broadcast while polls are
still open). Participants then listed the
thoughts that had occurred to them as they
read the essay and indicated their own atti-
tudes toward the issue.
Impression-motivated participants expres-
sed attitudes that were much more congruent
with their alleged partners’ attitudes than did
accuracy-motivated participants: when the
partner favored one side of the issue, they
favored the same side, whereas when the
partner opposed it, they opposed it. Inter-
estingly, accuracy-motivated and impression-
motivated participants exhibited the same
amount of systematic processing (as meas-
ured by the number of issue-relevant thoughts
that were listed). However, whereas accu-
racy-motivated participants’ systematic
processing was open-minded and unbiased
by their partners’ attitudes, impression-
motivated participants exhibited systematic
processing that was biased toward their
partners’ attitudes. For example, when the
partner favored allowing broadcasts of elec-
tion returns while the polls were still open,
impression-motivated participants listed
thoughts that revealed much more favorable
thinking about arguments supporting the
broadcasting of returns and more unfavora-
ble thinking about arguments opposing it.
Like impression motivation, defense
motivation can also guide heuristic and sys-
tematic processing in a directional fashion,
as individuals attempt to close the gap
between actual and desired confidence that a
judgment will protect their cherished beliefs
and self-views (e.g., Ditto and Lopez, 1992;
Giner-Sorolla and Chaiken, 1997; Liberman
and Chaiken, 1992; Lord et al., 1979). For
instance, Giner-Sorolla and Chaiken (1997)
found that participants’ vested interest in
a campus issue biased their judgments of a
consensus cue’s reliability, when additional
information that would permit systematic
processing was unavailable. Specifically,
participants rated the consensus information
(an opinion poll of their fellow students) as
more reliable, and criticized it less, when the
poll results supported rather than opposed
their vested interests. When additional
information was available, participants also
displayed a defensive bias in their systematic
processing, cognitively elaborating the argu-
ments presented in a selective manner that
reflected their vested interests. Interestingly,
when both types of information were availa-
ble, exposure to a hostile consensus cue
appeared to undermine judgmental confi-
dence and increase systematic processing of
the arguments presented: In these conditions,
the influence of vested interests on partici-
pants’ subsequent attitudes was mediated by
their cognitive elaborations about the issue.
In contrast, exposure to a congenial cue
appeared to close the confidence gap, such
that participants simply used their vested
interests to directly inform their subsequent
attitudes, rather than engaging in additional
heuristic or systematic processing. Thus, as
with accuracy and impression motives, both
heuristic and systematic processing can be
used to serve self-protective processing
goals.
IMPLICATIONS FOR SOCIAL ISSUES
Because it focuses on the basic mechanisms
by which persuasion can occur, the heuristic-
systematic model can predict how a wide
range of variables will influence attitudes
and judgments in various situations. It is
therefore a particularly powerful tool for
understanding and influencing information
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
259
processing in ways that can help effect posi-
tive social change, and has been applied to
diverse issues such as increasing individuals’
acceptance of potentially threatening health
information, improving the design of product
warning labels, identifying and decreasing
bias in jury decision-making, increasing
recycling behavior, and developing more
effective programs for preventing substance
abuse among teens (e.g., Brewer and Hupfeld,
2004; ForsterLee et al., 2006; Harris and
Napper, 2005; Howard et al., 2006; Jepson
and Chaiken, 1990; Liberman and Chaiken,
1992; Scott, 1996; Werner et al., 2002;
Zuckerman and Chaiken, 1998). Here, we
discuss the implications of the heuristic-
systematic model for two areas that we find
particularly interesting: negotiation and
political decision-making.
Negotiation and conflict
resolution
Recent research exploring heuristic and sys-
tematic processing in simulated negotiations
has confirmed the utility of a dual-process
perspective for understanding information
processing in conflict settings (see
Ledgerwood et al., 2006, for a review).
Specifically, when negotiators have modest
levels of motivation (or low cognitive capac-
ity), they often rely on heuristics such as
fixed-pie assumptions (the perception that a
negotiation is a zero-sum game), initial
anchor values (e.g., first offers, or informa-
tion about the typical outcome of similar
negotiations), and stereotypes about an
opponent’s group membership (De Dreu
et al., 1999; Thompson and Hastie, 1990; see
De Dreu, 2004, for a review). In contrast,
when motivation and capacity are relatively
high, sole reliance on these heuristics tends
to decrease as systematic processing
increases.
Researchers have identified several factors
that influence the extent to which people
process information in negotiations (see De
Dreu, 2004). These factors include both
stable individual differences and temporary
elements of a given situation that influence
motivation and/or capacity. For instance,
negotiators who are high in the dispositional
need for cognitive closure – that is, the desire
to reach a judgment quickly and avoid ambi-
guity (Webster and Kruglanski, 1994) – are
more likely to rely solely on heuristics than
are those who have a low need for closure
(De Dreu et al., 1999).
Temporary, situation-specific factors such
as the presence of a highly involving task or
process accountability (the need to justify the
way in which a decision is made) tend to
increase the extent of systematic processing,
whereas time pressure and capacity-degrad-
ing conditions (e.g., noise) tend to decrease
such processing (e.g., De Dreu, 2003; Tetlock
et al., 1989; see Ledgerwood et al., 2006, for
a review). For example, De Dreu (2003)
examined the effect of time pressure on
fixed-pie perceptions. Business students were
placed into pairs and asked to play the role of
a buyer or seller in a negotiation over the
purchase of a car. The negotiation task was
designed to hold integrative potential: the
different issues varied in importance to
the two negotiators, so that an integrative
solution that capitalized on this variation in
priorities would be more beneficial to both
negotiators than a 50:50 split based on a
fixed-pie assumption. Participants were led
to believe that they had either plenty of time
in which to complete the negotiation (low
time pressure condition), or relatively little
time (high time pressure condition).
Participants were more likely to revise their
fixed-pie assumptions, which led to higher
joint outcomes, under low rather than high
time pressure. These results suggest that
time pressure reduces systematic processing,
heightening reliance on heuristic cues
such as fixed-pie perceptions and preventing
negotiators from capitalizing on integrative
potential.
In contrast, when an individual expects
to discuss an issue with, justify a decision to,
or be evaluated by an unknown audience,
he or she tends to engage in pre-emptive
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
260
self-criticism, displaying a heightened moti-
vation to arrive at an accurate conclusion
(Lerner and Tetlock, 1999; Tetlock et al.,
1989). In terms of the heuristic-systematic
model, holding a person accountable to an
audience whose views are unknown can
increase desired confidence for a correct
judgment and thereby stimulate accuracy-
motivated systematic processing. Confirming
this idea, De Dreu et al. (2000) randomly
assigned business student participants to
high-accountability and low-accountability
conditions before asking them to engage in a
mock negotiation over the purchase of a car.
In the high-accountability condition, partici-
pants expected that their negotiation strate-
gies and decisions would be reviewed and
evaluated several days later by an experi-
enced negotiator and a psychologist. In the
low-accountability condition, participants
did not receive this information. The results
showed that under high accountability,
participants were more likely to revise their
fixed-pie assumptions and tended to obtain
higher joint outcomes. Together, these
studies suggest that negotiation outcomes
can be improved by reducing the impact of
variables that decrease accuracy motivation
and capacity (like time pressure), as well as
by facilitating factors that increase accuracy
motivation (like accountability to an impar-
tial expert).
Political attitudes
The heuristic-systematic model can also be
used to shed light on political decision-
making and voting behavior (e.g., Forehand
et al., 2004; Marcus et al., 2000; Mondak,
1993; Newman and Perloff, 2004), and
suggests that the impact of various factors on
political judgments and intentions will
depend on a voter’s ability and motivation to
think about available information. When
people are motivated and able to process
political information, they will tend to
weigh the quality of the arguments put forth
regarding an issue or candidate. In contrast,
when people are low in motivation to process
information about political issues or candi-
dates (e.g., involvement and personal
relevance are low), or lack the ability to proc-
ess systematically (e.g., they are stressed or
under time pressure), they may tend to rely
on heuristics such as party labels, expert or
celebrity endorsements, and source cues such
as attractiveness or group membership. For
example, a low-motivation or low-capacity
voter might oppose a state ballot initiative
because Oprah opposes it, support a senator
because the letter (“D” or “R”) next to the
name matches the voter’s typical political
preferences, or vote for a presidential candi-
date because their facial features convey an
air of competence (see Hall et al., 2009;
Todorov et al., 2005).
Political psychologists have identified
five broad categories of heuristics that can
influence voting behavior: party affiliation,
ideological affiliation, endorsements, polls
(i.e., consensus information), and candidate
appearance (Lau and Redlawsk, 2001).
Although in an ideal world, citizens partici-
pating in a democratic process would usually
think carefully and critically about political
information before arriving at conclusion,
heuristic processing is thought to guide a
substantial portion of political decision-
making. For instance, echoing Converse’s
(1964) observation that the majority of
Americans display relatively low levels of
political sophistication and knowledge,
Mondak (1993) suggested that most voters
face a range of pressing everyday concerns
that tend to take precedence over political
matters, increasing the likelihood that voters
will rely on heuristics when processing
political information (see also Ledgerwood
and Chaiken, 2007). Consistent with this
notion, Lau and Redlawsk (2001) found a
high rate of heuristic use among individuals
participating in a mock presidential election.
Using a process-tracing methodology, these
researchers were able to track the extent to
which participants accessed different kinds
of information about the candidates on a
computer: They provided participants with a
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
261
list of available types of information (e.g.,
“Issue Stance,” “Past Experience,” “Endorse-
ments”), each of which could be opened with
a mouse click to display the relevant infor-
mation, and then recorded which kinds
of information participants chose to access.
Information from each of Lau and Redlawsk’s
five political heuristic categories was accessed
by over 90 percent of participants.
Interestingly, different participants also
appeared to prefer different types of heuris-
tics: those higher in political expertise were
more likely to use ideology and endorsement
heuristics, whereas those lower in expertise
were more likely to use candidate appearance
heuristics. As the heuristic-systematic model
would predict, participants were more likely
to use heuristics when their ability to engage
in more effortful processing was limited (i.e.,
when the information environment was made
more complex by having the information
labels actively scroll past participants on the
computer screen rather than remain static).
Lau and Redlawsk’s (2001) study suggests
that all five categories of heuristics are likely
to play a role in a given election; however,
some types have been studied more
frequently than others. For example, given
the prolific use of endorsements for a wide
variety of political attitude objects (including
everything from local ballot initiatives to
presidential candidates), and from a wide
variety of endorsers (ranging from political
organizations to celebrities), political scien-
tists have been particularly interested in how
endorsement heuristics influence political
opinions and voting behavior. Using data
from a California poll regarding an upcom-
ing election for members of the State Supreme
Court, Mondak (1993) showed that endorse-
ments increased voters’ willingness to express
an opinion and the direction of that opinion
when they had relatively little information
about the issue. Specifically, respondents
were more likely to say a Supreme Court
justice should be retained or recalled (rather
than choosing “not sure”) when told which
governor had appointed the justice, and they
used their evaluation of the governor to guide
their evaluation of the justice in question.
In other words, they used the governor’s
endorsement as a heuristic in forming an
attitude toward the associated Supreme
Court justice. Consistent with the heuristic-
systematic model, this was more likely to
occur when respondents had been previously
exposed to relatively little media information
regarding the justice (thereby limiting their
ability to engage in systematic processing)
and for respondents scoring higher on a need
for cognitive efficiency measure (designed to
tap both motivation and ability to carefully
process information).
In Mondak’s (1993) study, the heuristic
implication of an endorsement from a politi-
cian depended on a voter’s attitude toward
that politician. However, the impact of
an endorsement could also depend on the
perceived reliability of the heuristic for a
particular judgmental task; that is, the extent
to which a perceiver deems a heuristic to be
a valid guide for judgment in a given situa-
tion (see Chen and Chaiken, 1999). For
example, when considering an environmental
issue, a voter might feel that an endorsement
from Greenpeace affords a sizeable increase
in judgmental confidence, whereas an
endorsement from the National Basketball
Association does not, despite equivalent
evaluations of the two organizations. Indeed,
Forehand et al. (2004) found that participants
expressed more favorable attitudes toward a
hypothetical initiative when it was endorsed
by a well-known and issue-relevant source
rather than a fictional or issue-irrelevant
source. Supporting the heuristic-systematic
model’s sufficiency principle, this difference
emerged in a low motivation context (in
which participants expected to justify their
preferences about an unimportant and unre-
lated issue, ballot formatting) but not a high
motivation context (in which participants
expected to be held accountable for their
position on the initiative itself).
Group endorsements can also act to bias
systematic information processing about an
issue or a candidate. Individuals may be
motivated by defense or impression concerns
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
262
to agree with an ingroup and disagree with an
outgroup, and may therefore process infor-
mation selectively to arrive at these preferred
judgments (Fleming and Petty, 2000). For
example, Cohen (2003: Study 4) asked lib-
eral undergraduate students to evaluate a
(stereotypically liberal) proposal for a gener-
ous federally funded job-training program.
Half the participants learned that Democrats
opposed and Republicans supported the
program, while half received no information
about group endorsement. On average,
participants in the latter condition supported
the program, in keeping with their ideologi-
cal beliefs. However, when participants were
told that their ingroup opposed the program,
they showed biased processing of the infor-
mation presented in the proposal, selectively
interpreting ambiguous information and
selectively attending to unambiguous infor-
mation to support the ingroup position. As a
result, participants in the ingroup-opposed
condition were more likely to oppose the
program themselves, compared to partici-
pants in the no-information condition.
Moreover, the Democratic participants
believed that group endorsement influenced
the attitudes of other Democrats and (even
more strongly) Republicans, but perceived
themselves to be relatively unaffected by this
information. Thus, consistent with the notion
that heuristic processing need not involve
intentionality and self-awareness (see
Chaiken et al., 1989; Chen and Chaiken,
1999), it seems likely that people are
unaware of the extent to which group endorse-
ments bias their thinking about an issue. This
may tend to exacerbate political conflicts:
whereas Democrats and Republicans might
agree on a policy in the absence of endorse-
ment information, merely attaching a party
label to a proposal can distort information
processing and lead partisans to adopt diver-
gent positions. Bipartisan proposals may
therefore be particularly likely to gain
public support not only because their actual
content may better address the political goals
of both groups, but also because the absence
of a link to a particular party may help to
promote more open-minded information
processing.
CONCLUSION
Looking back, we see the heuristic-system-
atic model as very much a product of its
historical context, building on theories both
within the attitudes domain and outside of it,
and developing beyond the study of basic
social psychological processes to shed light
on important and relevant social issues. To
us, this illustrates the benefit of working in
an area with such a long and cumulative his-
tory that both influences and draws from
other psychological and related social-
science disciplines. In coming years, we
hope that the field continues to develop the
heuristic-systematic model in concert with
other dual-process theories, drawing from
the research that has already been done to
influence that which is yet to come.
REFERENCES
Allport, G. (1954) The Nature of Prejudice. Reading,
MA: Addison-Wesley.
Anderson, R.C. and Pichert, J.W. (1978) Recall of previ-
ously unrecallable information following a shift in
perspective. Journal of Verbal Learning and Verbal
Behavior, 17, 1–12.
Axsom, D., Yates, S.M. and Chaiken, S. (1987)
Audience response as a heuristic cue in persuasion.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 53,
30–40.
Bargh, J.A. (1994) The Four Horsemen of automaticity:
Awareness, efficiency, intention, and control in
social cognition. In R.S. Wyer, Jr. and T.K. Srull (eds),
Handbook of Social Cognition, 2nd Edition,
pp. 1–40. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Baumeister, R.F. and Leary, M.R. (1995) The need to
belong: Desire for interpersonal attachments as a
fundamental human motivation. Psychological
Bulletin, 117, 497–529.
Bem, D.J. (1972) Self-perception theory. In L. Berkowitz
(ed.), Advances in Experimental Social Psychology,
6, 1–62. New York: Academic Press.
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
263
Brewer, M.B. (1988) A dual-process model of impres-
sion formation. In T. Srull and R. Wyer (eds).
Advances in Social Cognition, 1, 1–36. Hillsdale,
NJ: Erlbaum.
Brewer, N. and Hupfeld, R.M. (2004) Effects of testimo-
nial inconsistencies and witness group identity on
mock-juror judgments. Journal of Applied Social
Psychology, 34, 493–513.
Brewer, W.F. and Treyens, J.C. (1981) Role of schemata
in memory for places. Cognitive Psychology, 13,
207–230.
Bruner, J.S. (1957) On perceptual readiness.
Psychological Review, 64, 123–152.
Chaiken, S. (1980) Heuristic versus systematic
information processing and the use of source versus
message cues in persuasion. Journal of Personality
and Social Psychology, 39, 752–766.
Chaiken, S. (1987) The heuristic model of persuasion.
In M.P. Zanna, J.M. Olson and C.P. Herman (eds),
Social Influence: The Ontario Symposium, 5, 3–39.
Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Chaiken, S., Axsom, D., Liberman, A. and Wilson, D.
(1992) Heuristic processing of persuasive
messages: Chronic and temporary sources of rule
accessibility. Unpublished manuscript, New York
University.
Chaiken, S. and Eagly, A.H. (1976) Communication
modality as a determinant of message persuasive-
ness and message comprehension. Journal of
Personality and Social Psychology, 34, 605–614.
Chaiken, S. and Eagly, A.H. (1983) Communication
modality as a determinant of persuasion: The role of
communicator salience. Journal of Personality and
Social Psychology, 45, 241–256.
Chaiken, S., Giner-Sorolla, R. and Chen, S. (1996)
Beyond accuracy: multiple motives in heuristic
and systematic processing. In P.M. Gollwitzer and
J.A. Bargh (eds), The Psychology of Action: Linking
Motivation and Cognition to Action, pp. 553–578.
New York: Guilford Press.
Chaiken, S., Liberman, A. and Eagly, A.H. (1989)
Heuristic and systematic information processing
within and beyond the persuasion context. In
J.S. Uleman and J.A. Bargh (eds), Unintended
Thought, pp. 212–252. New York: Guilford Press.
Chaiken, S. and Maheswaran, D. (1994) Heuristic
processing can bias systematic processing: Effects
of source credibility, argument ambiguity, and
task importance on attitude judgment. Journal
of Personality and Social Psychology, 66, 460–473.
Chaiken, S. and Trope, Y. (eds) (1999) Dual-Process
Theories in Social Psychology. New York: Guilford
Press.
Chen, S. and Chaiken, S. (1999) The heuristic-
systematic model in its broader context. In
S. Chaiken and Y. Trope (eds), Dual-process Theories
in Social Psychology, pp. 73–96. New York: Guilford
Press.
Chen, S., Shechter, D. and Chaiken, S. (1996) Getting
at the truth or getting along: Accuracy- versus
impression-motivated heuristic and systematic
processing. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 71, 262–275.
Cohen, G.L. (2003) Party over policy: The dominating
impact of group influence on political beliefs.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 85,
808–822.
Converse, P.E. (1964) The nature of belief systems in
mass publics. In D.E. Apter (ed.), Ideology and
Discontent, pp. 206–261. New York: Free Press.
Darke, P.R., Chaiken, S., Bohner, G., Einwiller, S.,
Erb, H.-P. and Hazlewood, J.D. (1998) Accuracy
motivation, consensus information, and the law of
large numbers: Effects on attitude judgment in the
absence of argumentation. Personality and Social
Psychology Bulletin, 24, 1205–1215.
De Dreu, C.K.W. (2003) Time pressure and closing of
the mind in negotiation. Organizational Behavior
and Human Decision Processes, 91, 280–295.
De Dreu, C.K.W. (2004) Motivation in negotiation:
A social psychological analysis. In M. Gelfand and
J. M. Brett (eds), Handbook of Negotiation and
Culture, pp. 114–135. Palo Alto, CA: Stanford
University Press.
De Dreu, C.K.W., Koole, S. and Oldersma, F.L. (1999)
On the seizing and freezing of negotiator inferences:
Need for cognitive closure moderates the use of
heuristics in negotiation. Personality and Social
Psychology Bulletin, 25, 348–362.
De Dreu, C. K. W., Koole, S. L. and Steinel, S. (2000)
Unfixing the fixed pie: A motivated information-
processing approach to integrative negotiation.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 79,
975-987.
Deutsch, M. and Gerard, H.B. (1955) A study of
normative and informational social infleunces upon
individual judgment. Journal of Abnormal Social
Psychology, 51, 629–636.
Devine, P.G. (1989) Stereotypes and prejudice:
Their automatic and controlled components.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 56,
5–18.
Ditto, P.H. and Lopez, D.F. (1992) Motivated skepti-
cism: Use of differential decision criteria for preferred
and nonpreferred conclusions. Journal of Personality
and Social Psychology, 63, 568–584.
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
264
Eagly, A.H. and Chaiken, S. (1993) The Psychology of
Attitudes. Belmont, CA: Wadsworth.
Erb, H.P., Bohner, G., Schmalzle, K. and Rank, S.
(1998) Beyond conflict and discrepancy: cognitive
bias in minority and majority influence. Personality
and Social Psychology Bulletin, 24, 620–633.
Fazio, R.H. and Towles-Schwen, T. (1999) The
MODE model of attitude-behavior processes. In
S. Chaiken and Y. Trope (eds), Dual-process Theories
in Social Psychology, pp. 97–116. New York:
Guilford.
Fiske, S.T. (2002) Five core social motives, plus or
minus five. In S.J. Spencer, S. Fein, M.P. Zanna and
J. Olson (eds) Motivated Social Perception: The
Ontario Symposium, 9, 233–246. Mahwah, NJ:
Erlbaum.
Fiske, S.T. and Linville, P.W. (1980) What does the
schema concept buy us? Personality and Social
Psychology Bulletin, 6, 543–557.
Fiske, S.T., Lin, M.H. and Neuberg, S.L. (1999) The
Continuum Model: Ten years later. In S. Chaiken and
Y. Trope (eds), Dual-process Theories in Social
Psychology, pp. 231–254. New York: Guilford
Press.
Fiske, S.T. and Taylor, S.E. (2008) Social Cognition:
From Brains to Culture. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Fleming, M.A. and Petty, R.E. (2000) Identity and
persuasion: An elaboration likelihood approach. In
D.J. Terry and M.A. Hogg (eds), Attitudes, Behavior,
and Social Context: The Role of Norms and Group
Membership, pp. 171–199. Mahwah, NJ: Lawrence
Erlbaum Associates.
Forehand, M., Gastil, J. and Smith, M.A. (2004)
Endorsements as voting cues: Heuristic and system-
atic processing in initiative elections. Journal of
Applied Social Psychology, 34, 2215–2233.
ForsterLee, R., ForsterLee, L., Horowitz, I.A. and King,
E. (2006) The effects of defendant race, victim
race, and juror gender on evidence processing in a
murder trial. Behavioral Sciences and the Law, 24,
179–198.
Gawronski, B. and Bodenhausen, G.V. (2006)
Associative and propositional processes in evalua-
tion: An integrative review of implicit and explicit
attitude change. Psychological Bulletin, 132,
692–731.
Gilbert, D.T. (1989) Thinking lightly about others:
Automatic components of the social inference
process. In J.S. Uleman and J.A. Bargh (eds),
Unintended Thought, pp. 189–211. New York:
Guilford.
Giner-Sorolla, R. and Chaiken, S. (1997) Selective use
of heuristic and systematic processing under defense
motivation. Personality and Social Psychology
Bulletin, 23, 84–97.
Giner-Sorolla, R., Chaiken, S. and Lutz, S. (2002)
Validity beliefs and ideology can influence legal
case judgments differently. Law and Human
Behavior, 26, 507–526.
Hall, C.C, Goren, A., Chaiken, S. and Todorov, A.
(2009) Shallow cues with deep effects: Trait judg-
ments from faces and voting decisions. In E. Borgida,
J.L. Sullivan, and C.M. Federico (eds), The Political
Psychology of Democratic Citizenship, pp. 73–99.
Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Harris, P.R. and Napper, L. (2005) Self-affirmation and
the biased processing of health-risk information.
Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 31,
1250–1263.
Heider, F. (1958) The psychology of interpersonal
relations
. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley.
Higgins, E.T. (1989) Knowledge accessibility and acti-
vation: Subjectivity and suffering from unconscious
sources. In J. S. Uleman and J. A. Bargh (eds),
Unintended thought, pp. 75–115. New York:
Guilford Press.
Higgins, E.T., King, G.A. and Mavin, G.H. (1982.
Individual construct accessibility and subjective
impressions and recall. Journal of Personality &
Social Psychology, 43, 35–47.
Higgins, E.T. and McCann, C.D. (1984) Social encoding
and subsequent attitudes, impressions, and memory:
‘Context-driven’ and motivational aspects of
processing. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 47, 26–39.
Howard, M.V.A, Brewer, N. and Williams, K.D. (2006)
How processing resources shape the influence of
stealing thunder on mock-juror verdicts. Psychiatry,
Psychology and Law, 13, 60–66.
Jepson, C. and Chaiken, S. (1990) Chronic issue-
specific fear inhibits systematic processing of
persuasive communications. Journal of Social
Behavior and Personality, 5, 61–84.
Johnson, B.T. and Eagly, A.H. (1989) The effects of
involvement on persuasion: A meta-analysis.
Psychological Bulletin, 106, 290–314.
Jones, E.E. and Davis, K.E. (1965) From acts to
dispositions: The attribution process in social
psychology. In L. Berkowitz (ed.), Advances in
Experimental Social Psychology, 2, 219–266.
New York: Academic Press.
Katz, D. (1960) The functional approach to the
study of attitudes. Public Opinion Quarterly, 24,
163–204.
Kelley, H.H. (1972) Causal Schemata and the Attribution
Process. New York: General Learning Press.
A THEORY OF HEURISTIC AND SYSTEMATIC INFORMATION PROCESSING
265
Kelley, H.H. (1973) The processes of causal attribution.
American Psychologist, 28, 107–128.
Kiesler, C.A. (1971) The Psychology of Commitment:
Experiments Linking Behavior to Belief. San Diego,
CA: Academic Press.
Kohler, W. (1930) Gestalt Psychology. London: Bell.
Lau, R.R. and Redlawsk, D.P. (2001) An experimental
study of information search, memory, and decision
making during a political campaign. In J. Kuklinski
(ed.), Citizens and Politics: Perspectives from Political
Psychology, pp. 136–159. New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Ledgerwood, A. and Chaiken, S. (2007) Priming us and
them: Automatic assimilation and contrast in group
attitudes. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 93, 940–956.
Ledgerwood, A., Chaiken, S., Gruenfeld, D.H. and
Judd, C.M. (2006) Changing minds: Persuasion in
negotiation and conflict resolution. In M. Deutsch,
P.T. Coleman and E.C. Marcus (eds), The Handbook
of Conflict Resolution: Theory and Practice,
2nd Edition, pp. 455–485. San Francisco: Jossey-
Bass.
Ledgerwood, A., Mandisodza, A.N., Jost, J.T. and
Pohl, M.J. (in press) Working for the system:
Motivated defense of meritocratic beliefs. Social
Cognition.
Lerner, J.S. and Tetlock, P.E. (1999) Accounting for
the effects of accountability. Psychological Bulletin,
125, 255–275.
Liberman, A. and Chaiken, S. (1992) Defensive
processing of personally relevant health messages.
Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin, 18,
669–679.
Lord, C.G., Ross, L. and Lepper, M.R. (1979) Biased
assimilation and attitude polarization: The effects of
prior theories on subsequently considered evidence.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 37,
2098–2109.
Mackie, D.M. (1987) Systematic and nonsystematic
processing of majority and minority persuasive
communications. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 53, 41–52.
Maheswaran, D. and Chaiken, S. (1991) Promoting
systematic processing in low motivation settings:
Effect of incongruent information on processing and
judgment. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 61, 13–25.
Maheswaran, D., Mackie, D.M. and Chaiken, S. (1992)
Brand name as a heuristic cue: The effects of task
importance and expectancy confirmation on
consumer judgments. Journal of Consumer
Psychology, 1, 317–336.
Marcus, G.E., Neumann, W.R. and MacKuen, M.B.
(2000) Affective Intelligence and Political Judgment.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Martin, R., Hewstone, M. and Martin, P.Y. (2007)
Systematic and heuristic processing of majority and
minority endorsed messages: The effects of varying
‘levels of orientation’ and outcome relevance on
attitude and message processing. Personality and
Social Psychology Bulletin, 33, 43–56.
McGuire, W.J. (1969) The nature of attitudes and
attitude change. In G. Lindzey and E. Aronson (eds),
Handbook of Social Psychology, 2nd Edition, 3,
136–314. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Mondak, J.J. (1993) Public opinion and heuristic
processing of source cues. Political Behavior, 15,
167–192.
Moskowitz, G.B., Skurnik, L and Galinsky, A.D. (1999)
The history of dual-process notions, and the future
of pre-conscious control. In S. Chaiken and Y. Trope
(eds), Dual-process Theories in Social Psychology,
pp. 12–36. New York: Guilford Press.
Newman, B.I. and Perloff, R.M. (2004) Political
marketing: theory, research, and applications. In
L.L. Kaid (ed.), Handbook of Political Communication
Research, pp. 17–43. Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum.
Pallak, M.S., Mueller, M., Dollar, K. and Pallak, J.
(1972) Effect of commitment on responsiveness to
an extreme consonant communication. Journal of
Personality and Social Psychology, 23, 429–436.
Petty, R.E. and Cacioppo, J.T. (1984) Source
factors and the elaboration likelihood model of
persuasion. Advances in Consumer Research, 11,
668–672.
Petty, R.E., Cacioppo, J.T. and Goldman, R. (1981)
Personal involvement as a determinant of argument-
based persuasion. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 41, 847–855.
Petty, R. E. and Wegener, D. T. (1999) The elaboration
likelihood model: Current status and controversies.
In S. Chaiken and Y. Trope (eds), Dual process
theories in social psychology, pp. 37-72. New York:
Guilford.
Petty, R.E., Wells, G.L. and Brock, T.C. (1976)
Distraction can enhance or reduce yielding to
propaganda: Thought disruption versus effort
justification. Journal of Personality and Social
Psychology, 34, 874–884.
Ratneshwar, S. and Chaiken, S. (1991) Comprehension’s
role in persuasion: The case of its moderating effect
on the persuasive impact of source cues. Journal of
Consumer Research, 18, 52–62.
Scott, C.G. (1996) Understanding attitude change in
developing effective substance abuse prevention
HANDBOOK OF THEORIES OF SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGY
266
programs for adolescents. The School Counselor,
43, 187–195.
Sherif, M. and Cantril, H. (1947) The Psychology of
Ego-involvements: Social Attitudes and Identifications.
New York: Wiley.
Sherif, M. and Hovland, C.I. (1961) Social Judgment:
Assimilation and Contrast Effects in Communication
and Attitude Change. New Haven, CT: Yale University
Press.
Simon, H.A. (1976). Administrative Behavior, 3rd
Edition. New York: Free Press.
Smith, E.R. and DeCoster, J. (2000) Dual-process
models in social and cognitive psychology:
Conceptual integration and links to underlying
memory systems. Personality and Social Psychology
Review, 4, 108–131.
Smith, M.B., Bruner, J.S. and White, R.W. (1956)
Opinions and Personality. New York: Wiley.
Stroebe, W. and Diehl, M. (1988) When social support
fails: Supporter characteristics in compliance-induced
attitude change. Personality and Social Psychology
Bulletin, 14, 136–144.
Taylor, S.E. (1975) On inferring one’s attitudes
from one’s behavior: Some delimiting conditions.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 31,
126–131.
Taylor, S.E. and Crocker, J. (1981) Schematic bases
of social information processing. In E.T. Higgins,
C.P. Herman and M.P. Zanna (eds), Social Cognition:
The Ontario Symposium, 1 (pp. 89–134. Hillsdale,
NJ: Erlbaum.
Tesser, A. and Campbell, J. (1983) Self-definition
and self-evaluation maintenance. In J. Suls and
A. Greenwald (eds), Social Psychological Perspectives
on the Self, 2, 1–31). Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Tetlock, P.E. (1989) Structure and function in political
belief systems. In A.R. Pratkanis, S.J. Breckler and
A.G. Greenwald (eds), Attitude Structure and
Function, pp. 129–151. Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum.
Tetlock, P.E., Skitka, L. and Boettger, R. (1989) Social
and cognitive strategies for coping with account-
ability: Conformity, complexity, and bolstering.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 57,
632–640.
Thompson, L.L. and Hastie, R. (1990) Social perception
in negotiation. Organizational Behavior and Human
Decision Processes, 47, 98–123.
Todorov, A., Mandisodza, A.N., Goren, A. and
Hall, C.C. (2005) Inferences of competence from
faces predict election outcomes. Science, 308,
1623–1626.
Tversky, A. and Kahneman, D. (1974) Judgment under
uncertainty: Heuristics and biases. Science, 185,
1124–1131.
Webster, D.M. and Kruglanski, A.W. (1994)
Individual differences in need for cognitive closure.
Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 67,
1049–1062.
Werner, C.M., Stroll, R., Birch, P. and White, P.H.
(2002) Clinical validation and cognitive elaboration:
Signs that encourage sustained recycling. Basic and
Applied Social Psychology,
24, 185–203.
Wood, W., Kallgren, C.A. and Preisler, R.M (1985)
Access to attitude-relevant information in memory
as a determinant of persuasion: The role of message
attributes. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology,
21, 73–85.
Yates, J. (1985) The content of awareness is a model of
the world. Psychological Review, 92, 249–284.
Ziegler, R., von Schwichow, A. and Diehl, M.
(2005) Matching the message source to attitude
functions: Implications for biased processing.
Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 41,
645–653.
Zuckerman, A. and Chaiken, S. (1998) A heuristic-
systematic processing analysis of the effectiveness of
product warning labels. Psychology and Marketing,
15, 621–664.