Prepared by a joint team comprised of
Era Dabla-Norris, Ruud de Mooij, Andrew Hodge,
Jan Loeprick, Dinar Prihardini, Alpa Shah,
Sebastian Beer, Sonja Davidovic,
Arbind Modi, and Fan Qi
Digitalization and
Taxation in Asia
Asia-Pacic and Fiscal Affairs Departments
DP/2021/017
INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND
Digitalization and
Taxation in Asia
Prepared by a joint team from the IMF Asia-Pacic and Fiscal Aairs
Departments, comprised of Era Dabla-Norris, Ruud de Mooij,
Andrew Hodge, Jan Loeprick, Dinar Prihardini, Alpa Shah,
Sebastian Beer, Sonja Davidovic, Arbind Modi, and Fan Qi
Asia-Pacific and Fiscal Affairs Departments
Copyright ©2021 International Monetary Fund
Cataloging-in-Publication Data
IMF Library
Names: Dabla-Norris, Era, project director. | Mooij, Ruud A. de, project director. |International Monetary
Fund. Asia and Pacic Department, issuing body. | International
Monetary Fund. Fiscal Aairs Department, issuing body. | International Monetary Fund, publisher.
Title: Digitalization and taxation in Asia / prepared by a joint team from the IMF Asia-Pacic and Fiscal
Aairs Departments, led by Era Dabla-Norris and Ruud de Mooij.
Other titles: International Monetary Fund. Asia and Pacic Department (Series). | International Monetary
Fund. Fiscal Aairs Department (Series).
Description: Washington, DC : International Monetary Fund, 2021. | Departmental paper series. | “Prepared
by a joint team from the IMF Asia-Pacic and Fiscal Aairs Departments, led by Era Dabla-Norris and
Ruud de Mooij, and comprising Andrew Hodge, Jan Loeprick, Dinar Prihardini (coordinator), Alpa Shah,
with contributions from Sebastian Beer, Sonja Davidovic, Arbind Modi, and Fan Qi. Research assistance was
provided by Hibah Khan and Biying Zhu. Soa Cerna Rubinstein supported the production of the paper.” |
Includes bibliographical references.
Identiers: ISBN 9781513577425
Subjects: LCSH: Technological innovations—Economic aspects—Asia. | Taxation—Asia. | Tax administration
and procedure—Asia.
Classication: LCC T173.8 D33 2021
Prepared by a joint team from the IMF Asia-Pacic and Fiscal Aairs Departments, led by Era Dabla-Norris
and Ruud de Mooij, and comprising Andrew Hodge, Jan Loeprick, Dinar Prihardini (coordinator), Alpa Shah,
with contributions from Sebastian Beer, Sonja Davidovic, Arbind Modi, and Fan Qi. Research assistance was
provided by Hibah Khan and Biying Zhu. Soa Cerna Rubinstein supported the production of the paper.
Publication orders may be placed online, by fax, or through the mail:
International Monetary Fund, Publication Services
P.O. Box92780, Washington, DC 20090, U.S.A.
Tel. (202) 623-7430 Fax: (202) 623-7201
www.imfbookstore.org
www.elibrary.imf.org
is joint Asia-Pacic–Fiscal Aairs Departmental Paper presents research by IMF sta on issues of broad
regional or cross-country interest. e views expressed in this paper are those of the author(s) and do not
necessarily represent the views of the IMF, its Executive Board, or IMF management.
Contents
Glossary ����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������v
Executive Summary ������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� vii
Introduction �������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 1
1� Digitalization in Asia ������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 5
Asias ICT Sector ............................................................................................................ 6
Digitalization Beyond the ICT Sector ............................................................................6
How Is Digitalization in Asia Dierent? ........................................................................9
2� Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia––Challenges and a Way
Forward �������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 17
Challenges of Taxing Digitalized Businesses in Asia .....................................................17
Multilateral Reform ......................................................................................................18
Digital Services Taxes ...................................................................................................24
Alternative Policy Options ...........................................................................................34
3� Digital Services, Digitally Delivered Goods, and VAT ��������������������������������������������� 43
Digital Services in Asia .................................................................................................44
Policy Options and Country Practices..........................................................................45
Revenue Potential .........................................................................................................49
Annex 1� Methodology �������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 55
Annex 2� Detailed Formulary Apportionment Results �������������������������������������������������� 59
References ���������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 61
Boxes
Box 1. Amazon and Alibaba––Comparison between an American and Asian Tech
Giant ......................................................................................................................14
Box 2. Indias Equalization Levy ..................................................................................40
Box 3. Ensuring Taxation of Intermediary Fees ............................................................51
Box 4. GST Compliance Mechanism for Supply of Digital Services by MNEs in
the Case of India .................................................................................................... 52
Tables
Table 1. Residual Prot by Headquater Jurisdiction, 2017...........................................20
Table 2. Residual Prot and Other Descriptive Statistics by Sector, 2017 ....................21
iii
Table 3. Digital Services Taxes in Asia ..........................................................................25
Table 4. e Economic Impact of DSTs ......................................................................28
Table 5. VAT on Digital Services––Approaches in Asia-Pacic ....................................46
Figures
Figure 1. A Digitalized Economy ...................................................................................6
Figure 2. Asias ICT Sector .............................................................................................7
Figure 3. Internet Access in Asia ....................................................................................8
Figure 4. E-Commerce in Asia .......................................................................................9
Figure 5. Asian Sales of E-Commerce Companies ........................................................10
Figure 6. Global Market Share: E-Commerce Companies ...........................................10
Figure 7. Turnover of Asias Tech Giants ......................................................................11
Figure 8. Sales, Productivity, and Prots of Asias Tech Giants .....................................11
Figure 9. Income Tax Expensed ...................................................................................12
Figure 10. Growth of Asias Tech Giants ......................................................................13
Figure 11. Top 20 Locations of Residual Prot ............................................................22
Figure 12. Potential Revenue Eects of Pillar 1, Amount A .........................................23
Figure 13. Facebook: Active Users and Average Revenue Per User ...............................30
Figure 14. Survey-Based Estimates of the Tax Base and Revenue Potential in 2019 ..... 31
Figure 15. MNE Activities at Home and Abroad and the Destination of Asian
MNE Prots ..........................................................................................................33
Figure 16. Change in Income Tax Revenue from Applying FA ....................................36
Figure 17. Total CIT Revenue Eects from Destination-Based RPA ............................36
Figure 18. Partial CIT Revenue Eects—from Elimination of Prot Shifting .............38
Figure 19. Partial CIT Revenue Eects—from Reallocation of Residual Earnings ....... 39
Figure 20. Increase in Digitally Delivered Services and Demand for Digital Media ..... 45
Figure 21. Survey-Based Estimates of Direct VAT Revenue Potential and VAT
Eciency in Asia....................................................................................................50
iv
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
Glossary
ADS Automated Digital Service
B2B Business to Business
B2C Business to Consumer
BEPS Base Erosion and Prot Shifting
CbCR Country by Country Reporting
CIT Corporate Income Tax
Destination country Country in which the purchaser is located (same as
market country)
DST Digital Services Tax
EL Equalization Levy
EU European Union
FA Formula Apportionment
FDI Foreign Direct Investment
G20 e G20 is the international forum that brings
together the world’s major economies
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GST Goods and Services Tax
ICT Information and Communications Technology
IF Inclusive Framework
Investment Hub Generally refer to countries with a high ratio of FDI
to GDP. For example, the OECD considers those
countries with inward FDI greater than 150 percent
of GDP to be an investment hub.
Market country Country in which the purchaser is located (same as
destination country)
IGST Integrated Goods and Services Tax
MNE Multinational Enterprise
OECD Organisation for Economic Cooperation and
Development
v
OIDAR India is chargeable on supply of Online Information
Database Access and Retrieval
PE Permanent Establishment
Prot shifting Shifting of where prots are booked for tax purposes,
and encompasses base erosion
Rents Earnings in excess of the normal required return
Residence country For a corporation (most frequently the location of
managerial functions; occasionally the place of
incorporation)
Residual prot Prots in excess of routine
Routine return Broadly equivalent to normal return, commonly as
identied by transfer pricing methods
RP Residual Prot
RPA Residual Prot Allocation
Source country Jurisdiction in which production of goods or services
occurs
User participation Contribution by the user of the product to the busi-
ness model
VAT Value-Added Tax
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
vi
Executive Summary
Digitalization in Asia is pervasive, unique, and growing. It stands out by
its sheer scale, with internet users far exceeding numbers in other regions.
is facilitates e-commerce in markets that are large by international stan-
dards, supported by innovative payment systems and featuring major cor-
porate players, including a number of large, home-grown, highly digitalized
businesses (tech giants) that rival US multinational enterprises (MNEs) in
size. Opportunity for future growth exists, as a signicant population share
remains unconnected.
Digitalization raises new tax challenges and existing rules can be perceived as
unfair. Existing income tax systems have been criticized as failing to con-
fer taxing rights on jurisdictions where highly digitalized businesses have a
large base of customers that generate value, but where they have no physical
presence. Increasingly digitalized businesses may also have relatively more
intangible assets (for example, trademark and patents), which are harder to
value and easier to relocate, enabling prot shifting under existing rules. is
may especially aect smaller, less developed economies. e nexus of digitali-
zation and tax also goes beyond income taxation, raising issues regarding the
eective value-added taxation of digital services, property rights over private
information, and the use of digital technology in tax design and revenue
administration.
Global tax reform proposals will create winners and losers in the region,
although the overall revenue impact is likely to be modest. New taxing rights
for market countries at the expense of residence countries, along the lines of
proposals discussed under Pillar 1 of the OECD-Inclusive Framework (IF)
will change the geographic distribution of tax revenue paid by MNEs in Asia.
Investment hubs and low-tax jurisdictions are likely to lose revenue as less
prot will be shifted towards them. Countries that do not host the headquar-
ters of large MNEs, but have a large user base of their customers, are likely to
gain revenue from the reallocation. Results are more ambiguous for countries
vii
that have both a large market and tax residence for large MNEs. For exam-
ple, the home countries of Asias tech giants could lose revenue if these rms
have to pay more tax in other countries where they are expanding. While
the revenue eects are likely to be modest for most countries under current
proposals, the rapid pace of digitalization can increase the importance of this
revenue reallocation eect over time.
Digitalization is increasing pressure on the century-old international tax
framework, which more fundamental reforms could address in the medium
term. e reforms currently being considered in the OECD-IF could be
a step toward more comprehensive reforms in the future. Systems that are
being discussed among tax experts include, for example, formulary appor-
tionment and residual prot allocation. ese approaches would cause a
much larger reallocation of tax revenue across countries, with the largest
losses expected for investment hubs. At the same time, these proposals could
deliver considerable simplication and closer alignment of prot attributions
to where production and sales take place. Depending on the design, these
reforms could also ease the pressure of international tax competition and
provide scope for increasing revenue raised from MNEs, including through
an increase in CIT rates as desired by countries.
Unilateral tax measures, such as digital services taxes (DSTs), adopted by a
number of Asian countries are likely to have small revenue eects. DSTs are
simpler in design and implementation than corporate income tax initiatives,
but risk introducing distortions of double taxation and trade retaliation. In
taxing gross revenue, they are blind to the protability of the ring-fenced
tech giants and therefore less ecient than alternative prot taxation reform
options. Countries with domestic tech giants may nd a DST less attractive
as the income of these rms is already taxed under the existing CIT regime.
A relatively narrow gross revenue tax base also results in limited revenue col-
lection—often estimated in the range of 0.01-0.02 percent of GDP, suggest-
ing that the choice to introduce a DST needs to be weighed against other tax
reform priorities. at said, revenue from DSTs may have higher buoyancy in
the future, given strong growth of digital economic activity, a trend that has
been accelerated by the COVID-19 pandemic.
Extending the value added taxes (VAT) to capture e-commerce and digi-
tal services more eectively could yield signicant short-term revenue and
other eciency gains. Capturing VAT on digitally provided services and
e-commerce supplied from abroad will help countries increase revenue
unilaterally. Applying VAT consistently on all digital imports also levels the
playing eld between domestic and foreign suppliers, and between goods
and services—thus enhancing eciency. e expected revenue eects from
eectively doing so are greater than from DSTs or the global reform proposal
currently under consideration under OECD-IF Pillar 1, in particular when
accounting for indirect returns from relying on marketplaces as a third party
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
viii
information source and as collection agents to expand the VAT base. ere is
scope to leverage administrative reforms in VAT on digital imports to sup-
port both the compliance management of residents and the implementation
of corporate tax reforms that shift taxing rights to the market country for
non-residents.
For many Asian countries, additional eorts in taxation are necessary to meet
their revenue mobilization needs. International tax reform towards greater
destination-based income taxation in combination with a global minimum
tax (Pillar 2 of the OECD-IF) would ease pressures from international tax
competition and allow countries to raise corporate income tax rates if desired.
Further revenue mobilization eorts might be required to nance future
spending needs. ese could focus on broadening the tax base by remov-
ing tax holidays, exemptions, and other preferential tax treatments. ese
are common in developing Asia but are often ineective and inecient and
could even become redundant under a global minimum tax. Digitalization of
tax administrations could further help revenue mobilization by addressing tax
evasion and widen the tax base for corporate taxes and VAT. Such compre-
hensive tax reforms, however, go beyond the scope of this paper.
Executive Summary
ix
Digitalization has been impacting countries in Asia and this eect is set
to grow in the aftermath of the COVID-19 pandemic. Digitalization has
extended well beyond the information communications and technology
(ICT) sector, with widespread internet usage underpinning e-commerce,
ntech, as well as online nancial and other services. In addition to rms
selling goods and services through their own websites, online platforms and
marketplaces have rapidly emerged that connect rms with consumers and
consumers with each other. ese business models are supported by cutting
edge technologies, including articial intelligence, machine learning, and big
data. Local rms have emerged as major players, particularly in large mar-
kets such as China, Japan, and Indonesia, competing with US multinational
enterprises (MNEs) operating in the region. e potential for further growth
in internet usage and the shift away from in-person activities during the
pandemic is likely to fuel the growth of large, digitalized businesses in Asia
in coming years, as well as the adoption of digital technologies across the
entire economy.
e experience of digitalization varies across Asian countries depending on
demographics, geography, and the stage of economic development. G20
economies such as China, Japan and Korea have large ICT sectors, including
manufacturing, and well-established, locally headquartered, highly digitalized
businesses engaging in e-commerce and online services. India and Indonesia
are also rapidly developing markets for e-commerce and online services, with
emerging local rms. Advanced services-based economies such as Australia
and New Zealand are highly digitalized, although ICT-led manufacturing is
less prevalent. Additionally, Asia has city states that are hubs for ICT sec-
tor businesses and ntech, such as Singapore. In contrast, developing Asian
economies have lower rates of internet connectivity and are less likely to have
large, locally headquartered digitalized rms.
Introduction
1
e ability of highly digitalized rms to make cross-border sales without a
physical presence challenges traditional corporate income tax (CIT) rules.
ese rules give taxing rights over corporate prots to countries where rms
are headquartered and where they have a permanent establishment (for exam-
ple, factory or storefront). For highly digitalized businesses trading online
across borders, this can mean that the countries where sales are made (market
countries), or where online users are located have no taxing rights over the
rms income. ere are also challenges for countries with taxing rights under
existing rules because the assets of highly digitalized rms can be more con-
centrated in intangibles (for example, intellectual property) compared with
other businesses. Intangible assets can be more easily transferred to related
members of a corporate group in lower tax jurisdictions, allowing prot to be
shifted away from a country with higher tax rates.
Cross-border online sales of goods and services also place pressure on value
added tax (VAT) collection. ere is broad agreement across countries that
VAT should be paid where the nal consumer resides (see for example, the
OECD’s VAT/GST guidelines 2017). is is increasingly dicult to imple-
ment in a digitalized economy as VAT collections largely rely on locally regis-
tered rms remitting the tax. Enforcing VAT collection on, for example, the
purchase of online streaming services from a non-resident supplier is much
more challenging.
Multilateral discussions to resolve the challenges of taxing income in an
increasingly digitalized economy are conducted under the auspices of the
G20/OECD Inclusive Framework (IF). e IF consists of 139 members,
including the major Asian economies and many developing countries. Under
the so-called Pillar 1, countries are discussing a proposal to provide a new
taxing right to market jurisdictions, thus addressing the concern around tax-
ing rights in a digitalized economy.
1
While awaiting agreement in the IF, some countries have begun imple-
menting digital services taxes (DSTs), which typically tax the receipts of
non-resident rms from sales made to their residents. DSTs can take the form
of simple withholding taxes on payments (for example, for online advertis-
ing), similar to existing taxes on cross-border technical services. Alternatively,
they can be in the form of user-based turnover taxes that aim to tax the value
created by the ultimate users of digital services in a particular country.
is paper illustrates how digitalization has aected Asian economies and
their CIT and VAT systems, analyzing the impact of proposed reforms. It
builds on the IMF’s policy and analytical work in international taxation and
contributes to the policy debate by: (1) giving an overview of trends in digi-
1
A second pillar in these discussions deals with the introduction of an eective global minimum tax.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
2
talization in Asia and how this diers from other regions (Chapter1);
(2) discussing the implications of multilateral and unilateral tax policy
reforms aimed at taxing the income of companies in an increasingly digi-
talized economy (Chapter2); and (3) exploring how best to address VAT
challenges in the face of expanding online sales (Chapter3). It is important
to note that the nexus of digitalization and tax go beyond what is discussed
in the paper, including issues of property rights over private information and
the use of technology in tax design and revenue administration.
Introduction
3
is chapter describes the landscape of digitalization in Asia. Digitalization is
having a profound impact on Asias economy, underpinned by widespread inter-
net access. Digitalization extends well beyond the large ICT sector, with high
levels of e-commerce and automated digital services. Asia stands out in its large,
highly digitalized and locally headquartered tech giants, operating alongside US
MNEs. e rapid growth of Asias homegrown tech giants and the presence of
US MNEs highlights the importance of appropriate tax policies for these highly
digitalized businesses.
Digitalized economic activity in Asia encompasses both the ICT sector and
other types of digitalized businesses.
For the purposes of this paper, the ICT sector is dened to include manufac-
turing of computers, electronic and optical products, publishing and broad-
casting, telecommunications and computer programming, and information
services.
1
Beyond the ICT sector, nearly all businesses in the formal economy
approach a “digital asymptote” (Figure1), using digital technology to varying
degrees, ranging from the use of digital systems to facilitate online order-
ing of goods to the provision of purely digital services (for example, online
gaming, search, and social media). is paper gives particular attention to
large, highly digitalized businesses, referred to as “tech giants.” ese tech
giants rely heavily on digital technology to carry on business, despite their
dierent business models, ranging from ICT manufacturers and retailers that
have built large e-commerce platforms, to online marketplaces that facilitate
e-commerce between third parties.
1
e ICT sector is measured using industry-level national accounts data and the relevant International
Standard Industrial Classication codes (G20 2018, United Nations 2008) for computer programming and
information services (Div. 62 63); telecommunications (Div. 61); publishing and broadcasting (Div. 58 60);
and manufacturing of computer, electronic, and optical products (Div. 26).
Digitalization in Asia
CCHAPTERHAPTER
1
5
Asia’s ICT Sector
e ICT sector in Asia is among the world’s
largest. e sector accounts for more than
12, 7, and 6percent of total value added
in Korea, India, and Japan, respectively
(Figure2, panel 1), comparable in size to
most other OECD countries (IMF 2018a,
2018b).
2
Chinas ICT sector is estimated
to be around 5.6percent of GDP (Herrero
and Xu 2018). e employment share of the
ICT sector in Chinas urban areas is already
larger than in many OECD countries (Fig-
ure2, panel 2).
Asias ICT sector has grown rapidly, driven
by manufacturing, which has exhibited high
labor productivity. e strong growth of
the ICT sectors real value added in Korea
and Japan is comparable to that of the United States and Europe (Figure2,
panel 3). Chinas ICT sector is also estimated to have grown rapidly by about
10percent per year between 2013 and 2016 (Herrero and Xu 2018). Unlike
the United States and Europe, the ICT manufacturing sector in Korea has
recorded stronger growth than in ICT services and exhibited high labor
productivity (Figure2, panel 4), potentially reecting the regions compara-
tive advantage in manufacturing relative to services. MNEs engaging in ICT
manufacturing may also provide digital services and engage in e-commerce
(for example, Apple, Samsung).
Digitalization Beyond the ICT Sector
Asias unrivalled level of internet connectivity, which has underpinned the
economys digitalization beyond the ICT sector, creates enormous scope for
future growth. Reecting their population size, China, India, and Indonesia
taken together have more than 2billion active mobile broadband connec-
tions, compared with approximately 500million in the United States (Fig-
ure3). Japan has more than 200million connections, while Bangladesh, the
Philippines, ailand, and Vietnam also each have 50–100million mobile
connections. e number of xed broadband connections is more than
three times as large in China as in the United States. Considerable potential
2
Although fully comparable data are not available, McKinsey Global Institute (2019) estimate that Indias
ICT sector accounted for around 7percent of GDP in 2017–18, mainly reecting IT and digital communi-
cations services.
Source: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development.
Note: ICT = information and communications technology.
Figure 1. A Digitalized Economy
E-commerce
(online sales, etc.)
Digital services;
online platforms
ICT sector
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
6
appears possible for further growth, particularly in China, Indonesia, and
South Asia, where the number of internet users as a share of the population
remains well below the level in the United States, as well as in other major
emerging market economies.
D26: Computer, electronic and optical products manufacturing
Total ICT sector
D58T60: Publishing, audiovisual and broadcasting activities
D61: Telecommunications
D62T63: IT and other information services
Non-ICT sector
Other ICT sector (incl. manufacturing)
IT and other information services
Non-ICT sector
Other ICT sector (incl. manufacturing)
IT and other information services
Computer, elect. and optical manufacturing
ICT sector
Publishing, audiovisual and broadcasting activities
Telecommunications
IT and other information services
Sources: OECD Structural Analysis Database (STAN, 2020 ed.); McKinsey Global Institute^; and Herrero and Xu (2018).^^
Note: In panel 1, ^2017–18 estimate, incl. IT & digital comms. services; electronics manufacturing. Breakdown unavailable.
^^2016 estimate, incl. electronic manufacturing, IT & telecommunications services. Breakdown unavailable.
^^^Europe incl. FRA, DEU, ITA and UK.
In panel 2, ^^estimate for 2010 in urban areas only. Breakdown unavailable.
**Data for computer, elect. and optical manufacturing only.
***Europe incl. FRA, DEU, ITA and UK.
In panel 3, *data for KOR are for 2005–2015 and sourced from the 2018 update of the STAN database.
**Data on the ICT sector in JPN include only ICT manufacturing.
***Advanced Europe incl. FRA, DEU, ITA and UK.
In panel 4, *data for KOR are for 2005–2015 and sourced from the 2018 update of the STAN database.
**Data on the ICT sector in JPN are missing except for ICT manufacturing.
***Advanced Europe incl. FRA, DEU, ITA and UK.
Figure 2. Asia’s ICT Sector
14
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
250
200
150
100
50
0
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1. Value Added of ICT Sector
(Percent of total, 2017, or latest year available)
2. Employment in ICT Sector
(Percent of total, 2017, or latest available)
3. Real Value Added Growth of ICT Sector, 2005–2017
(In percent change)
4. Labor Productivity Growth of ICT Sector, 2005–2017
(In percent change)
160
140
120
100
60
80
40
20
0
KOR IND^ JPN CHN^^ AUS &
NZL average
USA Europe
average^^^
MEX KOR CHN^^ AUS & NZL
average
JPN** USA Europe
average***
KOR* JPN** USA Advanced
Europe***
MEX KOR* JPN** USA Advanced
Europe***
MEX
Digitalization in Asia
7
Online sales are more common in some Asian economies than in other
regions, including e-commerce exports. Business-to-consumer (B2C)
e-commerce in China and Korea is larger than in the United States, while
in Japan it is of similar size to other G7 economies (Figure4, panel 1).
Cross-border e-commerce is also substantial, with B2C e-commerce exports
in China and Japan exceeding those in some G7 economies (Figure4, panel
2). ese trends have continued during the pandemic. For instance, in 2020
alone, e-commerce sales grew by 30–50percent in Indonesia and Singapore,
some of the fastest growth rates even in comparison to other advanced econo-
mies (Figure4, panels 3 and 4).
Large and highly digitalized businesses—tech giants—thrive beyond the
ICT sector. Firms providing e-commerce and ntech services are closest to
the digital asymptote in ICT, nance, other professional services, wholesale,
and retail trade (Sedik 2018). Public companies from China (Alibaba, JD,
Meituan), Japan (Rakuten), and Singapore (Sea Limited) are among the
largest in Asias e-commerce space (Figure5) (Hvistendahl 2019, Ecommer-
ceDB 2019). Private companies including Koreas Coupang and Indonesias
Go-Jek are also important players. ese local rms generate levels of reve-
nue in Asia similar to large US rms, including Amazon, Walmart, and their
local subsidiaries.
Asia
Non-Asia
Asia
Non-Asia
Source: International Telecommunications Union.
Figure 3. Internet Access in Asia
1600
1400
1200
0
1000
800
600
400
200
100
90
80
50
60
40
30
0
70
20
10
1. Active Mobile Broadband Connections
(2019, in millions)
2. Internet Users
(2019, in percent of population)
CHN IND IDN Other
Asia
Total
Europe
Total
North
America
Total
ZAF BRA CHN IDN IND BGD USA RUS TUR BRA MEX
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
8
How Is Digitalization in Asia Different?
Asia stands out from other regions in having home-grown tech giants that
rival US MNEs in size. China has several of the largest e-commerce com-
panies in the world, both measured in terms of market share or total sales.
For instance, Chinas Alibaba Group and JD.com have about 38percent of
global e-commerce market share by merchandise volume (Figure6), although
the total value of Alibabas transactions is smaller than that of Amazon
(Box1). Alibaba operates Chinas most-visited online marketplaces, Taobao
(consumer to consumer [C2C]) and TMall (business to consumer [B2C]),
while JD.coms marketplace has a large in-house delivery network. Japans
Rakuten and Singapore’s Sea Group (trading as subsidiary Shopee) are other
major players in e-commerce. Asia is also home to some of the worlds largest
providers of digital services other than e-commerce, such as Chinas Tencent
Non-Asia
Asia
Non-Asia
Asia
Non-Asia
Asia
Singapore
Indonesia
Sources: Statista; United Nations Conference on Trade and Development; and IMF staff calculations.
Figure 4. E-Commerce in Asia
10
9
8
7
6
4
3
5
2
1
0
70
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
8
7
6
5
4
3
2
1
0
1. E-Commerce Sales
(B2C, percent of GDP, 2017)
2. Cross-Border E-Commerce Sales
(B2C, percent of merchandise exports, 2017)
3. E-Commerce Sales
(Annual percentage change, 2017–20)
4. E-Commerce Sales
(Annual percentage change, 2020)
605030 40201002018 2019 2020
CHN UK KOR USA CAN FRA JPN DEU ITA IND
Germany
UK
Japan
USA
New Zealand
Russia
South Korea
Australia
Brazil
Italy
Spain
South Africa
China
Mexico
Singapore
Vietnam
Malaysia
India
Cambodia
Philippines
Thailand
Turkey
Indonesia
UK USA CHN JPN FRA CAN DEU ITA KOR NLD
Digitalization in Asia
9
(operating the WeChat communications, social media, and payment plat-
form) and Baidu (Chinas largest internet search engine) (Figure7).
Unlike US MNEs, available evidence suggests that Asias homegrown tech
giants operate mainly within their domestic markets. While large US tech
giants generate the majority of their revenue outside the United States (Fig-
ure8, panel 1), major e-commerce providers such as Japans Rakuten derive
the bulk of their income from the Japanese market (Figure8, panel 2). is
also appears to be the case for Chinas e-commerce giants. Expansion beyond
domestic markets is occurring, sometimes through joint ventures and acqui-
sitions of foreign rms. High prole examples include Alibabas purchase of
Singapore’s Lazard Group e-commerce rm, recent acquisitions by Singa-
pores Sea Group, facilitating expansion into ntech, as well as acquisitions in
recent years by Indonesias Gojek to expand its range of online products.
Asias homegrown tech giants appear to rely on intangible assets as much as
MNEs in the United States, and their protability is comparable. Firms that
derive value from intangible assets, such as intellectual property, can be more
dicult to tax since it is easier to shift these assets across borders to lower
tax jurisdictions. Intangible assets are also dicult to value for the purposes
of transfer pricing, whereby transactions within corporate groups, includ-
ing between subsidiaries and parent companies, are valued for tax purposes.
Using revenue per employee as a proxy for the degree of intangibility, it
appears that some of the Asian tech giants eclipse large US MNEs such as
Asian HQ
Non-Asian HQ
Source: Pitchbook Data Inc. Data have not been reviewed by PitchBook analysts.
*Japan only.
**Republic of Korea only.
90
50
60
80
70
0
20
10
40
30
JD
Alibaba
Amazon*
Meituan
VIPshop
Rakuten
Pinduoduo
Sea Limited
ebay**
Figure 5. Asian Sales of E-Commerce Companies (Public)
(Revenue, FY 2019, US$ billions)
Asian HQ
Non-Asian HQ
Sources: Statista; and Activate.
Figure 6. Global Market Share: E-Commerce
Companies (Public)
(Percent of total, by gross merchandise volume, 2019)
Alibaba
Amazon
JD
Pinduoduo
ebay
Other
Suning.com, Rakuten, Apple,
Walmart, Vip.com, and Sea Limited
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
10
Asian HQ
Non-Asian HQ
Asian HQ
Non-Asian HQ
Source: Pitchbook Data Inc. Data have not been reviewed by PitchBook analysts.
Figure 7. Turnover of Asia’s Tech Giants
300
250
200
0
150
100
50
180
160
140
80
100
60
40
0
120
20
1. Total Sales: E-Commerce Companies (Public)
(FY19, US$ billions)
2. Total Sales: Internet Companies (Public)
(FY19, US$ billions)
Amazon
JD
Alibaba
Meituan
VIPshop
Rakuten
ebay
Pinduoduo
Sea
Limited
Google Facebook Tencent Netflix Baidu Uber
Sales outside USADomestic sales in USA Sales in other countriesDomestic sales in country of HQ
Non-Asian HQ
Asian HQ
Non-Asian HQ
Asian HQ
Sources: Statista; and Pitchbook Data Inc. Data have not been reviewed by PitchBook analysts.
Note: MNEs = multinational enterprises.
In panel 1, *Sales in both USA and Canada.
In panel 2, *E-commerce sales only, 2019.
Figure 8. Sales, Productivity, and Profits of Asia’s Tech Giants
100
80
60
40
20
0
1.6
1.4
1.2
1.0
0.8
0.6
0.4
0.2
0.0
100
80
60
40
20
0
1. Domestic vs Foreign Sales: US MNE’s (Public)
(Percent of total, FY19)
2. Domestic vs Foreign Sales: Asian Co’s (Public)
(Percent of total, FY19)
3. Labor Productivity of E-Commerce Co’s (Public)
(Revenue per employee, US$ millions, FY19)
4. Return on Equity: Internet & EComm. Companies (Public)
(Percent, average over FY17–FY19)
35
30
20
25
15
10
5
0
Pinduoduo ebay VIPshop Rakuten Alibaba JD Amazon
eBay Facebook Netflix* Uber Groupon Amazon
JD
VIPshop
Pinduoduo
Baidu
Meituan
Suning
Tencent
Alibaba*
Rakuten
Tencent
Facebook
Amazon
VIPshop
ebay
Alibaba
Google
Rakuten
Suning
Baidu
Digitalization in Asia
11
Amazon on this metric (Figure8) and are
broadly as protable, when judged by return
on equity in recent years.
Some of Asias largest home-grown tech
giants also appear to have income tax rates
comparable to those of US MNEs. Figure9
shows tax rates computed as income tax
expensed in a nancial year, as a percent of
pretax income, for a selection of large Asian
and US tech giants. Although this may not
capture tax paid precisely, it indicates that
tax outcomes for Asias tech giants can be
similar to large US digitalized companies.
e rapid growth of Asias homegrown tech
giants and the presence of US MNEs high-
lights the importance of appropriate tax pol-
icies for these highly digitalized businesses.
Asian e-commerce and internet giants Alib-
aba, JD, and Baidu have emerged as major players only in the last 10 years,
rivalling the turnover of Amazon, Google, and Facebook (Figure10, panel
1). Asian giants have also recorded solid growth in recent years (Figure10,
panel 2), comparable to large US MNEs. With continued expansion, revenue
collection from both local and foreign tech giants will become increasingly
important and appropriate tax policies will need to be in place to ensure that
revenue is distributed across countries in a manner that is perceived to be fair.
Asian HQ
Non-Asian HQ
Source: Pitchbook Data Inc. Data have not been reviewed by PitchBook analysts.
25
5
10
20
15
0
Suning
VIPshop
Rakuten
Facebook
Alibaba
Tencent
Amazon
Google
Pinduoduo
ebay
Figure 9. Income Tax Expensed
(Percent of pretax income, average during FY18–FY19)
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
12
Amazon
Alibaba
Google
Tencent
Facebook
Baidu
Asian HQ
Non-Asian HQ
Source: Pitchbook Data Inc. Data have not been reviewed by PitchBook analysts.
Figure 10. Growth of Asia’s Tech Giants
300
250
200
0
150
100
50
45
40
35
30
15
20
10
5
–5
0
25
1. Sales of Internet Companies (Public)
(FY10, FY15 and FY19, US$ billions)
2. Profit Growth: Internet Companies (Public)
(Percent, average during FY15–FY19)
FY19 FY15 FY10
JD
Facebook
Amazon
Alibaba
VIPshop
Suning
Google
Tencent
Rakuten
ebay
Baidu
Digitalization in Asia
13
Alibaba is a Chinese tech giant with websites that serve as platforms for other sellers,
while Amazon has become an integrated retailer. Beginning in the late 1990s, Amazon
and Alibaba both developed comprehensive e-commerce websites (Laubscher 2018, Xu
2016). Alibabas websites have traditionally been a platform for third party sellers, with-
out marketing Alibabas own products or providing delivery services (Box Table1.1).
Amazon invested in an extensive delivery network for its goods and services, as well
as selling its own products via its website. e two tech giants have converged more
recently in some business decisions, as Alibaba jointly founded Cainiao Network in
2013, as a platform for businesses oering delivery services. Both Amazon and Alibaba
have also recently acquired traditional retail outlets, in Whole Foods (Amazon) and
Hema Fresh (Alibaba).
Amazon has signicantly higher turnover and is more protable. Although Alibaba
facilitates a higher volume of merchandise trade, Amazon has signicantly higher rev-
enue and larger prots. is may reect Amazons diversication, as the share of Ama-
zons revenue contributed by online e-commerce has declined from 65percent to about
50percent between 2016 and 2019, as its cloud computing services (AWS) and other
businesses have grown rapidly. E-commerce continues to account for more than 80per-
cent of Alibabas revenue (PitchBook Data, Inc).
Alibaba is an intangible business with signicant potential to expand internationally
similar to Amazon. Alibaba has less than a quarter of Amazons employees, given the
absence of an integrated retail and delivery network. is reects a less tangible business
model with signicant scope to increase use of its online platforms by foreign buyers
Box Table 1.1. Comparison between an American and Asian Tech Giant
Amazon Alibaba
Founded 1995 1999
Subsidiaries Amazon.com (B2C).
AWS for cloud computing.
Wholefoods traditional retail.
TMall (B2C) and Taobao (C2C).
Cainiao Network: delivery co platform.
Hema Fresh traditional retail
Foreign operations Localized versions of Amazon.com
operate in 20 countries.
Alibaba.com (B2B)
Aliexpress (B2C)
Lazard for e-commerce in SE Asia.
Revenue FY19 US$ 280.5 billion US$ 56.1 billion
Foreign Revenue FY19 31% 10.1%
Gross Profit FY19 US$ 74.7 billion US$ 25.3 billion
ROE
(FY17-19 avge)
21.2% 18.1%
Profit growth (FY15-19 avge) 37.2 % 32.1 %
Employees (2019) 798,000 116,519
Income tax expense (% pretax income,
FY18-19 avge)
17.7% 13.8%
Source: PitchBook Data Inc. Data have not been reviewed by PitchBook analysts.
Box 1. Amazon and Alibaba—Comparison between an American and Asian Tech Giant
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
14
and sellers. Progress has been limited so far, with most revenue generated by its Chinese
websites, unlike Amazons websites in multiple countries.
Alibabas tax obligations appear to be similar to those of Amazon in recent years. Aliba-
bas income tax expense (percent of pretax income) was 17.7percent on average during
FY2018 and FY2019, compared to 13.8percent for Amazon. Although an imperfect
measure of income tax paid, these gures do not suggest that either company enjoys a
signicant tax advantage over the other.
Box 1. Amazon and Alibaba (continued)
15
Digitalization in Asia
is chapter focuses on the international tax challenges stemming from a highly
digitalized economy, rather than domestic tax challenges related to prot shifting.
Under the proposed multilateral solution by the OECD Inclusive Framework,
investment hubs, including those in Asia, would lose revenue, while those with
a large user base or high-income consumers will likely gain. Other multilateral
policy alternatives go farther, calling for a complete replacement of the existing
CIT regime. While highly digitalized businesses are not explicitly targeted by the
OECD proposals, they remain some of the most aected. In the interim, some
countries in the region have introduced a DST on the receipts of non-resident
rms from the sale of services to residents. ese taxes raise low levels of revenue,
suggesting that the choice to introduce a DST needs to be weighed against other
reform priorities.
Challenges of Taxing Digitalized Businesses in Asia
e existing approach to taxing highly digitalized businesses operating inter-
nationally has been perceived as unfair by governments and civil society
organizations. e view held by many governments is that their citizenry is
remotely contributing to the rents generated by digital service providers from
other countries. First, increasingly sophisticated technology has facilitated
a large surge in both business to business (B2B) and business to consumer
(B2C) remote cross-jurisdictional sales/exports, challenging the concept of a
permanent establishment (PE) which requires a physical presence to generate
taxing rights for income taxes. Second, many governments claim that infor-
mation collected by companies on the personal preferences and habits of the
customer or “user” as they consume digital services—which is then processed
and monetized through personalized advertising and product development—
is contributing signicantly to the prots of these companies, without ade-
quate compensation to the users. Highly digitalized businesses may also
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses
in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
CCHAPTERHAPTER
2
17
have relatively more intangible assets, which are harder to value and easier
to relocate (Beer and Loeprick 2015), enabling prot shifting under existing
transfer pricing rules.
e impact of international tax policy reforms in Asia could dier from other
regions, given the unique landscape of digitalized businesses. Reducing the
importance of physical presence in determining a companys income tax lia-
bility could increase the ability of Asian countries to tax foreign MNEs oper-
ating in Asia with few tangible assets. However, the home countries of Asias
tech giants could also lose revenue if these rms have to pay more tax in
other countries where they are expanding. e consequences for revenue col-
lection could be non-trivial, given that home-grown tech giants are growing
rapidly and face similar implicit tax rates to US MNEs. Some Asian countries
are also turning to DSTs—withholding taxes or user-based turnover taxes on
digital activities—as a unilateral means of taxing tech giants and other highly
digitalized businesses. is paper rst discusses multilateral tax reform pro-
posals and implications for the region before turning to digital services taxes
in Asia, potential trade-os, and economic implications.
Multilateral Reform
e OECD-led IF has proposed multilateral reform as a solution for taxing
an increasingly digitalized economy. e rst pillar of the policy proposal
seeks to adapt the international corporate tax system to new digitized busi-
ness models, by reallocating part of residual prot to market (or “destina-
tion”) countries. It would establish new taxing rights without requiring a
physical presence (new “nexus”). is reects a fundamental shift from exist-
ing norms by going beyond the arms length principle and moving toward
formulary methods when reallocating prots to the new nexus, thereby
addressing some of the challenges in taxing digitalized businesses. Notably,
this new taxing right would be overlaid on top of the existing system of inter-
national taxation.
1
e following are key elements of Pillar 1:
A new taxing right for market jurisdictions over a share of residual profit
calculated at a consolidated MNE group (or segment) level (“Amount
1
Some countries consider the DSTs discussed in the following section, merely as an interim solution
until international agreement is achieved. Indeed, countries such as Belgium, Czech Republic and Hungary
have delayed the implementation of their DSTs, anticipating agreement on a multilateral solution can be
reached by mid-2021.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
18
A”). Specifically, a portion (perhaps 20percent)
2
of the “residual profit”—
earnings in excess of “routine profits”—of MNEs with group revenues
above EUR 750million (USD 850million), that are engaged in automated
digital services or consumer-facing business would be allocated to market
(or “destination”) countries. Routine profit equates broadly to profits that
would be earned by an entity undertaking that activity on an outsourced
basis. There are different ways of calculating routine profits, but for this
purpose it is likely to be defined as some percentage (perhaps 10percent)
of revenue from unrelated party sales; the residual is any profit above this.
3
A (separate) fixed return for certain baseline marketing and distribution activi-
ties taking place physically in a market jurisdiction, in line with the existing
arms length principle (”Amount B”). This does not create a new taxing
right, rather it secures a taxing right that already exists. It presents a simpli-
fication of existing rules and may help effective implementation of taxing
rights, wherein rules to ensure a minimum return to activities are currently
not well enforced, such as in developing Asian countries.
Processes to improve tax certainty aimed at dispute prevention and resolution.
e second pillar introduces minimum taxation of inbound and outbound
investment. Pillar 2 applies more broadly and does not have a special treat-
ment for digital businesses and is not covered in this paper. However, some
countries (including the US)
4
see Pillar 1 and Pillar 2 as a package, with
acceptance of Pillar 1 predicated on acceptance of Pillar 2. Notably, by plac-
ing a oor on the CIT rate, Pillar 2 is expected to raise more revenue than
Pillar 1. Broader revenue implications of Pillar 1 for Asia are discussed below
and extend beyond the digital economy.
Implications of Amount A for Asia
MNEs headquartered in the Asia-Pacic region generate a signicant share
of the global residual prot covered by “Amount A.Table1 reports on the
share of residual prots by country of headquarter for MNE groups with
annual revenue larger than EUR 750million (USD 850million). e size
and distribution of residual prots are reported separately for all industries,
ICT industries, and online retailers. Although these classications do not
directly map to the denition of consumer-facing businesses and automated
2
e OECD-IF argues that not all the residual is generated by the market jurisdiction (for example, some
reects risk-taking by the MNE), hence only a portion of the residual prot is reallocated.
3
For economists, routine returns may resemble a normal return on investment and “residual” prots, resem-
ble rents (earnings in excess of the minimum required by the investor).
4
For instance, the Made in America Tax Plan would bring the international minimum tax provisions (GILTI
and BEAT) closer in line with the OECD-IF’s Pillar 2 proposal. e plan envisages a higher minimum tax rate
of 21percent compared to the OECD-IF.
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
19
digital services, they are nonetheless indicative.
5
Assuming that routine prots
are 10percent of revenue (that is, a 10percent protability threshold), global
residual prot across all industries is USD 1.5trillion. MNEs headquartered
in the US account for the bulk of residual prots (33percent), but a sizeable
share (32percent) are earned by MNEs headquartered in Asia-Pacic, with
China, Hong Kong SAR, Korea, and Japan playing a prominent role. Nar-
rowing the scope to the ICT industry shrinks the size of residual prots but
maintains the importance of MNEs headquartered in Asia-Pacic.
e ICT sector is relatively protable compared with other industry sectors,
disproportionately contributing to residual prot. e ICT sector is one
of the most protable industries as measured by the return to total assets,
and its residual prot as a share of total prot also ranks high compared to
other sectors (Table2). Although the sector falls within the narrow scope of
Amount A,” even without this ringfencing, the high level of protability
means that rms in the sector are more likely to be included in the tax base.
e sector accounts for about 16percent of the global residual prots, which
is similar to the level of the nancial and real estate sector, but with a con-
5
e denition of consumer-facing business is not yet nalized.
Table 1. Residual Profit by Headquarter Jurisdiction, 2017
All industries (2017) ICT industry (2017)
Country
Share of
Global RP
(%)
Mean
RP/EBT
(%) Country
Share of
Global RP
(%)
Mean
RP/EBT
(%)
United States 33.1 18.0 United States 53.3 24.4
China 12.1 13.1 Hong Kong SAR 7.6 29.6
United Kingdom 8.0 11.0 China 6.7 23.2
Hong Kong SAR 5.9 32.1 Japan 6.6 11.6
South Korea 4.0 8.7 India 3.2 43.2
Japan 3.9 5.1 Germany 2.3 20.9
France 3.5 9.5 Canada 2.0 35.3
Germany 2.9 7.5 Netherlands 1.4 9.6
Canada 2.1 17.7 Australia 1.2 26.9
Russia 2.0 25.1 Spain 1.2 16.1
Other Asia Pacific 5.9 14.5 Other Asia-Pacific 5.7 18.8
Rest of the World 16.7 12.9 Rest of the World 8.8 12.9
Total 1,457 USD billions Total 236 USD billions
Online Retailers (2017)
Country
Share of
Global RP
(%)
Mean
RP/EBT
(%)
United States 65.1 10.1
Japan 26.8 2.9
China 8.1 7.4
Total 1.45 USD billions
Sources: S&P Capital IQ and IMF staff estimates.
Note: EBT = earnings before tax; RP = residual profit.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
20
siderably smaller number of companies. e average return on assets in the
sector is twice as large as in the nancial sector. e median rate of return
ratio indicates divergence of protability within the ICT group.
Under the current system of international taxation, residual prots across
all industries are reported mainly in large economies and investment hubs.
Figure11 shows the location of residual prot for MNEs headquartered in
25 economies (including Australia, China, India, Indonesia, Japan, Singa-
pore, and the United States) for all sectors, not just highly digitalized rms.
6
Together, these MNEs account for 71percent of total global residual prot.
With a protability threshold based on revenue (that is, the current de-
nition of residual prot under Amount A), about 44percent of the resid-
ual prot from these MNEs are declared in China and the United States,
followed by the Netherlands, Canada, and Puerto Rico. Other Asia-Pacic
economies with a sizeable share of residual prot include Australia, Hong
Kong SAR, and Singapore. Regionally, Europe has the largest share of resid-
ual prot (35percent) followed by Asia Pacic (31percent) and the Amer-
icas (29percent).
7
e presence of investment hubs potentially reects the
extent of prot shifting that occurs under the current regime. at said, these
results should be interpreted with caution, as the prot measure available can
include income from equity investment in aliates (for example, dividends
from subsidiaries) that are not subject to tax in the home country under cur-
rent rules, and not subject to redistribution under Pillar 1.
6
However, as noted above using consolidated data, digital rms account for a sizeable share of residual prots,
with the ICT sector alone responsible for 16percent of total residual prots. Hence the analysis presented here
should be viewed as illustrative. Indeed, digital rms are deemed to have greater opportunities for prot shift-
ing, given the importance of intangibles in their production process
7
Although the share of residual prot is evenly shared across the three continents, aliates located in Asia
tend to be more protable than their counterparts in other regions, earning a return on tangible assets of
17percent. e median aliate in Europe earns a 15percent return, and those in the Americas and Mid-
dle East earn a return of 8.5percent. e lowest returns are observed in Africa, with a return on assets of
only 4percent.
Table 2. Residual Profit and Other Descriptive Statistics by Sector, 2017
Industry Sector
Number of
Companies
mean
EBT/Assets (%)
median
EBT/Assets (%)
mean
RP/EBT (%)
Share of Global
RP (%)
Agriculture, Forestry and Fishing 25 8.3 8.3 12.6 0.2
Construction 298 5.6 4.7 5.2 1.0
Finance, Insurance and Real Estate 899 4.6 3.1 17.9 16.3
Manufacturing 2694 8.3 6.7 12.4 42.8
Retail Trade 608 8.1 6.2 3.7 2.1
Services 719 8.0 6.2 15.0 14.0
Transportation, Communications and Utilities 1160 5.9 4.5 20.2 20.3
Wholesale Trade 697 6.2 4.5 2.8 2.6
ICT 501 8.3 6.3 19.4 16.2
Sources: S&P Capital; and IMF staff estimates.
*ICT has overlaps with other sectors, so the sum of the share of Global RP is not 100 percent.
Note: EBT = earnings before tax; RP = residual profit.
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
21
e location of residual prots is sensitive to the precise method of calcula-
tion. Using a protability threshold based on returns to tangible assets (in
this case 10percent of their value), the United States emerges as the top loca-
tion for residual prots while China accounts for only 4percent of residual
prot. is reects the importance of tangible assets in the creation of prot
for China (for example, manufacturing) compared to the United States.
e global revenue eect of Amount A is small, increasing CIT revenue by
about 0.5percent (OECD 2020a), but implications for individual jurisdic-
tions can be signicant. e revenue increase is driven by the reallocation
from jurisdictions with low taxes toward jurisdictions with higher taxes.
However, only a proportion of the residual prot will be reallocated. Using
a protability threshold of 10percent of unrelated party sales and assuming
only 20percent is available for reallocation, then the pool of residual prots
to be reallocated is estimated to be relatively small at USD 98billion, limit-
ing the size of the revenue increase (OECD 2020). For individual jurisdic-
tions, the impact on tax revenues depends on their current share of residual
prot relative to their share of sales. e OECD estimates that low-income
countries would increase their CIT revenue by approximately 1percent
(or 0.02percent of GDP) and middle-income countries by 0.5percent
(0.02percent of GDP).
8
e revenue impact for high-income countries show
8
Results are presented in OECD (2020a) as the percentage change in CIT revenue. IMF sta converted this
change in CIT revenue into percentage points of GDP for ease of comparison with the other results pre-
sented in this paper.
Sales definition
Asset definition
Source: OECD country by country reports for 2016; and IMF staff estimates.
Figure 11. Top 20 Locations of Residual Profit
(Percent of total)
15
0
5
10
20
25
30
35
China
United States
Netherlands
Canada
Puerto Rico
Bermuda
Australia
Hong Kong
SAR
Singapore
Ireland
Sweden
British Virgin
Islands
Cayman
Islands
Bahamas,
The
India
Norway
United
Kingdom
Indonesia
Peru
Vietnam
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
22
greater variability, they could lose or gain a small amount of revenue. Invest-
ment hubs unequivocally lose revenue, by as much as 3.9percent of current
CIT revenue (0.2percent of GDP).
Under an expanded scope, which includes rms in all industries, investment
hubs and developing economies in the Asia Pacic region could lose revenue
(Figure12). Discussions surrounding the scope of Amount A are ongoing,
with a possibility that the scope would be based on a size threshold, rather
than type of business activity.
9
In this case, the estimates presented here could
be closer to the expected impact. e range reects assumptions regarding
9
e top 100 largest MNE groups by revenue have revenue greater than USD 67billion, with an average rev-
enue of USD 127billion, and an average residual of USD 1.7billion. e headquarters of these MNE groups
are dispersed equally across Asia, Europe, and the Americas. e average size, in terms of revenue, in each
region is similar, but the average MNE group headquartered in the Americas have more than twice the residual
prot (USD 3.4billion) of the average Asian MNE (USD 1.6billion). e average residual prot of European
is the lowest at USD 305million.
Sources: OECD Country by Country Reports for 2016; and IMF staff estimates.
Note: The range reflects assumptions regarding the profitability threshold (10 percent or 20 percent of unrelated party sales) and share of residual profit to be
reallocated (10 percent or 20 percent). Increasing (decreasing) the share of residual profit to be reallocated results in a proportional increase (decrease). Increasing
the threshold reduces the size of the potential pool of profits to be reallocated, but for some countries this results in an increase in the revenue gain. This is because
it is assumed that each jurisdiction’s ‘contribution’ to the pool to be reallocated is in proportion to the jurisdiction’s current share of residual profit. So, with a higher
profitability threshold, the residual profit becomes more concentrated in select countries.
Figure 12. Potential Revenue Effects of Pillar 1, Amount A
(Percent of GDP)
0.00 0.100.05–0.20 –0.05–0.10–0.15
Australia
Bangladesh
Bhutan
Brunei Darussalam
Cambodia
China
Fiji
Hong Kong SAR
India
Indonesia
Japan
Korea
Lao P.D.R.
Macao SAR
Malaysia
Maldives
Mongolia
Myanmar
Nepal
New Zealand
Papua New Guinea
Philippines
Samoa
Singapore
Solomon Islands
Sri Lanka
Thailand
Timor-Leste
Vietnam
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
23
the protability threshold (10percent or 20percent of unrelated party sales)
and share of residual prot to be reallocated (10percent or 20percent). For
instance, with a 10percent protability threshold and with 20percent of
residual prots reallocated, Vietnam could lose about 0.11percent of GDP
in revenue, driven by the prot reallocation of Japanese MNEs. Whereas
with a higher protability threshold, revenue eects are minimal. Similarly,
emerging economies such as India, Indonesia, and Malaysia could lose about
0.01percent of GDP in revenue or have a modest revenue gain. In contrast,
high-income countries such as Australia, Japan, and Korea, as well as large
markets such as China, gain revenue under the range of assumptions consid-
ered here. Singapore and Hong Kong SAR could lose about 0.15percent of
GDP in revenue. It is unsurprising that revenue losses are projected in these
investment hubs since they currently account for a disproportionate share of
residual prot compared to their market share.
10
Distributional eects dier
with the current proposal where the relative size of the in-scope sectors devi-
ates from the relative size of all MNEs. Annex1 provides an overview of the
methodology used to develop these estimates.
Digital Services Taxes
e use of unilateral measures to tax digital services is linked to wider global
discussions on expanding market (or “source”) country taxing rights. In a
context wherein direct taxation of prots is dicult, digital services taxes––
analogous to royalties imposed on the extraction of resource-rich countries––
allow countries to share in the rents of highly digitalized businesses. Data,
often proclaimed as the oil of the 21st century, have been a key driver for
new economic activity in recent decades. Such an analogy can be expanded
to the tax realm—if data on a countrys citizens are viewed as a collective
national asset, then just as the rents from natural resource extraction are
taxed in the host country in which they are located, the same could be
argued for personal data (IMF 2019, Aslam and Shah 2020). And, just as in
the extractive industries (Cui 2018, 2019; IMF 2019), a royalty instrument
(a tax on turnover) can substitute when direct taxation of rents is dicult,
especially where hard-to-value intangibles play a large role or capacity is lim-
ited to monitor cost-based prot shifting. Current DSTs, including in Asia
(Table3) take on the avor of (highly targeted) user-based royalties (Aslam
and Shah 2020).
10
For these estimates, residual prot is dened as prot above 10percent of unrelated party sales. Only
20percent of this residual is reallocated based on the share of destination sales in each jurisdiction. e
estimates assume that this reallocation is “funded” by countries relinquishing the residual prot to which they
currently have taxing rights.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
24
DSTs essentially attempt to overcome the “PE problem,” whereby a lack of
physical presence precludes governments from staking a claim to corporate
prots on a source basis. Since bilateral tax treaties preclude countries from
unilaterally adjusting taxing rights, countries have started to look for alterna-
tives outside the purview of income taxation. e key measures employed can
be categorized as follows:
Withholding taxes on payments to non-residents for digital services. These
are levies on payments to non-residents for digital services and are similar
in concept to existing withholding taxes on cross-border technical services
(for example, accounting, management, and subcontractor services). While
initially such taxes focused on B2B payments for online advertising, they
have since expanded in-scope to cover other digital services as well as some
B2C transactions (typically relying on financial institutions as withhold-
ing agents). These withholding tax obligations have been justified as an
Table 3. Digital Services Taxes in Asia
Country Status Date Name Rate (%) Scope Threshold
Payment
Obligation
India Implemented April
2020
EL 2 Revenues received by non-
residents for online provision
or facilitation of sales of goods
and services to the Indian
market, advertising targeted at
Indian users, and sale of data
collected from Indian users
Companies generating
India-based digital services
revenue > INR 20 million in
a financial year
Paid by non-
resident
e-commerce
operators.
India Implemented March
2016
EL 6 Revenues received by non-
residents for online advertising
services supplied to Indian
residents
Aggregate payments to
nonresident > INR 100,000
in a financial year
Charged and
withheld by
resident payors
Malaysia Implemented May
2019
WHT 6 All income from e-commerce
transactions deemed to be
derived in Malaysia
Companies generating
revenue from consumers in
Malaysia >500,000 RMB/
year
Paid by
nonresident
digital service
providers
Indonesia Primary Law
Enacted
March
2020
ETT Not
Specified
Revenue received by non-
residents from e-commerce
sales to Indonesian consumers,
when the digital PE cannot be
applied due to the provision of
a tax treaty
The digital PE conditions
will be met by exceeding
thresholds for (i) group
consolidated gross turnover;
(ii) sales in Indonesia; and
(iii) active digital media users
in Indonesia
Paid by
nonresident
digital service
providers
Vietnam Under
Discussion
January
2021
WHT Variable Revenues received by
non-resident e-commerce
businesses for the supply of
services to residents
Not specified Collected
and withheld
by financial
institutions
New
Zealand
Under
Discussion
June
2019
DST 3 New Zealand-source revenue
received by intermediation
platforms, social media
platforms, content sharing sites
and search engines
Businesses with a global
consolidated annual turnover
of at least €750m, and
annual revenues attributable
to New Zealand of at least
NZ$3.5m (USD 2.3m).
Paid by
nonresident
digital service
providers
Sources: KPMG (2021); Avalara; and IMF reports.
Note: DST = digital services tax; EL = equalization levy; ETT = electronic transaction tax; WH = withholding tax.
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
25
attempt to equalize (income tax) treatment on non-residents vis-a-vis resi-
dent service providers in a world with increasing cross border remote sales.
Tax rates on payments in scope vary widely at relatively high levels of 5 to
15percent globally.
User-based taxes: DSTs typically apply to both residents and non-resident
companies, but their high global turnover and domestic revenue threshold
means that they in effect target a few large foreign MNEs.
11
An increas-
ing number of countries globally are opting for broader user-based DSTs,
motivated by the desire to capture some of the value being generated by
their citizens for highly digitalized businesses. Such DSTs target revenue
generated through interaction with users in their jurisdiction from a range
of digital services (whether for a payment or through the provision of a
free service).
12
Such DSTs are levied on a gross basis at relatively low rates,
ranging from 1.5 to 7.5percent on revenues from the sale of the digital
services in scope.
Digital Permanent Establishment: A number of countries have proceeded
with the expansion of domestic rules to establish a taxing right for virtual
permanent establishments. A taxable permanent establishment to which
income tax obligations apply is deemed to exist when an MNE’s activities
exceed a global turnover and local sales and user thresholds.
13
However,
few countries have clearly articulated rules for revenue attribution to such
virtual PEs, and many countries will be constrained in applying a revised
PE definition, due to existing tax treaties.
Several countries in the region (Table3) have begun to adopt measures
that target income from digital activities generated in their jurisdiction by
non-residents. Larger middle-income countries without home-grown tech
giants appear to have been first-movers in the region. Countries that are
home to tech MNEs, primarily China, Japan, and Korea, have, thus far,
shown little interest in enacting DSTs. DSTs implemented to date or under
consideration differ significantly in terms of design (rates, scope, threshold,
and nature of payment obligation). For instance, Indonesia introduced a rule
to establish a taxing right for virtual permanent establishments in 2020. A
user-based DST has been implemented in India, with the new Equalization
11
High global revenue thresholds result in common DSTs, eectively capturing mainly important US MNEs,
which has been argued to create de facto discrimination (see Hufbauer and Lu 2018, and USTR 2021). e
eective targeting of US MNEs by DSTs, however, is a consequence of their market dominance and may be
temporary (Avi Yonah 2020).
12
is type of tax is typied by the 2018 European Commission draft directive for the taxation of digital
services, versions of which have subsequently been unilaterally introduced by EU members. e proposed DST,
which has since served as a model for a number of EU members states, imposes a 3percent levy on revenues
from certain specied digital activities, which users have “co-created.
13
In cases where a double tax treaty does not allow for the creation of a virtual PE, an “electronic transaction
tax” is supposed to be applied, though this measure is not yet eective/specied.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
26
Levy in 2020 (Box2). Similarly, while DSTs commonly target advertising
and intermediary services, in the case of India, they also cover the provision
of digital content and the sale of goods.
Assessment of DSTs: Potential Trade-offs and Impacts
DSTs introduced to date in the region and elsewhere reect large dierences
in design and create potential trade-os. eir broader economic and welfare
impact depends on market structures and the role of automated digital ser-
vice (ADS) providers (Table4). For instance, while digitalization is an econo-
mywide phenomenon, recent country proposals and reforms have singled out
specic digital activities as the subject of taxation. is approach of “ring-
fencing” risks driving an inecient wedge between “digital” and “non-digital
activities. Moreover, in choosing revenues over prots as the base, these taxes
are less likely to tax only the pure economic rent and therefore risk distort-
ing production or disincentivizing investment.
14
e level of taxation must
therefore be calibrated accordingly. ere is also a risk of pass-through of the
tax burden to consumers, particularly in a monopolistic setting.
Withholding taxes targeting B2B payments to non-residents are easy to
implement, but also to avoid. Typically, governments require the purchaser
of a service or, in some cases, nancial intermediaries, to remit the taxation
on the payment made to the nonresident service provider. While this implies
a narrow focus on selected transactions, these withholding taxes have the
appeal of being easy to introduce and administer and as such are the most
widespread to date. Examples include the initial Indian Equalization Levy
introduced in 2016, as well as more recent withholding requirements on
payments for specic digital services in Malaysia and Vietnam. However,
while simple to design and administer, such taxes can potentially be avoided.
For example, if a resident company sets up an oshore related entity to make
the payments to the non-resident service provider, it may be possible to avoid
withholding taxes altogether.
15
DSTs based on user contribution have both a broader scope and greater
associated revenue potential but entail more complex design issues and
administrative requirements. Centering the design of a DST on user contri-
14
Rents—that is, earnings in excess of normal required returns—are an attractive tax base because they can
be taxed without distorting a companys behavior. However, taxing rents is dicult in practice, since some costs
are hard to observe and provide deductions for and many sources of rent are not location specic; therefore,
taxing them risks driving them elsewhere.
15
ATAF (2020) proposes a hybrid approach that would deal with abuse risks by determining the DST
charge as the higher amount between the direct payments made and a countrys share in apportioned global
segment revenue of a company in scope (for instance, the share of a countrys advertising views in global total
advertising views).
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
27
butions requires clear rules to determine the location of the user and meth-
ods for determining the tax base. Without any direct measure of user value,
DSTs tend to approximate the user contribution of a country based on sales
revenues. User based DSTs tend to include revenue thresholds to determine
in scope businesses. High thresholds may result in targeting a few interna-
tional rms and risk retaliation, while too low a threshold may deter entry
by smaller rms.
16
Moreover, since the tax is payable by the non-resident
MNE, the introduction of a DST comes with requirements for registration
and regular ling of returns and payment of tax due, which entails collec-
tion challenges.
e modied Indian Equalization Levy introduced in 2020 is the broadest
user-based DST adopted globally to date, but the incidence can be dicult
to assess. e Indian approach builds on the European model,
17
but expands
its scope to cover all (B2B and B2C) digital sales of its own goods, content
16
Potentially contributing to further market concentration in the tech sector.
17
In 2018 the EU Commission proposed a DST of 3percent on the gross revenue from activities relying on
user participation such as selling online advertising space and intermediary activities that allow users to interact
and sell goods and services.
Table 4. The Economic Impact of DSTs
Issues… ...and opportunities
Taxing rights and revenue
Introduction of (unliteral) DSTs risks international double taxation if not
creditable against corporate income tax payable in-home jurisdictions.
International tax rules aimed at profit are particularly hard to apply to
providers of automated digital services operating two-sided platforms
(Schindler and Schjelderup 2010). DSTs allow countries to capture
uncompensated value generated by a country’s citizens, and to share
in the rents from digitalized businesses, while taxation of profits
is difficult.
1
Efficiency and social welfare
When taxing some activities on a gross rather than a net basis distortion
may result. Taxation of loss makers risks disrupting innovative business
development/disincentivizing investment in these sectors. It is common
for developers of ADS to initially have and use aggressive pricing
strategies to gain market share/user participation.
In practice, production decisions of ADS service providers may not be
influenced at the margin; for profitable businesses taxing revenue is
not significantly different from profit-based taxation where the marginal
cost of providing additional services is minimal, as is arguably the case
for many ADS (Cui and Hashimzade 2019; Koethenbuerger 2020). In the
context of heavily concentrated market power, which is typical for two-
sided digital platforms, taxation may have positive welfare effects (Kind
and others 2008).
By targeting only some activities an inefficient wedge may be driven
between activities in and out of scope (Aslam and Shah 2020).
To the extent that the levy reduces any tax-induced comparative
advantage that foreign suppliers may enjoy over domestic suppliers,
equalizing the tax treatment could ease production inefficiencies.
If the burden of tax is passed onto customers, increases in the cost of
advertising opportunities on platforms may lead business to revert to
less efficient marketing strategies.
Incidence effects are complex in two-sided markets (IMF 2019). Firms
may aim to shift some burden to the untaxed side: a tax on advertising
creates an incentive to raise the price charged (or reduce the subsidy
provided) to users; the price of advertising services may even fall.
2
Cui
and Hashimzade (2019) show that when the marginal cost is non-zero,
the incidence of a tax on platform revenue will fall on both the platform
and the advertisers/producers, but the effect on consumers
is ambiguous.
1
As noted by Wei Cui (2021), concerns of potential double taxation of DSTs are also mitigated by the expectation of the economic incidence primarily
falling on consumers.
2
On tax incidence in two-sided markets, see also Bourreau and others (2018) and Kind and others (2008).
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
28
provision, cloud, software, nancial and education services. It also explic-
itly excludes Indian residents from the scope of the tax, rather than opting
for a high global turnover threshold. However, the incidence of the levy is
hard to assess. Where service providers charge consumers directly, some of
the tax may be passed on, depending on market conditions including the
substitutability of digital and non-digital providers. MNEs operating with a
business model of providing free services and generating revenue from sell-
ing advertising opportunities can potentially share the tax burden with third
party advertisers. In addition to the new rate of 2percent on activities in
scope of its new DST, India also maintains a higher 6percent rate on B2B
payments received by nonresidents for advertising services provided in India.
To the extent that this tax reduces any tax-induced comparative advantage
that foreign suppliers may enjoy over domestic suppliers, equalizing the tax
treatment may ease production ineciencies. However, if the tax is passed
on to customers, the tax might arguably perpetuate production ineciencies
by targeting a business input (advertising expenses) that may be of particular
importance for smaller rms benetting from targeted cost-eective online
advertising opportunities
The Potential DST Tax Base in Asia
Although widely touted as an important source of revenue, understand-
ing the potential tax base of the DST in Asia is important for determining
revenue potential. e region is highly populous, constituting a sizeable user
base, but with lower value per user than Europe and the Americas. Whether
taxing rights are determined based on the value of its users has an impact on
revenue potential. For digital businesses, the value of users is correlated with
their purchasing power, propensity to spend, and activity on the platform.
For instance, user data from Facebook indicates that the Asian region consti-
tutes a sizeable and rapidly growing user base, albeit with relatively low value
associated with each user of the platform (Figure13).
18
Surveys suggest that digital sales are sizeable for the region, although heavily
concentrated in a small number of countries.
19
e scale of Chinas digital
activity dwarfs the rest of the region. However, even without China, the
18
And the potential Asian user base and revenue is much larger, as Facebook is not (yet) operating in China.
19
e Statista surveys cover market participants as well as consumers—for India, Indonesia, ailand, and
Vietnam. Reported results for the other economies are extrapolated using indicators of purchasing power of
consumers and digital maturity in the economy. E-commerce includes sale physical goods via a digital channel
(from all types of devices) to a private end user (B2C) with cross-border purchases attributed to the country of
the buyer. E-services capture sales of services and digital goods (event ticket reservation, dating, food deliv-
ery, etc.) with an online checkout process. Digital media captures spending on audiovisual media contents
and applications distributed online. Digital advertising captures advertisement spending for online channels.
(Statista 2020).
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
29
regional DST base is comparable to Europe and the Americas (Figure4).
Larger, middle- and high-income economies dominate (Figure14), in par-
ticular Australia, India, Indonesia, Japan, Korea, and Singapore. For small,
low-income countries in the region (Brunei, Myanmar), however, the tax base
remains negligible.
At present, applying a DST is expected to yield relatively low revenues.
For example, the initial Indian Equalization Levy introduced in 2016 and
applied on payments for advertisement services, resulted in collections of
about 0.02percent of GDP from 2016–2020.
20
Estimates of the revenue
potential for DSTs in the region drawing on Statistas consumer and market
surveys suggest equally limited revenue potential, even with a wide scope of
digital services covered.
21
For example, in Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, the
Philippines and Vietnam, the application of a DST resembling Indias cur-
rent Equalization Levy, would have yielded revenue of about 0.02percent of
GDP in 2019. is corresponds to an equally modest expectation for DST
revenues in the EU and the United Kingdom.
22
e revenue potential of a
20
See https://www.avalara.com/in/en/blog/2020/09/india-digital-tax-or-equalisation-levy-a-timeline.html.
21
Assuming that 40percent of the e-commerce, 70percent of digital media, 100percent of digital advertis-
ing, 10percent of e-services, online tourism and online mobility revenues estimated by Statista are in scope
and applying the rates of the Indian DST (2percent on gross revenue in scope, 6percent on gross adver-
tising revenue).
22
e European Commission has estimated annual revenue yield from its DST for member states of EUR
5billion (<0.01percent of EU GDP). France expects to collect EUR 400million from the DST in 2020
(0.02percent of GDP). e United Kingdom estimates that its DST will raise GBP 275million (0.01percent
of GDP) in 2020–21 rising to GBP 440million (0.02percent of GDP) in 2023–24. USTR (2021) nds an
Worldwide
US and Canada
Europe
Asia Pacific
Rest of World
Worldwide
US and Canada
Europe
Asia Pacific
Rest of World
Source: Facebook (2020).
Asia accounts for a large share of Facebook’s of users, but revenue per user is significantly below world average.
Figure 13. Facebook: Active Users and Average Revenue Per User
40
35
30
0
25
20
15
10
5
2,500
2,000
1,500
1,000
0
500
1. Facebook: Average Revenue per User 2. Facebook: Monthly Active Users (MAUs)
2009 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 2009 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
30
withholding tax resembling the 2016 version of the Indian Equalization Levy
is even smaller, amounting to about a fth of the DSTs potential.
However, given the current low base, revenue is likely to have high buoyancy
in the future (Figure10, Chapter1). Moreover, the pandemic and associated
lockdown measures are accelerating the development of digital economic
activity, including transactions and sales of digital goods and services. is
trend would likely have a bearing on future revenue potential.
Future Directions and Implications
e future role of DSTs in Asia is unclear. Global trends, the uncertainty of
ongoing international negotiations, and the experience of countries in the
region following Indias lead in introducing withholding taxes resembling the
initial equalization levy, suggest that DSTs may become more widespread.
23
e implementation of DSTs could also be facilitated by ongoing eorts
in several countries to eectively capture VAT on digital goods and services
supplied from abroad as these require similar investments into administrative
infrastructure and compliance management of nonresidents (see Chapter3).
equally moderate tax revenue potential when assessing tax liabilities for US rms as a result from the Indian
DST: in aggregate, the 86 US rms that are likely in scope of the Indian DST “may face tax payments in excess
of USD 30million per year.
23
By January 2021, more than 30 countries had enacted, held public consultations on policy propos-
als, or announced their intention to introduce unilateral direct tax measures aimed at digital services,
see KPMG (2021).
Digital media
E-services
Digital revenue (% of GDP) RHS
E-commerce
Digital advertising
E-commerce
Digital media
Mobility services
Travel & tourism E-services
Share of GDP (RHS)
Digital advertising
Source: Statista (2020).
Figure 14. Survey-Based Estimates of the Tax Base and Revenue Potential in 2019
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
4.50
4.00
3.50
3.00
2.50
2.00
1.50
1.00
0.50
0.00
A tax base concentrated in larger, richer economies ... ... with modest revenue at around 0.02 percent of GDP.
Australia
Bangladesh
Bhutan
Brunei
Darussalam
Hong Kong
Indonesia
Myanmar
Philippines
Singapore
South Korea
Sri Lanka
Thailand
Vietnam
India
Japan
Malaysia
Mongolia
2019 Revenue USD Billions
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
0.10
0.08
0.06
0.04
0.02
0.00
Bangladesh India Indonesia Philippines Vietnam
USD million
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
31
e approach to DSTs in the region has been varied. Adoption in the region
to date has varied depending on whether or not countries have home-grown
tech giants. Similarly, investments in a DST are unlikely to become a pri-
ority for low-income countries with limited digital activities. However, in
the future, as the global economy recovers, specically targeting important
revenue sources could become relevant for some low-income countries. is
is particularly likely to be the case for commissions for online facilitation of
hospitality services for economies heavily dependent on tourism.
24
e immediate impact of a proliferation of DSTs in the region and beyond
would likely be limited for Asian technology MNEs. While sizeable, Asian
MNEs appear to earn the bulk of their returns in their home/residence coun-
tries. For instance, Chinese MNEs make 87percent of their sales domesti-
cally, while Korean and Japanese MNEs derive 65 and 61percent of their
revenue from the domestic market, respectively (Figure15).
In the short term, taxpayers under DSTs would primarily be US MNEs,
potentially exacerbating the potential for retaliatory trade measures. On aver-
age, 25percent of prots earned by foreign MNEs are made by US MNEs
(Figure15). For countries such as Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, the Philip-
pines, Singapore, and Vietnam, US MNEs dominate, accounting for more
than 50percent of prots earned by foreign MNEs. DSTs, however, open
the door to retaliatory trade measures. For instance, the United States Trade
Representative (USTR) estimates that more than 70percent of digital service
companies subject to the Indian DST are US based and classied the tax as
discriminatory (USTR 2021). is classication allows for the imposition of
duties on Indian goods as part of a potential package of retaliatory measures
against countries operating DSTs.
25
Regional and bilateral coordination of DSTs could help reduce collection
costs and trade tensions. DSTs expand taxing rights over digital services
provided by nonresidents to market countries. Available information and
initial country experiences suggest that while the immediate revenue potential
is small, implementation of these taxes results in non-negligible administra-
tive and compliance costs. Regional coordination of central design features,
including on the scope of the rules, key denitions, as well as registration,
reporting and payment obligations could thus help ensure that compliance
costs associated with DSTs do not become barriers to market entry.
26
More-
24
For instance, Malaysia expanded the scope of its tourism tax charged per room per night in 2020 to cover
accommodation booked through online platforms and will impose the tax on resident and nonresident digital
platform service providers from July 2021.
25
Similar to taris announced following an investigation of France’s DST. ese were announced in July
2020, scheduled to go into eect in January 2021 (but have been temporarily suspended).
26
e African Tax Administration Forum (ATAF) for instance proposed model legislation for Digital Services
Taxes to its member states.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
32
Australia
Korea
China
Singapore
India
United States
Indonesia
Europe
Japan
Other
Sources: IMF, World Economic Outlook; and OECD country by country reports.
Note: MNEs = multinational enterprises.
Share of unrelated party sales from the domestic market
20
40
60
80
100
0
Figure 15. MNE Activities at Home and Abroad and the Destination of Asian MNE Profits
Chinese, Indian, and Indonesian MNEs make most of their sales at home... ... while US MNEs account for an important share of profits earned by
foreign MNEs in Asia.
GDP per capita (current USD)
Mongolia
Brunei
Timor-Leste
American Samoa
Bangladesh
Sri Lanka
Guam
Tonga
Vanuatu
Samoa
Solomon Islands
Nepal
Maldives
Bhutan
Marshall Islands
Australia
Myanmar
Macao SAR
Lao P.D.R.
Cambodia
China
India
Thailand
Hong Kong SAR
Japan
Taiwan POC
Korea
Philippines
Malaysia
Singapore
Indonesia
Vietnam
Fiji
New Zealand
Papua New Guinea
0.00
0.03
0.77
3.45
0.22
0.13
0.00
0.02
0.03
0.03
0.05
0.62
0.67
0.81
1.65
1.47
0.50
4.72
0.24
0.32
0.92
0.69
4.93
20.12
0.58
0.57
0.38
0.91
3.17
11.48
0.89
0.52
0.57
2.37
1.43
0 20 40 60 80 100
120,000
100,000
80,000
60,000
40,000
20,000
Bermuda
Ireland
Luxembourg
Netherlands
Sweden
Austria
Belgium
Denmark
Finland
France
Norway
Singapore
Australia
Canada
Italy
Japan
Korea
United States
Chile
Mexico
Poland
Slovenia
South Africa
China
India
Indonesia
Distribution of foreign MNE profit by headquarter country
Profit of foreign MNE (percent of GDP)
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
33
over, the proposed introduction of a new article into the UN Model Tax
Convention to deal with income from ADS could allow for bilateral coor-
dination of DSTs. e proposal builds on the existing tax treaty framework
guiding international tax rules and could eventually contribute to lowering
the risk of retaliatory taris between source/market and residence countries of
digital service providers.
Alternative Policy Options
Other policy options for taxing prots in an increasingly digitalized econ-
omy are more far reaching. e scope of these alternative options is wider
than digital businesses, given the diculties and ineciencies associated
with ringfencing digital business. Digitalization will continue and pervade
the economy, making ringfencing irrelevant in the future. In addition, other
sectors exhibit similar challenges, for example, pharmaceutical companies also
rely on hard-to-value intangibles. Importantly, unlike Pillar 1, these alter-
native policies reform the entire existing international taxation architecture,
rather than acting as an addition to existing norms. Following is a discussion
of two policy alternatives that could potentially address the key concerns with
the taxation of multinational prots in an increasingly digitalized economy:
formulary apportionment and residual prot allocation.
27,28
While digital
businesses are not explicitly targeted, their tax treatment is likely to be mark-
edly dierent under these two alternative reform options since their business
models enable a signicant disconnect between where prots are currently
booked and the location of factors of production or sales.
Formulary Apportionment
Formulary apportionment (FA) can address many of the challenges faced by
the current requirement to consider each aliate of an MNE group as a sepa-
rate entity (and hence the need to value intra-group transactions). Under this
approach, the revenue of the MNE group is consolidated across all aliates
and then allocated across countries based on each countrys share of the allo-
cation factor or key. e allocation key can be supply-based (assets, employ-
ment, or payroll) or demand-based (sales, user value). Each country can then
27
Other policy alternatives, such as a destination-based cash-ow tax, are discussed in IMF (2019) and Auer-
bach and others (2017).
28
ese alternatives, initially proposed by tax practitioners and academics, have gained traction with policy
makers (for example, the G24’s proposal for fractional apportionment), outlined in the Intergovernmental
Group of 24’s submission to the OECD on possible solutions to the tax challenges of digitalization. India was
the rst to propose such a solution, which was then endorsed by other members.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
34
apply its own tax rate or credits to the apportioned base.
29
Elements of FA
are included in Pillar 1, namely, the consolidation of prots to compute the
residual prot and the apportionment of this prot using a formula (in the
case of Pillar 1, the apportionment key is sales). However, under FA, all the
MNE’s consolidated prot is subject to apportionment rather than just a pro-
portion of residual prot. By calculating the tax base at a consolidated level,
FA eliminates the issues associated with arms-length pricing, which holds
the prospect of signicant simplication and removes prot shifting.
30
e
inclusion of demand-based factors in the formula, such as sales, can poten-
tially improve the perceived “fairness” of taxing rights, as is envisaged under
Amount A of Pillar 1.
At the global level, introducing FA can lead to a loss in CIT revenue, if CIT
rates remain unchanged. By allowing MNEs to consolidate prots and losses
across subsidiaries, FA leads to a loss in the aggregate tax base. e revenue
loss from FA is partially oset by a reallocation of the tax base from low-tax
to high-tax countries, as prot shifting is mitigated. at said, the global
revenue loss is based on existing CIT rates and can potentially be recouped
through an increase in those tax rates—although the scope and desirability of
this will dier across countries and will also depend on the allocation for-
mula. e scope for higher rates is more likely, for instance, if allocation is
based on destination sales, as the intensity of tax competition will be reduced.
High-income countries in the Asia-Pacic stand to benet from a sales-based
apportionment, while developing countries benet from employment-based
apportionment (see Annex2 for a full set of results). is is broadly consis-
tent with what is observed globally (Figures 16 and 17). Two data sets are
used for the analysis. e rst, from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis,
provides a detailed snapshot of the operation of US MNEs, allowing the
revenue eects under a wide range of apportionment formulas to be consid-
ered; this dataset is used despite its narrow focus on US MNEs. e second
is based on country-by-country reports which cover large MNEs from 25
countries with broader coverage of developing countries. High-income coun-
tries such as Australia and New Zealand gain revenue under a sales-based
formula applied to US MNEs, as well as non-US MNEs. Similarly, develop-
ing countries such as India, Malaysia, and the Philippines gain revenue from
an employment-based formula. Hong Kong SAR and Singapore, prominent
investment hubs, lose revenue from moving to FA. Singapore loses regardless
29
FA is commonly used to distribute CIT revenue at the subnational level, for instance, in countries such as
Canada, Germany, Japan and the United States. e European Commission has proposed such an approach
for the EU, in the form of the ’Common Consolidated Tax Base’, wherein the weights are a composite of sales,
assets, employment, payroll, and data.
30
See de Mooij and others (2019) for a detailed discussion of the benets and drawbacks of formu-
lary apportionment.
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
35
of the apportionment factor and under both data sources, while Hong Kong
SAR loses revenue under all but one apportionment factor. Revenue eects
under FA are larger than for Amount A because FA reallocates the entirety of
an MNE’s group prot, rather than a proportion of it.
Emps Sales
Assets
CD CCCTB VA Employment Payroll Sales Assets
Sources: CbCR for 2016; OECD; US Bureau of Economic Analysis; and de Mooij and others (2019).
Note: The Common Consolidated Corporate Tax Base (CCCTB) is a weighting based on assets, sales, employment and payroll, this estimate excludes the data factor.
VA stands for value added and is based on the reported series from the BEA. The Cobb Douglas (CD) weighting is based on assets and payroll, an alternate measure
of value added. Income brackets follow the World Bank definition and refer to the median country in the income group.
Figure 16. Change in Income Tax Revenue from Applying FA
1. U.S. MNEs
(Percent of GDP)
2. Large MNEs
(Percent of GDP)
–1.5 –1.0 –0.5 0.0 0.5 1.0–1.5 –1 –0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5
High income
Upper middle
Lower middle
Low
Australia
China
Hong Kong SAR
India
Indonesia
Japan
Korea
Malaysia
New Zealand
Philippines
Singapore
Taiwan POC
Thailand
High income
Upper middle
Lower middle
Australia
China
Hong Kong SAR
India
Indonesia
Japan
Korea
Malaysia
New Zealand
Philippines
Singapore
Taiwan POC
Thailand
Australia
Bangladesh
Bhutan
China
India
Japan
Cambodia
South Korea
Laos
Mongolia
Malaysia
New Zealand
Philippines
Singapore
Thailand
Source: Beer and others (2020).
Figure 17. Total CIT Revenue Effects from Destination-Based RPA
Revenue change (in percent of GDP)
–4
–3
–2
–1
0
1
2
5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
log(GDP per capita)
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
36
Under FA, rms at either end of the digitalization spectrum face the same
treatment, but there would be signicant changes to the taxation of highly
digitalized rms compared to others.
31
Firms would pay part of their tax
where consumers, or factors of production, are located. For highly digitalized
rms, the ability to make cross-border sales without physical presence means
a signicant disconnect exists between where taxes are currently paid and the
location of consumers. FA does not allocate taxing rights to the location of
intangibles, driving the disconnect between the current distribution of taxes
and those under FA even further for digitalized rms.
Residual Prot Allocation
e Inclusive Framework Pillar 1 proposal belongs to a wider family of
schemes that treat routine and residual prots dierently for tax purposes.
e schemes have in common that the taxing right of a routine return would
be allocated to jurisdictions where production takes place. e excess of a
groups earnings over its total routine prots, the residual, would then be
allocated based on some formulaic approach. e OECD-IF Pillar 1 com-
putes routine returns as a percent of sales and suggests redistributing a share
of the resulting global residual. However, other proposals exist, and routine
returns could be computed as a xed percentage of tangible asset stocks, cost
of goods sold, or by retaining traditional transfer pricing methods for func-
tions within a group that are believed to be “routine.” An important dier-
ence between these proposals and the OECD-IF Pillar 1 approach is that the
latter would retain current arrangements and subject large companies, where
turnover exceeds a certain threshold, to a residual prot allocation (RPA)
scheme. Countries would thus need to surrender taxing rights of large com-
panies’ excess prots to avoid double taxation. In contrast, an RPA scheme
that replaces current arrangements could yield signicant simplication gains
by assigning taxing rights over the routine component and allowing residuals
to be negative.
32
e revenue impact from introducing an RPA scheme is likely to be sizeable,
especially for Asia.
33
Assuming that routine returns amount to 10percent of
tangible asset stocks,
34
micro data suggest the global residual could amount
to USD 3trillion––much more than the residual prot that is considered in
the OECD-IF’s blueprint—and half of this amount is currently declared in
16 Asian economies. is design of the RPA would have a disproportionate
31
FA regimes generally have special treatment only for the extractives and nancial sectors.
32
A discussion of negative residuals can be found in Beer and others (2020).
33
e following analysis is based on Beer and others (2020).
34
Routine prots correspond broadly to a normal return on investment. Commonly, a return to tangible
assets is chosen at a level which is suciently high to encompass a return to all assets (including intangibles).
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
37
eect on highly digitalized rms, and others
which have a heavy reliance on intangi-
ble assets, since their return on tangible
assets will be elevated. For these rms, it
represents a fundamental change to where
they pay tax. Less tax will be paid where
intangibles are located, and more tax will be
paid in market countries. Figure17 illus-
trates revenue eects from introducing an
RPA mechanism that allocates the taxing
right of residual prot in proportion to
destination-based sales, which is believed to
be an ecient apportionment factor given
its unresponsiveness to corporate tax rate
dierentials. It shows that ve Asian econ-
omies, with relatively low average income
(Bangladesh, India, Laos, and Mongolia)
would tend to benet from such a reallo-
cation scheme, while many others, including Australia, Malaysia, and Singa-
pore, would tend to lose. Revenue losses are largest in Singapore, where the
decline in corporate revenues could exceed 55percent of current CIT collec-
tions (2.5percent of GDP).
Revenues are impacted because of the elimination of prot shifting. Although
transfer pricing rules aim to ensure a reasonable allocation of prots across
the subsidiaries of an MNE group, considerable leeway exists in determining
where residual prots end up in practice. RPA schemes, in contrast, depart
from the presumption that subsidiaries are independent entities for which
a fair remuneration can be established and use information on consolidated
returns, with allocation of the residual based on FA. Figure18 provides
illustrative revenue estimates from eliminating prot shifting, which are very
sensitive to the underlying assumptions. Overall, CIT rates in Asia are com-
paratively low, and many countries could lose if reported prots were no lon-
ger relocated for tax reasons. However, revenue eects vary widely and while
Singapore could lose up to 7.5percent of current CIT collections (0.4per-
cent of GDP), India would stand to gain 5percent (0.2percent of GDP).
e revenue impact also reects the relocation of excess prots. Figure19
illustrates the revenue eect from reallocating residual returns once prot
shifting has been eliminated. e reallocation would increase revenues in
countries with large destination-based sales, which is positively correlated
with trade decits, and reduce revenues in high-income countries and
investment hubs. For instance, Laos would gain about 30percent of cur-
Australia
Bangladesh
Bhutan
China
India
Japan
Cambodia
South Korea
Laos
Mongolia
Malaysia
Nepal
New Zealand
Philippines
Singapore
Thailand
Source: Beer and others (2020).
Figure 18. Partial CIT Revenue Effectsfrom Elimination of
Profit Shifting
–0.4
–0.3
–0.2
–0.1
0
0.1
0.2
0.3
CIT rate (in percent)
Change in revenue due to elimination of profit shifting
(in percent of GDP)
2015 25 30 35
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
38
rent revenues (0.5percent
of GDP) while Singapore
could lose about 50percent
(2.1percent of GDP).
Under a destination-based
RPA scheme, countries
would have scope to increase
taxes on corporations.
Destination-based RPA
schemes could address some
of the challenges of taxing
highly digitalized rms, as
well as broader challenges
with prot shifting and tax
competition. By shifting
taxing rights to countries
where consumers are located
(’market’ countries), countries have scope to tax their share of prot at a
relatively higher rate than under the current system, without inducing adverse
eects, since MNEs that wish to access their market have little choice but to
pay the tax.
35
For countries that tend to lose revenue from RPA, such higher
tax rates could partly oset loss in revenue, although further revenue mobi-
lization eorts might sometimes be needed too. If a global minimum tax is
implemented as well, countries could enjoy further revenue gains. is might
also hold for low-tax jurisdictions, which are the likely losers of RPA, since
they could raise their tax rates up to at least the global minimum, without
aecting MNEs. e success of this strategy would rely on the jurisdictions
ability to attract and retain foreign investment, based on its broader (non-tax)
comparative advantages.
35
ere could be an incentive to sell to a third-party distributor located in a low-cost jurisdiction. Sourcing
rules could be introduced to mitigate this new form of tax avoidance.
Australia
Bangladesh
Bhutan
China
India
Japan
Cambodia
South Korea
Laos
Mongolia
Malaysia
Nepal
New Zealand
Philippines
Singapore
Thailand
Sales (in percent of tax base)
Change in revenue due to reallocation of residuals
(in percent of GDP)
–3
–2.5
–2
–1.5
–1
–0.5
0
0.5
1
1.5
50 150 250 350 450 550 650 750
Source: Beer and others (2020).
Figure 19. Partial CIT Revenue Effects—from Reallocation of
Residual Earnings
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
39
e 2016 Levy
In 2016, India introduced an equalization levy in the form of a withholding tax on
payments by domestic businesses (Indian residents or Indian PEs of nonresidents)
to nonresident entities for online advertising services, at a rate of 6percent. e tax
applies to any nonresident receiving payments from Indian residents of more than
INR 100,000 (approximately USD 1,500) in a nancial year. For this version of the
levy, the burden of compliance is placed on the domestic recipient of services, with the
Indian purchaser of the digital advertising services being responsible for withholding
and remitting the digital advertising tax to the Indian government. is levy resulted
in collections of INR 7billion, about USD 100million (<0.01percent of GDP and
0.06percent of total tax revenues), in FY2017–18.
e 2020 Levy
In March 2020, the Indian government introduced a new levy applying a 2percent
charge on revenue generated by nonresident companies from a range of digital services
oered in India.
In-scope Activities. e companies subject to the DST must pay the tax on revenue
they derive from “e-commerce supply or services,” including the sale of online goods
and services (including through platforms) to any person who is resident in India or
who uses an Indian internet protocol address. It also applies to any nonresident who
is purchasing advertising services targeted at Indian residents, or selling data collected
from Indian residents or users with an Indian IP address. e broad scope of activities
eectively captures a wide range of services, including those that are not captured under
other DSTs, such as the supply of digital content, the sale of goods and services elec-
tronically, and cloud services.
With respect to B2B online advertising payments, the 2016 advertising levy
still remains in place. e 2016 levy taxes any payment made by a resident to a
non-resident for online advertising, regardless of the location of the recipient or viewer
of the advertisement, and the 2020 levy does not apply to payments already taxed
under the 2016 levy. However, the 2020 levy extends the scope of Indias taxing rights
to cover payments between two nonresidents if the advertising services are targeted at
Indian users. As noted in USTR (2021), “if an Indian company were to pay Google
(a US company) to advertise on Googles search engine, that revenue would be subject
to the 2016 digital advertising tax, and therefore not subject to the DST. However, if
Airbnb (a US company) were to pay Google to advertise to Indian users on Googles
search engine, that revenue would be subject to the DST.
Box 2. India’s Equalization Levy
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
40
Companies in-scope. e tax is payable only by nonresident e-commerce operators, spe-
cically excluding all Indian companies or nonresidents with a PE in India. In addition,
the tax applies only to companies above the threshold of Rs20million (approximately
US$270,000) in India-based digital services revenue.
Administration. Unlike the original levy on advertising, the nonresident e-commerce
operator is responsible for charging and paying.
Box 2. India’s Equalization Levy (continued)
Income Tax for Highly Digitalized Businesses in Asia—Challenges and a Way Forward
41
Changes in business models and consumption patterns due to digitalization pose
challenges for the VAT, but the policy concerns dier from those discussed previ-
ously for the CIT. Adopting and implementing a framework for eectively levying
VAT on the import of digitally delivered services and goods can improve general
compliance and revenue collection, including for other taxes, and help ensure a
level playing eld for domestic businesses.
e value-added tax on digital transactions does not involve any fundamental
rethink of taxing rights, but rather the development of a mechanism to give
eect to the destination principle in the case of digital transactions. e VAT
is a tax on consumption imposed commonly on the destination principle,
1
which means that the taxing right is commonly located at destination or the
place of consumption. It is often harder for services than for goods to deter-
mine the place of consumption, and the digital economy is exacerbating the
challenge of eectively imposing the taxing right in the case of cross-border
supplies of digital products that do not pass through any border control.
Challenges for VAT or sales tax design and collection arise in relation to
intangible services and some categories of goods/services supplied online
and/or with their supply facilitated by platform intermediaries. ey
include the following:
Digital services provided directly to final customers/consumers, such as
movies, music, and accounting services provided by multinational firms.
Such digital services pose challenges as there is no physical trace of the
transaction at the border, and sellers often do not have a domestic pres-
1
As provided for in the OECD (2017) VAT guidelines. A major reform along these lines was introduced in
the EU in 2015 to ensure taxation at destination on intra-EU supplies, which previously was based on origin
(the location of the supplier). See Dale and Vincent (2017).
Digital Services, Digitally Delivered Goods,
and VAT
CCHAPTERHAPTER
3
43
ence. While non-registered businesses and final consumers are sometimes
theoretically required to self-assess VAT, this tends to be an unenforceable
obligation in practice.
2
Imported services provided to businesses. B2B supplies provided by
non-residents are commonly subject to a VAT reverse charge whereby the
domestic business is required to account for the VAT on the imported
service. It can then take an input tax credit (for the self-billed VAT) when
calculating its VAT liability.
Goods supplied by foreign-based online sellers. E-commerce makes it
easier for foreign companies without a domestic presence to supply goods
to consumers. Currently, it is common for countries to provide a general
de minimis exemption threshold for low-value consignments, allowing for
tax-free supplies. Volumes of these transactions have increased as a result of
digitalization and bringing such transactions into the tax net can be diffi-
cult where goods are imported as personal items.
3
Adopting and implementing a framework for eectively levying VAT on the
import of digitally delivered services and goods helps ensure a level play-
ing eld for domestic businesses. Resident businesses with a total turnover
exceeding the VAT threshold and selling online directly to resident consum-
ers are required to register and charge VAT on their sales. Local sellers of
goods and services that use digital platforms to access consumers are simi-
larly required to register and remit VAT. With some evidence of e-commerce
activities being particularly benecial for the productivity of small rms in
Asia (Kinda 2019), several countries pursue an explicit and ambitious agenda
for the digital transition, including the promotion of digital entrepreneur-
ship, aimed at encouraging these activities. Levelling the VAT playing eld
for domestic providers of digital services and goods, by ensuring that their
non-resident competitors are liable for the same VAT, can eliminate distor-
tions and contribute to supporting local digital entrepreneurship.
4
Digital Services in Asia
VAT reform is important due to the rapid growth in digitally delivered
services in Asia. Over the last decade, these more than doubled and now
account for almost half of all service trade in Asia (Figure20). Although an
2
Requiring the individual consumers to register and fulll the necessary steps to remit VAT on a one-o
purchase on the internet is challenging (see Box4).
3
Without an agent or bill of entry that would help identify VAT and customs duty payments due and the
responsible taxpayer.
4
Levelling the playing eld is preferable to pursuing this objective with new tax incentives for digital startups.
In Vietnam, for instance, in 2020 incentives aimed at innovative startups were introduced, including a reduc-
tion of the corporate tax rate to 10percent for 30 years (Decree No.94/2020/ND-CP).
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
44
important part of these activities is related to business-to-business transac-
tions and does not translate into additional VAT revenue, a non-negligible
share is linked to supplies made to nal consumers. And supplies of some
digitally delivered services to consumers have been strongly aected by social
distancing measures introduced as part of the COVID-19 policy response,
with notable increases in demand for the remote supply of digital entertain-
ment services, for example (Figure20).
Policy Options and Country Practices
Emerging country practices can provide guidance on policy reforms and
administrative arrangements to ensure eective VAT collection on digital
services. Arrangements have been implemented by more than 60 coun-
tries, including a growing number in Asia (Table5) for both e-services and
low-value imported goods. e emerging international norm is to allocate
taxing rights under the VAT to the jurisdiction in which consumption occurs
based on the vendor collection model (see below).
5
5
e customer’s location is commonly determined by a combination of the information on the customer’s
payment prole (credit card information, bank account details), residence (billing address or home address),
and their internet access (the internet protocol of the device used or the country code of their SIM card [if
transaction made through a mobile device], location of the consumers xed landline). Most countries require
two pieces of nonconicting information to make this determination.
Australia China Hong Kong SAR
Macao SAR Taiwan Province of
Japan Korea, Republic of
Indonesia
Malaysia
New Zealand Philippines
Singapore Thailand
Vietnam
Netflix
Viu
iFlix
Sources: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development; and Google Trends.
Note: Streaming example for Indonesia.
Figure 20. Increase in Digitally Delivered Services and Demand for Digital Media
100
90
60
70
50
0
80
10
20
30
40
2005 07 09 11 13 15 17 19 2016
16 17
17 18 18 18 19 19 20 20
20
0
20,000
40,000
60,000
80,000
100,000
120,000
140,000
Streaming service searches (100 = peak popularity)
Digitally delivered services doubled in the past decade … … and demand for media streaming rose during the pandemic.
1. 2.
USD millions
Digital Services, Digitally Delivered Goods, and VAT
45
e usual rst step is to update VAT legislation to ensure coverage of remote
supplies directly to consumers. Activities covered by such legislation can
either be broadly or specically dened. e OECD VAT Guidelines set
out principles that apply broadly to all internationally traded services and
intangibles which should be taxed according to the rules of the jurisdic-
tion of consumption, removing the need to dene a specic subcategory of
Table 5. VAT on Digital Services—Approaches in Asia-Pacific
Country/ year of
adoption Threshold Scope of Services Collection Method
Reverse
Charge
for B2B
Australia (2017) AUS$75,000 Intangible supplies, anything other than goods or
real property
Vendor Collection Model Yes
Bangladesh
(2019)
BDT 30 million Streaming or download media and web-based
services
Collection by local payment provider Yes
India (2017) No threshold for
nonresidents
For Indian residents:
INR-10 lakh in
annual sales
A service is mediated over the internet or an
electronic network and the nature of which
renders their supply essentially automated
and involving minimal human intervention,
and impossible to ensure in the absence of
information technology
Includes streaming/downloads of music, e-books,
films; cloud-based or downloadable software;
membership fees to online sites, dating portals;
online gambling services; online advertising
Vendor Collection Model Yes
Indonesia (2020) Annual revenue
600m IDR, or
50m monthly
revenue; and 12,000
users annually/1000
users monthly
Foreign digital service providers and
intermediaries included on a government list
Vendor Collection Model Yes
Japan (2015) JYP 10 million per
annum
E-books, streaming media, apps, cloud-based
services and online gaming, services that post
online ads; voice and data telephony services
are excluded
Vendor Collection Model Yes
Singapore
(2020)
Global annual
turnover of at least
SDG 1 million,
making B2C supplies
of digital services to
non-GST registered
customers in
Singapore exceeding
$100,000
Supplies of downloadable digital content,
subscription-based media, software programs,
electronic data management services, support
services performed via electronic means to
arrange or facilitate transactions, which may
not be digital in nature (for example, service
or booking fee charged to the suppliers or
customers)
Vendor Collection Model Yes
Thailand
(September
2021)
THB 1.8m
(more than €60,000)
per annum
A service that includes incorporeal property
delivered through the internet or other electronic
means, where the service is, in essence,
performed automatically, and where the service
cannot be performed without information
technology; focus on streaming services and
online games
Vendor Collection Model Yes
Vietnam (2020) None Download or streaming media, apps, e-books
and online journals, e-learning, software-as-a-
service provisions, gaming, and online gambling
Collection by local payment provider Yes
Sources: KPMG (2021); Avalara; and IMF reports.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
46
digital services that should be in scope. Australia takes this approach: its tax
legislation applies broadly to the “sale of imported services and digital prod-
ucts” and species that intangible supplies are “anything other than goods
or real property.” e legislation includes digital services, but also applies
more widely to activities such as consulting services.
6
Other countries such as
Japan have taken the approach of setting out more denitive lists of activi-
ties in their legislation, covering the provision of audio-visual content, cloud
computing and advertising. Many countries are updating and revising their
approaches as international practice crystallizes,
7
including on the treatment
of intermediary fees (Box3).
Some countries decided initially to list companies in scope rather than
activities, which brings its own challenges. is approach has been taken
by Indonesia
8
through the periodic publication of company lists. e tar-
gets were initially the largest companies providing digital services. Indonesia
then gradually expanded the list to include more companies.
9
While the
idea of targeting just a few large players initially may help address concerns
on administrative burdens created by the new rules, it comes with its own
challenges of needing to identify relevant companies and creates distortions
between included and excluded suppliers. A self-assessment approach seems
more viable in the long-run. Increasing adoption of similar rules globally and
initial country experience suggests that perceived reputational costs associ-
ated with non-compliance tend to be large enough to ensure registration and
constructive engagement with major companies.
Imported services provided to registered VAT payers are usually subject to
reverse charge rules or, where this is not the case, countries are in the process
of implementing such rules. For example, Singapore implemented reverse
charge regimes for B2B supplies of imported services. Issues can, however,
arise regarding the treatment of large entities (government entities, nancial
and education institutions, and so forth) that make exempt VAT supplies.
Where the recipient uses imported services wholly or partly to make exempt
supplies, there is an incentive to source services, such as virtual learning oer-
6
e EU broadly denes the nature of in-scope digital or electronically supplied services to be covered under
new VAT legislation. e EU VAT Directive, species electronically supplied services to mean “services deliv-
ered over the internet or an electronic network and the nature of which renders their supply essentially auto-
mated and involving minimum human intervention, and impossible to ensure in the absence of information
technology.” A list of examples is provided in the accompanying VAT regulation, along with selected exclusions.
7
In some cases, exemptions are explicitly carved out for example, online gaming (Norway), professional ser-
vices provided over email (EU), and the provision of education and health services through digital means, areas
that are typically zero-rated in domestic legislation in these countries.
8
Other examples outside the region include Argentina and Costa Rica.
9
e Indonesian Directorate General of Taxation issued the rst list in July 2020. is included companies in
the spotlight of the digital tax debate, namely Amazon, Google, Netix, and Spotify. Four subsequent lists were
published between July and November, bringing the total number of in scope businesses to 46.
Digital Services, Digitally Delivered Goods, and VAT
47
ings, from abroad to limit unrecoverable input VAT. An extension of reverse
charge rules to cover these entities can help prevent the bias.
e most common administrative approach to implement these legal changes
is the vendor collection model (Brondolo and Konza 2021).
10
Under this
model, in line with the OECD guidelines, the liability of payment of the
tax by and large rests with the nonresident provider of the service, who
is required to register. Countries rely on voluntary compliance through a
simplied registration process for nonresident providers with activity above
a mandatory registration threshold.
11
is typically requires issuing guid-
ance on making payments for the VAT due through a simplied online
registration and compliance process.
12
Modelling these on approaches intro-
duced by other countries is advisable to minimize compliance costs for large
digital providers.
Several countries are planning on making marketplaces fully liable for VAT
collection on low-value consignments. In the EU and the United Kingdom,
the decision to remove the low-value goods exemption threshold has been
accompanied with guidelines making marketplaces the deemed supplier for
low value imported goods facilitated by them.
13
e same requirement could
allow countries in Asia to reduce or abolish their exemption threshold for
low-value imported goods without incurring unmanageable collection costs.
10
ere are some exceptions. In Argentina, Azerbaijan, and Bangladesh, for example, the liability falls not on
the non-resident supplier but on the local payment provider. Where that is the case, specication of transac-
tions for which payment providers need to withhold VAT is required, likely narrowing the scope of covered
supplies in practice. While this approach can thereby help address compliance management challenges, it is
unlikely to be a desirable long-term solution in most countries. A hybrid approach is pursued in Costa Rica,
where the government does allow voluntary compliance by companies on the in-scope list, but if they do not
comply, the payment is withheld by card issuers (for example, Visa, MasterCard).
11
resholds for cross-border digital services for VAT registration are typically at the same level or below the
domestic requirement for mandatory registration. Some countries do not include a threshold, even if one exists
in domestic legislation (for example, Moldova), or a modied lower threshold may apply. As part of its general
rules, Indonesia provides for a second threshold related to customer trac levels, which is used in conjunction
with the monetary threshold—the threshold is reached if the amount of trac or access in Indonesia exceeds
12,000 users annually or 1,000 users monthly. As discussed above, currently, however, registration requirements
are in practice limited to companies directly referenced in regularly published ocial lists.
12
No input credits can be claimed by foreign registrants in the simplied registration process. Consequently,
abuse risks are less of a concern than with regular registrants. If a foreign service provider wants to claim input
tax credits for supplies made in another country, the usual requirement is to establish a place of business in the
country and to go through the regular registration process.
13
From July (January) 2021, the EU (and United Kingdom), require platforms to withhold and remit VAT
on low-value parcels on behalf of sellers.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
48
Revenue Potential
Estimates suggest that the direct short-term revenue potential of including
imported digital services aimed at nal consumers and purchases of goods
online ranges between 0.02 and 0.11percent of GDP. When Australia
introduced its GST on digital services in 2017, it was expected to generate
AUD 350million (0.02percent of GDP) over two years.
14
In ailand the
expectation is to raise about THB3billion (0.017percent of GDP) from
the implementation of a 7percent VAT on nonresident service provid-
ers in 2021.
15
Estimates based on survey data suggest that charging VAT
on remotely delivered digital services and some goods to customers could
directly increase overall VAT revenue by between 0.04 and 0.11percent
of GDP in Bangladesh, India, Indonesia, the Philippines, and Vietnam
(Figure21).
16
is initial revenue gain can become larger through indirect eects. Gov-
ernments can realize potential additional benets from including digital
services and e-commerce in the VAT net by (1) using the large amount of
information held by digital platforms to enhance compliance with VAT,
other taxes, and other taxpayers and (2) using the platforms as tax collection
agents. Options for this include requesting information collected by digital
marketplaces on the income of suppliers operating through their platforms.
is information can then inform compliance management, for example, in
the tourism sector and of mobility services. is can signicantly contribute
to revenues.
17
Introducing reporting obligations to obtain information on
consumption and income generated via digital platforms can thus produce
important additional benets for governments.
18
14
Australia introduced 10percent GST on cross-border sales of services and digital products imported by
Australian consumers on July 1, 2017, following enactment of Tax and Superannuation Laws Amendment Bill
2016. e budget initially estimated revenue collection of A$150million during the rst year (FY2017–18),
followed by A$200million in FY2018–19.
15
https://www.avalara.com/vatlive/en/vat-news/thailand-vat-on-digital-services-near.html.
16
Applying the standard VAT rate and assuming that 100percent of transactions of digital media con-
tent, 10percent of all e-commerce transactions, 5percent of digital advertising, and 15percent of e-services,
mobility and travel services captured by Statista are provided by unregistered remote suppliers to nal
consumers and/or unregistered registered entities. For details on the Statista survey see also discussion
in section 2 on Digital Services Taxes.
17
In Croatia, for instance, a compliance management campaign launched in 2018 drew on a compari-
son of domestic tax returns with digital platform data regarding hotel and lodging accommodation sold on
behalf of Croatian suppliers. About 40percent of Croatian vendors using the platforms covered in the cam-
paign either did not register or declared signicantly less income for tax purposes than they received from
platform-facilitated sales (World Bank 2021).
18
Recent guidance provided by OECD (2020b) on model reporting rules for platform operators provide a
useful reference framework. See also OECD (2019) on the dierent approaches to leveraging the prominent
role of digital platforms for the collection of VAT.
Digital Services, Digitally Delivered Goods, and VAT
49
ere is also potential to rely on platforms to widen the VAT net for domes-
tic activities. Canada, for instance, announced revisions to VAT rules for
accommodation/hospitality services facilitated by marketplaces/platform
providers. ey include both a requirement for marketplaces to report infor-
mation on the property owner or suppliers using their platforms to the reve-
nue services from 2022. In addition, there is a requirement to collect tax on
supplies made through their platforms by all nonregistered domestic suppli-
ers, including those considered to be small suppliers below the current VAT
registration threshold.
19
is practice has also been adopted in India
where
platforms are required to remit GST to the government for suppliers whose
turnover is below GST registration thresholds (Box4). is practice is not
common but may evolve and become more widespread in the coming years
as it is a particularly attractive option for countries in the region with large
compliance gaps driving low VAT eciency (Figure21). Relatedly, it would
be an eective means to mitigate potential negative impacts on VAT revenue
from the growth of small suppliers in the sharing economy.
20
19
Fall Economic Statement, 2020, Annex4
https://www.budget.gc.ca/fes-eea/2020/report-rapport/anx4-en.html.
20
rough the use of P2P platforms, increasingly ecient small businesses may better compete with and
displace larger incumbents. If the rise of the sharing economy means that incumbents are being displaced and
replacement P2P activity remains below tax thresholds, governments risk losing revenue as income and prots
are dispersed across many smaller businesses instead of concentrated in large protable companies (Aslam
and Shah 2017).
Bangladesh Cambodia Indonesia Nepal
Philippines Sri Lanka Thailand
Digital advertising
Digital media
E-commerce
E-services
Mobility services
Travel & tourism
Share of GDP (RHS)
Sources: Statista; and Tax Policy Assessment Framework.
Note: Statista estimates are for 2019.
Figure 21. Survey-Based Estimates of Direct VAT Revenue Potential and VAT Efficiency in Asia
1
0.7
0.6
0.8
0.9
0.3
0.4
0.2
0
0.5
0.1
Bangladesh India Indonesia Philippines Vietnam 2000
03 06
09 12 15 18
Expanding VAT regimes can contribute directly to revenue collection ...
... and indirectly, by improving compliance/VAT c-efficiency.
0
500
1,000
1,500
2,000
2,500
3,000
3,500
4,000
4,500
5,000
0.00
0.02
0.04
0.06
0.08
0.10
0.12
0.14
0.16
0.18
USD million
1. 2.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
50
Some of the largest peer-to-peer platforms operating in Asia include Alibaba and
DiDi Chuxing in China, Ola in India, Grab in Indonesia, and some US platforms
that operate across the region: Airbnb, Amazon, BlaBlaCar, and Uber. One area that
often requires clarication is the approach to intermediation services provided by
such platforms.
In the context of goods or services provided through a digital marketplace/intermediary,
it is necessary to distinguish between the consideration for payment of the underlying
good or service and the fee associated with the use of the digital platform.
In terms of commission/intermediary fees, some marketplaces charge service fees only
to sellers, which would commonly apply reverse charge rules in a cross-border context.
Sometimes fees are, however, charged to both sellers and consumers. For example,
in the case of Airbnb, both hosts and guests are charged fees. e guest’s service fees
should be subject to VAT, but it is not always clear who gets to tax this fee. Given
the importance of tourism activity for many countries in Asia, clear guidance that
the service fee needs to be remitted based on the place of consumption of the under-
lying good can help ensure that the fee is not allocated to the country where a guest
normally resides.
e VAT treatment of the underlying good/service (for example, provision of rental
accommodation), a taxi ride, or the sale of a physical good through a digital platform
would usually be dealt with under existing domestic legislation, with the seller of the
physical good/service liable to register and remit VAT, subject to domestic registration
thresholds and a credit provided for the VAT paid on a fee for using the platform. In
the case of accommodation rental services through platforms such as Airbnb, similarly,
the liability for payment of VAT on the accommodation lies with the host, if they meet
VAT registration thresholds.
Signicant controversy remains as to the VAT liability of ride-sharing companies, with
Uber being at the center of a number of national court challenges. Since Uber classies
itself as an intermediation service provider, the company considers itself to be simply a
service provider to drivers, who are self-employed individuals; Uber does not book their
income as its own. Since most drivers would not earn enough income through the app
per year to meet VAT registration thresholds, limited VAT is collected in most coun-
tries from Uber drivers. However, this might change due to a recent court challenge in
the United Kingdom, which dened Uber drivers as workers.
1
If Uber is classied as a
transportation company with employed drivers, its entire turnover from the provision
of services would be subject to VAT. Legislation is evolving in this area, and we may see
changes and dierentiated treatment depending on the type of platform in future.
1
See https://www.supremecourt.uk/cases/docs/uksc-2019-0029-judgment.pdf for judgement details.
Box 3. Ensuring Taxation of Intermediary Fees
Digital Services, Digitally Delivered Goods, and VAT
51
Integrated Goods and Services Tax (IGST) in India is chargeable on supply of Online
Information Database Access and Retrieval (OIDAR) services to any person in India,
whether registered or not, if the supplier of the services is located in India, including,
MNEs with a physical presence in India.
OIDAR services are dened as “services whose delivery is mediated by information
technology over the internet or an electronic network and the nature of which renders
their supply essentially automated and involving minimal human intervention and
impossible to ensure in the absence of information technology and includes electronic
services such as: (1) advertising on the internet; (2) providing cloud services; (3) provi-
sion of e-books, movie, music, software and other intangibles through telecommunica-
tion networks or internet; (4) providing data or information, retrievable or otherwise,
to any person in electronic form through a computer network; (5) online supplies of
digital content (movies, television shows, music and the like); (6) digital data storage;
and (7) online gaming.” Since the place of supply determines the taxable jurisdiction
under any VAT-type consumption tax, the place of supply of OIDAR services is dened
to be the location of the recipient of services.
OIDAR services supplied by MNEs located outside India, to any registered entity in
India is taxable under the reverse charge mechanism. However, where the services are
directly provided to the consumers by MNEs with no physical presence in India, it is
not practicable to require the individual consumers to register and fulll the necessary
compliances under the IGST for a one-o purchase on the internet. erefore, the stat-
utory burden for payment of IGST is cast upon such MNEs and a special compliance
regime established to enable them to fulll their compliance obligations and minimize
the risk of revenue leakage.
In case the OIDAR B2C services are arranged or facilitated by an intermediary located
outside India, the intermediary is treated as the supplier of the said service, except when
the intermediary satises the following conditions:
1. e invoice issued by the intermediary clearly identies the nature of the service
and its supplier in the foreign jurisdiction.
2. e intermediary neither collects or processes payment in any manner nor
is responsible for the payment between the service recipient and the supplier
of such services.
3. e intermediary involved in the supply does not authorize delivery.
Box 4. GST Compliance Mechanism for Supply of Digital Services by MNEs in
the Case of India
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
52
4. e general terms and conditions of the supply are not set by the intermediary
involved in the supply but by the supplier of services.
e special compliance regime comprises: (1) a simplied registration scheme; and (2) a
simplied reporting and payment system.
1
Typically, in cases where the OIDAR ser-
vice provider and receiver are both located in India, the general registration rules apply.
However, where the service provider is located outside India but provides OIDAR
services B2C, the MNE service provider is required to obtain registration through a
representative in India or directly, under the simplied registration scheme.
1
Every registered OIDAR service provider providing B2C services from a place outside India to a
person in India is required to le a return in Form GSTR-5A on or before the 20th day of the month
succeeding the calendar month or part thereof in which the service is provided. e simplied form calls
for minimal information with a view to minimizing the cost of compliance. Toward this objective, such
service providers are also exempted from ling annual returns. Similarly, they have also been allowed to
remit the payment of tax through the SWIFT mode. However, other categories of OIDAR service pro-
viders (like those supplying OIDAR services from India) are required to le (1) regular monthly returns
(GSTR 1, 2, 3, or 3B) prescribed for general categories of registered persons and (2) annual returns.
Box 4. GST Compliance Mechanism for Supply of Digital Services by MNEs (continued)
Digital Services, Digitally Delivered Goods, and VAT
53
Pillar 1, Amount A
Revenue estimates are derived using data in country by country reports
(CbCR). In 2017, more than 60 tax jurisdictions have required large MNEs
headquartered in their jurisdictions to report on their income, taxes paid, and
other indicators of economic activity such as employment, assets, and sales
by origin (for both related and unrelated parties) on a country by coun-
try basis. Of these, 25 countries have publicly released their CbCRs on an
aggregate basis.
Estimating sales by destination begins with sales by origin for each
parent-country and aliate-pair from the CbCR data (say, sales of US MNE
aliate located in Mexico). en the export share is applied to determine the
component that is exported and the component that is sold domestically in
Mexico. e export share is taken either from the OECD Analytical Activi-
ties of MNEs database (dierentiating between exports by domestic MNEs
and foreign MNEs) or from the countrys national accounts. For the exported
component, the bilateral trade matrix, from the World Banks World Inte-
grated Trade Solution, of the producing country (that is, Mexico), is used to
approximate the destination of these exports. ese exports are then summed
by destination country. e exports are then added to the domestic sales
made by a US MNE aliate in that country (if any). For example, Mexican
exports to Nicaragua would be added to any US MNE aliate sales made
directly in Nicaragua.
To estimate the revenue eects of Amount A, the authors rst aggregate the
global prots and losses of MNEs by headquarter country. Sales to unrelated
parties are also aggregated by MNE headquarter country. Aggregate routine
prot is then dened as 10percent of aggregate unrelated party sales. e
dierence between prot and routine prot is dened to be the residual.
Annex 1. Methodology
55
A portion (20percent) of the residual is then allocated to each jurisdiction
based on that jurisdictions share of sales by destination for that MNE head-
quarter country. For example, Indias share of US MNEs residual prot is
determined by its share of US MNE sales.
Since Amount A is a reallocation of the tax base, jurisdictions must also
relinquish part of their taxing right. at is, each jurisdiction is assumed to
contribute” to the pool of residual prot to be reallocated. is contribution
is in proportion to the jurisdictions current share of residual prot. In prac-
tice, each group can nominate the aliate(s) and hence jurisdiction(s) that
will pay the new tax liability under Amount A.
For each jurisdiction, the tax base under Amount A is the dierence between
their allocation of residual prot under sales by destination and their current
allocation of the residual. To estimate tax revenue eects, the authors assume
that the statutory CIT rate is applied to this tax base.
e total change in revenue for a jurisdiction is the sum of revenue
changes across each headquarter country included in the dataset (that
is, 25 countries).
Formulary Apportionment
Revenue estimates are derived using data from published country by country
reports, as well as data from the US Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) on
the activities of US MNEs.
US Bureau of Economic Analysis
e BEA publishes annual data on the aggregate nances and operations of
US-based MNEs, with separate statistics for US parent companies and their
foreign aliates in 199 countries. For majority-owned aliates in 52 coun-
tries, there is detailed information on the foreign income tax paid, the prot
they report, and the level of xed assets in each country. It is data on these
aliates that are used for this analysis.
Regarding information on sales, the BEA provides information on sales by
origin as well as partial data on sales by destination. Specically, for each
country where an aliate is located, it reports goods and services supplied
to unaliated persons in either the United States, the host country, or other
foreign countries. For about 10percent of sales to unaliated persons, the
destination country is not specied in the BEA data. However, in the bench-
mark survey years, data are provided on the destination region (that is, Can-
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
56
ada, Europe, Latin America and Other Western Hemisphere, Africa, Middle
East, and Asia-Pacic) for these sales. To allocate sales to countries within
each region specied by the BEA, data on bilateral exports is used.
To estimate the revenue eects of formulary apportionment, prots and
losses declared in each jurisdiction are rst aggregated to determine the tax
base at the global level. is is then apportioned to each jurisdiction using its
share of the factor under consideration. For example, under the employment
factor, Indias share of global US MNE prot is determined by its share of
total employment by US MNEs. e tax rate applied to this tax base is either
the Eective Tax Rate (ETR) calculated from the data, or where the ETR is
an outlier, the statutory tax rate for that country is used.
Country by Country Reports
e same CbCR data set used to estimate the revenue eects under Amount
A is also used to estimate the revenue eects of FA.
To estimate the revenue eects of formulary apportionment, prots and losses
declared in each jurisdiction are aggregated by MNE headquarter country to
determine the tax base. is is then apportioned to each jurisdiction using its
share of the factor under consideration, by MNE headquarter country. For
example, Indias share of a Chinese MNEs prot is determined by its share of
Chinese MNE sales. e tax rate applied to this tax base is either the ETR
calculated from the data on prot-making rms, or where the ETR is an
outlier, the statutory tax rate for that country is used.
Annex 1. Methodology
57
is annex shows the revenue eects of formulary apportionment for indi-
vidual economies. e table on the next page presents the change in CIT
revenue collected from MNEs if there is global adoption of formulary
apportionment (percent of GDP). e results are presented based on var-
ious apportionment factors, using the CbCR data set. For example, the
Employment column shows the change in total CIT revenue from MNEs, if
the share of employees in each economy is used to allocate the consolidated
prot of the MNE.
Annex 2. Detailed Formulary
Apportionment Results
59
Annex Table 2.1. Detailed Formulary Apportionment Results
Sales Employment Asset
Australia 0.07 –0.02 0.38
Bangladesh 0.00 –0.04 –0.02
Bhutan –0.07 –0.11 –0.13
Brunei Darussalam 0.04 0.01 0.02
Cambodia 0.09 0.05 0.02
China –0.02 0.11 –0.03
Fiji 0.04 0.43 0.25
Hong Kong SAR –0.20 –1.00 –0.91
India –0.51 0.19 –0.51
Indonesia –0.10 0.77 0.08
Japan –0.07 –0.70 –0.05
Korea –0.28 –0.54 –0.19
Lao P.D.R. 0.05 0.10 0.06
Macao SAR 0.48 –0.05 0.05
Malaysia –0.08 0.58 –0.12
Maldives –0.19 –0.21 –0.12
Marshall Islands 0.00 0.00 0.00
Mongolia –0.04 0.08 0.15
Myanmar 0.05 0.02 0.03
Nepal –0.08 –0.15 –0.15
New Zealand 0.10 0.14 –0.17
Papua New Guinea 0.20 0.19 1.95
Philippines –0.01 0.79 –0.06
Samoa 0.00 –0.01 –0.01
Singapore –0.02 –0.30 –0.22
Solomon Islands 0.36 0.29 0.14
Sri Lanka 0.06 0.05 –0.03
Taiwan Province of China –0.07 0.15 –0.05
Thailand –0.38 0.44 –0.22
Timor-Leste –0.04 –0.04 –0.07
Tonga 0.00 –0.01 –0.01
Vanuatu 0.00 0.00 0.00
Vietnam –1.87 –1.85 –2.75
Median –0.01 0.01 –0.03
Mean –0.08 –0.02 –0.08
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
60
Aslam, Aqib, and Alpa Shah. 2017. “Taxation and the Peer-to-Peer Econ-
omy.” In: Sanjeev Gupta, Michael Keen, Alpa Shah, and Geneviève Verdier
(eds.), Digital Revolutions in Public Finance. International Monetary Fund,
Washington, DC.
Aslam, Aqib, Alpa Shah. 2020. “Tec(h)tonic shifts: Taxing the Digital Econ-
omy.” IMF Working Paper No. 20/76, Washington, DC.
African Tax Administration Forum (ATAF). 2020. Suggested Approach to
Drafting Digital Services Tax Legislation, https:// events .ataftax .org/ index .php
?page = documents & func = view & document _id = 79
Auerbach, Alan, Michael P. Devereux, Michael Keen, and John Vella. 2017.
“Destination-Based Cash Flow Taxation.” Oxford University Centre for Busi-
ness Taxation WP 17/01, Oxford, UK.
Avi Yonah, Reuven. 2020. ’What’s Everyones Problem with DSTs?” Tax Notes
International, Letters to the Editor, December 7, 2020.
Beer, Sebastian, and Jan Loeprick. 2015. Prot shifting: drivers of transfer
(mis) pricing and the potential of countermeasures.International Tax and
Public Finance22(3): 426–51.
Beer, Sebastian, Ruud de Mooij, Shak Hebous, Michael Keen, and Li
Liu. 2020. “Exploring Residual Prot Allocation.” IMF Working Paper No.
20/49, International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Bourreau, Marc, Bernard Caillaud, and Romain De Nijs. 2018. “Taxation of
a Digital Monopoly Platform.Journal of Public Economic eory, Special Issue
on Taxation in the Digital Economy 20(1): 40–51.
References
61
Brondolo, John, and Mark Konza. 2021. “Administering the Value-Added
Tax on Imported Digital Services and Low-Value Imported Goods.” IMF
Technical Notes and Manuals, Washington, DC.
Cui, Wei. 2018. “e Digital Services Tax: A Conceptual Defense.” Mimeo
(Allard School of Law at the University of British Columbia).
Cui, Wei. 2021. Digital Services Taxes in Developing Countries. Remarks
made at IMF/WB Spring Meetings Conference on International Taxation.
Cui, Wei, and Nigar Hashimzade. 2019. “e Digital Services Tax as a Tax
on Location-Specic Rent.” CESifo Working Paper Series No. 7737.
Dale, Stephen, and Venise Vincent. 2017. “e European Unions Approach
to VAT and E-Commerce.World Journal of VAT/GST Law 6(1): 55–61.
de Mooij, Ruud A., Li Liu, and Dinar Prihardini. 2019. “An Assessment of
Global Formula Apportionment.” IMF Working Paper No. 19/213, Interna-
tional Monetary Fund, Washington, DC.
Devereux, Michael P., Alan J. Auerbach, Michael Keen, Paul Oosterhuis,
Wolfgang Schön, and John Vella. 2019. “Residual Prot Allocation by
Income.” Oxford University Centre for Business Taxation Working Paper
WP19/01, Oxford, UK.
Ecommerce DB. 2019. “In-Depth: B2B E-Commerce 2019.
Statista, New York.
Group of Twenty (G20). 2018. “Toolkit for Measuring the Digital Econ-
omy.” G20 Secretariat.
Herrero, Alicia G., and Jianwei Xu. 2018. “How Big is Chinas Digital Econ-
omy?” Bruegel Working Paper Issue 04, Bruegel, Brussels.
Hvistendahl, Mara. 2019. “Chinas Tech Giants Want to Go Global. Just One
ing Might Stand in eir Way.MIT Technology Review, December 19.
Hufbauer, Gary Clyde, and Zhiyao (Lucy) Lu. 2018. “e European Unions
Proposed Digital Services Tax: A De Facto Tari.” Policy Briefs PB18–15,
Peterson Institute for International Economics.
Kinda, Tidiane. 2019. “E-Commerce as a Potential New Engine for Growth
in Asia.” IMF Working Paper 19/135, International Monetary Fund,
Washington, DC.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
62
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2018a. “Regional Economic Outlook.
Asia and Pacic—Asia at the Forefront: Growth Challenges for the Next
Decade and Beyond.” Washington, DC.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2018b. “e Digital Revolution in Asia:
Disruptor or New Growth Engine (or Both)?” Regional Economic Outlook:
Asia and Pacic Background Paper No. 4, Washington, DC.
International Monetary Fund (IMF). 2019. “Corporate Taxation in the
Global Economy.” IMF Policy Paper, Washington, DC.
Kind, Hans J., Marko Köthenbürger, and Guttorm Schjelderup. 2008. “E-
ciency Enhancing Taxation in Two-Sided Markets.Journal of Public Econom-
ics 92(5–6): 1531–39.
Köthenbürger, Marko. 2020. “Taxation of Digital Platforms,” EconPol Work-
ing Paper 41, ifo Institute - Leibniz Institute for Economic Research at the
University of Munich.
KPMG. 2021. Taxation of the Digitalized Economy – Developments
Summary. https:// tax .kpmg .us/ articles/ 2021/ tracking -digital -services -taxes
-developments .html. Accessed on May 24, 2021.
Laubscher, H. 2018. “e Prime Dierence between Amazon and Alibaba.
Forbes.com, December 28.
McKinsey Global Institute. 2019. “Digital India: Technology to Transform a
Connected Nation.” March 27.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). 2017.
International VAT/GST Guidelines. Paris.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD).
2019. “e Role of Digital Platforms in the Collection of VAT/GST on
Online Sales.” Paris.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD).
2020a. “Tax Challenges Arising from Digitalisation – Report on the Pillar
One Blueprint.” Paris.
Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD).
2020b. “Model Rules for Reporting by Platform Operators with respect to
Sellers in the Sharing and Gig Economy.” Paris.
References
63
Schindler, Dirk, and Guttorm Schjelderup. 2010. “Prot Shifting in
Two‐Sided Markets.International Journal of the Economics of Busi-
ness 17(3): 373–83.
Sedik, Tahsin Saadi. 2018. “Asias Digital Revolution.Finance &
Development 55(3).
Statista. 2020. “Digital Market Data Sheet.” New York.
United Nations. 2008. International Standard Industrial Classication of All
Economic Activities Rev. 4. New York.
United States Trade Representative (USTR). 2021. Section301 Investigation
- Report on Indias Digital Services Tax, January 2021.
World Bank. 2021. World Development Report: Data for Better Lives.
Washington, DC.
Xu, Feifei. 2016. “Alibaba vs. Amazon: A business model compari-
son.”Louvain School of Management, Université Catholique de Louvain,
Louvain-la-Neuve, Belgium.
DIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIADIGITALIZATION AND TAXATION IN ASIA
64